Chapter III
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
Wei Cui*
1 .
Introduction
Designing and enforcing a legal regime for taxing non-residents on
capital gains realized from domestic sources is a topic of vital importance for developing countries. The reason is that non-capital-gain
income that may be derived from a given country can generally be
crystalized in the form of capital gains on the disposition of the
income-generating asset. 1 This is true of most important types of
income, be it rent, interest, royalty, dividend or business profit. Taxing
capital gains, therefore, is invariably needed to ensure that income
from assets in the source country is properly subject to tax. In this
sense, capital gains taxation of non-residents is inherently a measure
for protecting that country’s tax base from erosion.
This perspective, however, cannot be said to be clearly reflected
in the prevailing international tax regime. There is a well-known
principle that if the non-capital-gain income from an asset is taxable in a source country (for example, because the asset is properly
viewed as being located in that country), then the capital gains from
the disposition of that asset should be taxable in the same country. 2
* Associate Professor of Law, University of British Columbia Faculty of
Law, Canada.
1
The intrinsic connection between income derived from an asset and
capital gains realized on the disposition of the asset is grounded in a basic
tenet of modern finance theory, namely, that the value of an asset simply is
the present discounted value of future income that the asset can be expected
to generate.
2
“It is normal to give the right to tax capital gains on a property of a
given kind to the State which under the Convention is entitled to tax both
the property and the income derived therefrom: ” see paragraph 4 of the
Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations Model Double Taxation
Convention between Developed and Developing Countries (United Nations
Model Convention), quoting paragraph 4 of the Commentary on Article 13
127
Wei Cui
This principle, clearly based on the intrinsic connection between the
income derived from an asset and any capital gains realized on the
disposition of the asset, is commonly used to justify taxing capital
gains realized by non-residents on the disposition of immovable property and assets used in a permanent establishment (PE) situated in
the taxing country. Nonetheless, it has not been consistently applied
to other types of capital gains realized by non-residents. The United
Nations Model Double Taxation Convention between Developed
and Developing Countries 3 (United Nations Model Convention), for
example, provides for source-country taxation of interest, dividends,
royalties and other income, in addition to the taxation of income from
immovable property and business profits attributed to a PE. However,
in Article 13 (Capital gains), the United Nations Model Convention
follows the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital 4 (OECD Model
Convention) in giving prominence to taxing capital gains realized on
the disposition of immovable property and business assets used in a
PE, but takes a weaker stance on the taxation of gains realized on the
disposition of company shares, and allows other capital gains realized
by non-residents to go untaxed. 5 The reason for this inconsistency is
of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Model
Tax Convention on Income and on Capital (OECD Model Convention). The
rule that “gains from the alienation of immovable property may be taxed in
the State in which it is situated … corresponds to the provisions of Article 6
and of Article 22 (1): ” see paragraph 5 of the Commentary on Article 13 of
the United Nations Model Convention, quoting paragraph 22 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the OECD Model Convention. The taxation of gains
on the business assets of a permanent establishment (PE) or fixed base “corresponds to the rules for business profits [and for income from independent
personal services] (Article[s] 7 [and 14]): ” see paragraph 6 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations Model Convention, quoting and
supplementing paragraph 24 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the OECD
Model Convention.
3
United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, United
Nations Model Double Taxation Convention between Developed and Developing Countries (New York: United Nations, 2011).
4
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Model
Tax Convention on Income and on Capital (Paris: OECD, 2014).
5
See section 5 below.
128
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
not well articulated. Adding to this, there are substantive disagreements — often between developing and developed countries — about
what types of non-capital-gain income should be taxable in a country other than the resident country of the recipient of the income. 6
Both of these factors — divergent views about where non-capital-gain
income should be taxed, and inconsistencies in observing the equivalence between income and gain (and therefore between the sources of
income and gain)—have led to widely divergent practices in the capital gains taxation of non-residents.
The first challenge facing developing countries in designing policies in this area, therefore, may be the apparent absence of an “international norm,” or confusing accounts of what such a norm consists of.
The present chapter will offer a basic conceptual framework for understanding the divergent practices. It argues that there are sound conceptual justifications for taxing non-residents on capital gains in general,
and that there are no compelling reasons for assuming that such taxation should be limited to immovable property. 7 Instead, the legitimacy
of such a tax may depend more on its specific design—for example,
its treatment of losses, and its ability to avoid arbitrary and multiple taxation of the same economic gain—than on the basic idea of its
imposition. Unfortunately, both the United Nations and OECD Model
Conventions — and many of the existing discussions purporting to
6
This could be a debate either about whether a source country should
have a taxing right, or about what the source of the income is in the first place.
7
In this respect, the arguments of the present chapter go beyond some
recent discussions of the taxation of capital gains that are intended to
emphasize the interests of developing countries. See United Nations, Economic and Social Council, Committee of Experts on International Cooperation in Tax Matters, “Article 13 (Capital Gains): the practical implications
of paragraph 4,” (2014), available at http://www.un.org/esa/ffd/wp-content/
uploads/2014/10/10STM_CRP13_CapitalGains.pdf (hereinafter “Committee
of Experts Paper”); International Monetary Fund (IMF), “Spillovers in International Corporate Taxation,” (2014) Policy Paper, available at http://www.
imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2014/050914.pdf (hereinafter “IMF Spillovers
Report”); and Richard Krever, “Tax Treaties and the Taxation of Non-Residents’ Capital Gains,” in Arthur J. Cockfield, ed., Globalization and its Tax
Discontents: Tax Policy and International Investments (Toronto: University of
Toronto Press, 2010), 212-238.
129
Wei Cui
give guidance to developing countries —tend to be brief, or even silent,
on these design issues.
A second, more important challenge for taxing non-residents
on capital gains lies elsewhere: namely, the tax can be difficult to
enforce, and the dynamics of engagement between tax administrators and taxpayers in collecting the tax can be quite different from
normal tax administration. These difficulties may provoke questions
about whether the likely revenue payoff from the tax justifies the
resources needed for its enforcement. The difficulty of enforcing the
capital gains tax on non-residents may sound clichéd. However, some
of the more familiar descriptions of the administrative difficulties may
not be accurate. For example, it is unclear whether developing countries are more likely to be at a disadvantage in administering the tax.
The present chapter analyses the pros and cons of the various mechanisms for administering the capital gains tax for non-residents and
argues that buyer withholding is a more effective enforcement mechanism than tactics that focus on the transferred assets. Moreover, the
chapter will consider ways in which voluntary compliance in this area
may be improved.
Tax avoidance poses the third challenge for taxing non-residents
on capital gains. The typical strategies for legally avoiding a tax on capital gains imposed by a source country are neither complex nor difficult
to identify. They include treaty shopping and the use of offshore holding companies. However, the incentives for taxpayers to adopt such
strategies may vary as a function of the severity of the first two challenges. If there are basic inconsistencies in the rules adopted by domestic law and by tax treaties towards capital gains taxation, and if the
enforcement of such tax rules is inadequate, taxpayers may have greater
incentives to engage in avoidance. Moreover, the feasibility of avoidance behaviour could also depend to a substantial extent on non-tax
characteristics of the business and the legal environment for investing in a country: some countries witness the use of extensive offshore
markets through which investments are channelled into those countries, while others do not have to cope with such markets. The present
chapter will discuss both specific and general anti-avoidance rules for
maintaining the integrity of a tax on capital gains earned by foreigners, as well as how to choose among these rules in light of the circumstances that generate tax avoidance.
130
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
Section 2 of the present chapter examines the general principles for taxing non-residents on capital gains realized on the disposition of domestic assets. It considers the relationship between capital
gains and other forms of income from an asset, as well as the question
why immovable property has been regarded as a special asset class for
source-based taxation of capital gains. Section 3 analyses specific legal
design issues for taxing capital gains, including whether to assimilate
such taxation to gross- or net-income-based taxation, and issues arising from the taxation of shares of companies. Section 4 considers the
fundamental administrative issues in taxing non-residents on capital
gains. Whereas the issues described in sections 2 – 4 below normally
need to be addressed under domestic legislation, section 5 briefly
reviews Article 13 of the United Nations Model Convention—highlighting some shortcomings of the Article from the source-country
perspective — as well as treaty practices among developing countries
with respect to taxing capital gains. Section 6 turns to tax planning
commonly adopted to avoid the tax on capital gains. It pays particular attention to policies recently adopted by a number of developing
countries aimed at taxing indirect transfers of the shares of resident
companies. Section 7 briefly examines the issue of departure taxes for
individuals. Section 8 concludes by offering some reflections on how
to view the pursuit by developing countries of capital gains taxation of
non-residents.
2 .
General principles for taxing non-residents
on capital gains
2 .1
The economic substance of capital gains
In thinking about taxing non-residents on gains realized on the disposition of domestic assets, it is useful to keep in mind what assets
tend to generate capital gains in the first place and why. For instance,
mass-produced durable assets (for example, machines, computers,
household appliances, vehicles, ships and aircraft) generally see their
values depreciate over their useful lives because of wear and tear and
newer, better products becoming available on the market. Even the
value of buildings as physical structures —if the value of the land
they sit on is disregarded— generally declines instead of increases. By
131
Wei Cui
contrast, the value of the ownership (for example, through company
shares) of businesses may increase, if the businesses are successful, as
may the value of land in locations that experience economic growth.
Other than land, assets that are unique in some ways —for example,
depletable resources and, importantly, monopoly rights (such as rights
to operate in restricted industrial sectors, for instance, mining or telecommunications)—may also increase in value. Finally, modern financial markets create possibilities of speculation and arbitrage that can
give rise to substantial gains (and losses). Many developing countries,
for example, have become acquainted with “vulture funds” that buy up
non-performing business loans or sovereign debts with high risks of
default and realize substantial returns from them.
Reflecting on the types of assets that are likely to give rise to
capital gains is important for two reasons. First, it helps a source country to determine for which categories of assets it is important to reserve
rights in terms of taxing capital gains. This issue will be discussed
further in section 4 below, 8 but it is already immediately clear that
immovable property, even if defined to include mining and mineral
rights, is not the only type of asset that can yield substantial gain. In
fact, from all that is known, it may not even be the most important
class of assets. 9 Second, it enables an appreciation of the economic
nature of capital gains. Essentially, in a competitive asset market,
assets experience gain because of an increased expectation of the
streams of income that they will generate. In effect, between the time
the owner acquires the asset and the time he or she sells it, the market
(that is to say, potential buyers) has come to expect the asset to generate more future income in present value terms. This increased expectation could be due to greater certainty in the future flow of income,
an acceleration of the timing of the return, an increase in the absolute
value of the future return or its value relative to other assets available
for investment. Indeed, gain could arise due to the lack of competition
8
This issue is particularly pertinent to the interpretation of Article 13 (2)
and (3) of the United Nations Model Convention.
9
In the global private equity industry, for example, where capital gains
tend to be the driver of profits, funds deployed in the real estate and infrastructure sectors have been consistently and significantly smaller in comparison with funds deployed in other sectors (such as buyouts). See Bain and
Company, Global Private Equity Report 2014, at 6.
132
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
as well: an initial buyer with special access or bargaining power may
be able to obtain an asset cheaply and “flip” it to other buyers.
From the perspective of economic efficiency, it is in fact attractive to tax many of the types of gain described above. Increases in the
value of non-reproducible assets —land, natural resources and collectibles —tend to reflect what economists call “pure rent” or “economic
profit”: taxing pure rent is efficient because it does not distort economic
behaviour. Taxing gains that arise because of imperfect competition is
also often efficient. Finally, gains in operating businesses and speculative gains on financial markets may represent a mixture of rent, return
to risk-taking and return to managerial skills. Although taxing the
latter two types of return may distort economic behaviour, the magnitude of the distortions may be limited—for instance, where the managerial skills are relatively location-specific, for example, involving
specific language, culture and/or political skills.
Capital gains that arise in the ways just described can be
contrasted with some other forms of gains. One kind of nominal capital gain results from inflation: in an inflationary context, even depreciating equipment can sell for a greater nominal amount of cash than
the purchase price. Another kind of gain is income that has already
been earned on the asset but that has been added to or reinvested in
(capitalized into) the original asset. For example, if a corporation has
retained earnings and does not distribute such earnings to shareholders, the price of its shares will go up simply because the shareholders
have deferred the realization of their income, not because the corporation’s business has better prospects than before. If a shareholder sells
his or her shares, the gain realized may simply be the income that he
or she could have realized as dividend if the corporation had made a
distribution. 10
In general, the design of an income tax may need to provide
special treatment for these latter forms of nominal capital gain. In the
10
Similarly, if a zero-coupon bond with a $100 face amount is issued for
two years in an environment where the market interest rate is stable at 5 per
cent, no one will buy the bond initially if it is issued for more than $90.703.
After a year (with the bondholder being one year closer to maturity) the bond
will be worth $95.24, but the increase from $90.703 merely represents an
accrual of interest, and not a change in the expectation of the bond’s yield.
133
Wei Cui
case of inflation, its presence should ideally be taken into account in
determining whether the taxpayer has any taxable gain. In the case of
accrued earnings realized through a sale of the asset, it may be important to treat the gain from the sale similarly to other ways of realizing already-accrued earnings (for example, dividends). 11 However, it
is crucial to recognize that capital gains often come about not because
income has already accrued, but because of a changed expectation of
what income will accrue.
This conceptual discussion has a direct bearing on a common
scepticism about the wisdom of taxing foreigners on capital gains.
Because transfers of domestic assets by foreigners may be difficult
to detect, and a tax on such transfers may be difficult to enforce, it
is sometimes asked why the source country should attempt to do so.
The asset itself is still located in the source country, and most of the
income it generates —in the form of rent, dividends and other periodic
payments — can be more easily subjected to tax (for instance through
withholding). What does the source country lose by not taxing the
gains non-residents derive by transferring ownership of the asset?
Why tax upon transfer of ownership of an asset, and not just when
income is received by the owner? 12
There is a resolution to this scepticism. As already explained,
generally, the value of an asset is determined by the stream of income
it is expected to generate. If such income is going to be taxed at known
rates, then the value of the asset should also reflect the tax. For example,
if an asset generates $10 of income in each period, and a 20 per cent tax is
imposed on the $10 of income no matter who owns it, then the after-tax
income generated by the asset will be $8 per period. The value of the
asset to a private owner will then be determined by the $8 return, and
11
In the bond example in note 10, if the interest rate stays the same, the
increases in the value of the bond in year one and year two should both be
treated as interest.
12
Notably, the recent IMF Spillovers Report expresses this scepticism:
“Conceptually, there are arguments as to whether or not it is appropriate to
tax [capital] gains at all: they presumably reflect accumulated and expected
earnings, so it may not be necessary or appropriate to tax them if those earnings have been, or will be, adequately taxed in other ways.” See IMF Spillovers Report, supra note 7, at 29.
134
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
not the $10 return. 13 If, despite the lower price, buyers are willing to pay
in view of the expected tax on income, then the seller still realizes a gain
and the seller’s ownership of the asset has generated a form of income
for him or her that is not captured by the tax imposed on future income.
Indeed, in this example, since the burden (economic incidence) of the
tax on dividends has already shifted onto the seller by being capitalized
into asset value, it is clear that only a tax on capital gains can reach the
additional income realized by the seller in the form of gain. Thus insofar as gains arise as a result of changes in expectations, there is a unique
role for the tax on capital gains — one that cannot be played by the tax
on investment income such as dividends. 14
2 .2
Why do source countries tax non-residents so little on
capital gains?
In light of the preceding arguments that capital gains taxation is not
redundant, and, moreover, that capital gains may arise not only in
connection with immovable property, it is striking how little source
countries are expected to tax non-residents on capital gains under
prevailing international norms. Most importantly, many developed
countries do not tax capital gains realized by non-residents on the
disposition of shares of domestic (that is to say, resident) companies,
with the exception of companies that hold domestic real estate. There
are a number of different reasons for the adoption of this policy, most
of which are not necessarily relevant or persuasive in the context of
developing countries. For example, developed countries generally
prefer residence-based taxation, vis-à-vis themselves 15 and develop13
This reflects the idea that a tax on the income generated by an asset
may be “capitalized” into the value of the asset. Economists have offered
many empirical confirmations of the capitalization of different types of taxes
into the value of different types of assets, for example, real estate and company shares.
14
To put it differently, a tax on dividends will tax a given amount of
dividend the same way, no matter how the shares yielding the dividends are
acquired. For income tax purposes, however, how the shares are acquired—
with what amount of previously taxed funds — does matter.
15
If investment flows between two developed countries are roughly
equal, it makes sense for them to forgo source-country taxation; thereby they
will save administrative costs without losing revenue overall.
135
Wei Cui
ing countries. In the European Union, there has even been a coordinated move towards residence-based taxation, removing the tax on
dividends, interest and royalties derived from related companies. 16
Independently, there has also been a desire to align the treatment of
shareholder capital gains with the policy of exempting dividends paid
both to residents and non-residents. 17
For developing countries that are capital importers and that
have decided to maintain the classic corporate income tax, the above
reasons generally have been considered— and frequently found to
be outweighed by other considerations. Two practices of developed
countries are, however, relevant. First, some of them have historically eschewed capital gains taxation of non-residents because of its
perceived administrative burden. The United States of America, for
example, originally abandoned taxing non-residents on capital gains
realized on the sale of United States securities in 1936 for administrative reasons. 18 Canada narrowed its range of capital gains taxation for foreigners recently, in 2010, partly for the same reason. 19 This
shows that enforcing the tax may be challenging for developed and
developing countries alike. Second, even in countries where the alienation of shares of domestic companies by non-residents generally goes
16
See Harry Huizinga, “Taxing Corporate Income — Commentary,”
in Stuart Adams and others, eds., Dimensions of Tax Design [The Mirrlees
Review] (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2010), 894 –903. In connection
with the OECD Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting initiative,
some scholars have advocated for a reversal of this trend. See, for example,
Katharina Finke, Clemens Fuest, Hannah Nusser and Christoph Spengel,
“Extending Taxation of Interest and Royalty Income at Source —An Option
to Limit Base Erosion and Profit Shifting?” (2014), ZEW— Centre for European Economic Research Discussion Paper No. 14-073.
17
See Hugh J. Ault and Brian J. Arnold, Comparative Income Taxation:
A Structural Analysis (Alphen aan den Rijn, the Netherlands: Kluwer Law
International, 2010), Part IV, chapter C, section 3.
18
See Stanford G. Ross, “United States Taxation of Aliens and Foreign
Corporations: the Foreign Investors Tax Act of 1966 and Related Developments,” (1967) Vol. 22, Tax Law Review, 279, 293 –295.
19
See Jinyan Li, Arthur J. Cockfield and J. Scott Wilkie, International
Taxation in Canada: Principles and Practices (Toronto: LexisNexis Canada,
2011), at 184.
136
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
untaxed, special exceptions have been made —in Australia, Canada,
Japan and the United States, for example —for companies that hold
domestic real estate. In other words, taxing real estate gain is felt to be
sufficiently important, from both a revenue and (perhaps more importantly) a political perspective, that the administrative costs of enforcing a tax on the transfers of shares of some resident companies are
worth incurring.
It is useful to reflect on this last trade-off between the importance of taxing a particular category of capital gains and its administrative costs. An often-repeated justification for taxing the gain from
the dispositions of real property holding companies is that if such
dispositions are not taxed, it would be too easy to avoid a tax on the
capital gains realized on the disposition of the real estate itself by selling the shares of holding companies. This justification seems obvious.
But it should be equally obvious that tax avoidance concerns arise not
just in connection with real estate. Take, for example, an operating
business the value of which has increased due to its improved prospects. It is undisputed that the disposition of a business run through a
permanent establishment (PE) of a non-resident should be taxable in
the country of the PE (paralleling the taxability of the business profits attributable to the PE). However, if a business is operated through
the form of a domestic subsidiary and is sold through a share deal, the
tax on the disposition of the business would be avoided, if share sales
are not taxed. Nonetheless, this concern has not generally motivated a
policy of taxing share sales despite the effort in a number of countries
(for example, in Canada and the United States) to equate the tax treatment of branches and subsidiaries, for instance, through the branch
profits tax. This appears to be an obvious case of inconsistency.
One possible explanation for this inconsistency is that the
administrative cost of taxing share transfers should be equal between
a company that holds domestic real estate and a company that holds a
domestic operating business. The need to tax share transfers to prevent
avoidance of a tax on direct asset transfers also arises equally for
immovable property and for assets of operating businesses. 20 Finally,
20
This rationale extends to the disposition of interest in other entities
that are treated as legal persons. See David A. Weisbach, “The Irreducible
Complexity of Firm-Level Income Taxes: Theory and Doctrine in the Corpo-
137
Wei Cui
as discussed above, there is no clear difference between immovable
property and business assets in their ability to generate capital gains.
What is different is that foreign ownership of domestic immovable
property has traditionally been politically more sensitive than foreign
ownership of other domestic assets. It may be this political significance —rather than anything to do with revenue potential, the ease
of tax administration or the need to rationalize tax systems —that
has elevated immovable property to the status of an “especially taxable” asset class in the international tax arena. This is not to say that
foreign ownership of domestic real estate is not politically sensitive in
developing countries. Indeed, it may be so sensitive that it is prohibited outright—in which case the issue of taxing non-residents on capital gains from selling domestic real estate also becomes irrelevant.
Although this source of political legitimacy for the taxation
of non-residents on capital gains may still possess political appeal in
various countries, tax systems in the twenty-first century typically rely
on a wider range of justifications, having to do with budgetary needs,
efficiency, fairness and administrative requirements. These justifications may well point to the taxation of a wider range of capital gains
realized by non-residents.
3 .
Non-administrative design issues in taxing
non-residents on capital gains
3 .1
Gross-income versus net-income approaches
Under their domestic laws, countries may tax income earned from
sources within them by non-residents on either a net- or a gross-income
basis. Under net-income-based taxation, non-resident taxpayers are
treated in many ways like residents: they file income tax returns on a
periodic basis; report income from different sources and of different
types, as well as expenses that are associated with the various items
of income and allowable as deductions; and are subject to tax rates
generally applicable to domestic individuals or corporations. Under
rate Tax,” (2007) Vol. 60, Tax Law Review, at 215; Wei Cui, “Taxing Indirect
Transfers: Improving an Instrument for Stemming Tax and Legal Base Erosion,” (2014) Vol. 33, Virginia Tax Review, 649.
138
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
gross-income-based taxation, by contrast, non-resident taxpayers may
not need to file a tax return at all: the tax imposed by the source country may simply be withheld by the payer. Even when a non-resident
is required to file a tax return, it may be reporting only particular
items of income earned in the source country and not all such income
earned in a period, and it may not be able to claim expenses or offsetting losses. Finally, the tax rate applied to income taxed on a gross basis
is typically lower, in part to reflect the decision not to allow deductions
of expenses and losses. Overall, gross-income-based taxation simplifies compliance and tax administration: the amount of gross proceeds
is usually easily verifiable from the payer, whereas expenses and losses
are more costly to substantiate and verify.
The decision to tax a particular type of income either on a grossor net-income basis could depend on such administrative considerations alone. For example, if a non-resident has a sufficient physical
presence in the source country that periodic contact with the country’s tax administration for purposes of filing a return and cooperating with audits is possible, then net-income taxation may be regarded
as justified. Such a physical presence might be an office —possibly one
that does not operate any business or at least not the business that
generates the relevant taxable income — or a regular agent (even an
agent that is independent). 21 However, for at least the past half century,
it has been more common to tax on a net-income basis only business
income attributable to a physical presence that is akin to a PE, whereas,
short of a PE, income derived by a non-resident is either not taxed (if
it is business income) or taxed on a gross-income basis (if it consists of
particular types of investment income). Moreover, net-income taxation
has become associated with active business income and gross-income
taxation with passive investment income.
Some of these long-standing conventions have recently come
under critical scrutiny: questions have been raised especially regarding whether the concept of PE should still undergird the taxation of
21
See paragraph 6 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United
Nations Model Convention, quoting paragraph 27 of the Commentary on
Article 13 of the OECD Model Convention (“force of attraction” approach to
taxing capital gains).
139
Wei Cui
business profits. 22 In any case, capital gains realized by non-residents
have always fitted uneasily within the above conventions. On the one
hand, capital gains are often a form of passive investment income. On
the other hand, the computation of the amount of gain will almost
always require the taxpayer to submit information about the original cost of the investment and not just the amount of the gross
proceeds. In contrast to dividends, interest and royalties, it is difficult to collect tax on capital gains through final withholding. But
once the non-resident taxpayer is already required to file a tax return
(because it has crossed the administrative threshold), it can be fairly
asked whether net-income-based taxation may be more sensible. This
may mean allowing offsetting capital losses from the country against
the capital gain; it may also mean permitting other types of expenses
to be deducted. At the same time, it may require a higher tax rate to
be applied.
Countries differ widely in this regard in their approaches to
taxing non-residents on capital gains. China and Japan, for example,
require the reporting of a taxable capital gain by a non-resident, but
still apply a reduced rate to such capital gains and do not allow offsetting losses. This can be viewed as being at one end of the spectrum.
The United States, by contrast, treats capital gains on the disposition
of certain real estate-related (FIRPTA 23 ) property realized by foreigners as though they are simply business income, and allows other losses
realized in connection with a United States trade or business of the
foreigner to be offset against such capital gain. This can be viewed as
being on the opposite end of the spectrum from China and Japan. 24
There are important arguments in favour of allowing foreigners to reduce their taxable capital gains by their capital losses from the
source country. To begin with, recognizing gains but ignoring losses
may discourage investors from taking risks. Moreover, taking losses
into account allows a more accurate measurement of the income of
the non-resident that has been realized in the country, and imparts
22
See chapter VIII, Protecting the tax base in the digital economy, by
Jinyan Li.
23
United States Foreign Investment in Real Property Tax Act (FIRPTA).
24
Canada allows the offsetting of losses from a given period from the
disposition of similar investments (taxable Canadian property).
140
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
greater legitimacy to taxing capital gains. 25 However, allowing loss
offsets does reduce the revenue potential from taxing non-residents on
capital gains. Moreover, because the tax on capital gains is difficult to
enforce, non-residents who do not have offsetting losses might demonstrate less compliance than those who do. 26
Whether a gross- or net-income approach is taken also has
consequences for the computation of the amount of capital gains on
each transaction. For example, should fees paid to lawyers, accountants and investment bankers by the seller be allowed to reduce the
amount recognized as the proceeds from sale, and should such fees
paid by the buyer be included in the cost of their investment that can
be deducted in the future? If the law treats capital gains as a form of
passive income, just like dividends and interest, and applies a reduced
tax rate to such income earned by foreigners, then the appropriate
answer is no: any expense similar to expenses that cannot be deducted
from dividends or interests should also not be deductible. This means
that from the perspectives of the source country and the residence
country, the amount of the capital gains realized on a sale can be very
different. 27 From the residence country’s perspective, the amount of
capital gains may depend on all kinds of expenses that should either
be capitalized into the cost of the disposed asset or deducted from
the income realized (thereby reducing the amount of capital gain), as
well as on any depreciation or other allowance that has been given in
respect of the investment (which may increase the amount of capital
25
Under the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland’s
recently introduced regime of taxing non-residents on the disposal of residential properties in the United Kingdom, allowable losses may be taken into
account, and for non-residents who need to file annual tax returns, they must
remit tax payment only by 31 January of the following year instead of within
30 days after the disposal. See Trevor Johnson, “U.K. Tax Update: Nonresidents’ Capital Gains —The Pendulum Swings, but Too Far?” (2015) Vol. 78,
Tax Notes International, 747.
26
However, a compliance culture may be fostered by taxpayers who
expect to be able to claim losses, and the tax administration will be able to
obtain information from such taxpayers. See section 4 below.
27
This is recognized in paragraph 4 of the Commentary on Article 13
of the United Nations Model Convention, quoting paragraphs 13-16 of the
Commentary on Article 13 of the OECD Model Convention.
141
Wei Cui
gains or trigger the recapture of income). From the source country’s
perspective, unless the capital gains are attributable to a PE, none of
the expenses and allowances may be taken into account. This need
not in itself cause alarm—it should be remembered that the difference originates in the source country treating the capital gains as a
form of passive investment income, subject to a simplified method of
collection. 28
3 .2
Special issues in taxing transfer of interests in entities
Taxing share sales creates the possibility of excessive taxation of the
appreciation experienced by the assets held by the target company
(whether immovable properties, operating businesses or some other
type of assets): the appreciation may be taxed at both the corporate and
the shareholder levels. In fact, the problem arises even for business entities (for example, partnerships) that are not themselves subject to tax:
the sale of the assets of a partnership and the sale of the partnership itself
are both ways of realizing a gain from the appreciation of partnership
assets. Both need to be subject to tax to prevent taxpayer manipulation. 29
However, this means that the same economic gain might be taxed more
than once. If such excessive taxation is to be avoided, then potentially
complex measures —involving conforming the “inside” and “outside”
tax cost base (or “basis”) of assets and shares —may have to be applied
to ensure that a gain that has been taxed at the shareholder level is not
taxed again at the entity level (and vice versa).
Such measures are adopted in domestic contexts by some
sophisticated tax systems (such as those implemented in Australia
and the United States) within regimes for group consolidation or
28
See paragraph 4 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United
Nations Model Convention, quoting paragraph 12 of the Commentary on
Article 13 of the OECD Model Convention, where it is stated that “as a rule,
capital gains are calculated by deducting the cost from the selling price. To
arrive at cost all expenses incidental to the purchase and all expenditure for
improvements are added to the purchase price.” However, the same paragraph acknowledges that “the Article does not specify how to compute a capital gain, this being left to the domestic law applicable.”
29
See David A. Weisbach, “The Irreducible Complexity of Firm-Level
Income Taxes: Theory and Doctrine in the Corporate Tax,” supra note 20.
142
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
“flow-through” taxation. However, such regimes rarely extend to
foreign entities. In domestic contexts, the ability of corporations to
claim losses also sometimes mitigates the problem of excessive taxation of corporate assets. However, if foreign shareholders (or foreign
owners of interests in other forms of business entities such as partnerships) are taxed on a gross-income basis and cannot offset losses
against gains, corporate assets that are ultimately foreign-owned are
again more likely to be subject to excessive taxation in this respect. In
general, few countries that tax foreigners on the disposition of companies that hold domestic assets (such as immovable property) have
systematically committed to mitigating potential excessive taxation.
One approach suggested later in the present chapter (see section
6) in connection with the taxation of indirect share transfers is to treat
such transfers as dispositions of underlying assets. That approach
would go some way towards reducing the risk of excessive taxation, as
it would adopt a net-income-based approach to taxing non-residents
on capital gains.
3 .3
Should publicly traded shares be exempt?
Enormous gains may be realized on stock markets, raising the question of whether such gains realized by foreigners on domestic stock
exchanges, for example, under “qualified foreign institutional investor”
regimes operated in countries like China and India, should be taxed.
It used to be said that because trading on stock exchanges tends to
have very high volume and frequency, it would be impossible to keep
track of the gains and losses realized by investors on exchange trades.
But with advancing technology and increasing uses of such technology
by financial intermediaries, tracking information on gains or losses
realized by investors (including foreign investors) may become less
difficult. 30 Moreover, it is possible to require such financial intermediaries, and not the sellers, to act as withholding agents. Therefore, the
decision whether to tax stock exchange gains may hinge more on policies regarding attracting foreign investment than on administrability.
30
See United States Internal Revenue Service, Notice 2012-34, “Basis
Reporting by Securities Brokers and Basis Determination for Debt Instruments and Options.”
143
Wei Cui
In addition, trading gains are more likely to reflect risk-taking rather
than economic rent, and the case for allowing offsetting losses is thus
rather strong.
For gains realized on shares of resident companies listed and
traded abroad, it is obviously difficult to secure cooperation from
foreign stock exchanges to collect tax, even if such taxation is otherwise legitimate.
For foreign listed companies, there is an important argument
against source-country taxation of the transfers of their publicly traded
shares, even if the companies hold substantial assets in the country.
The argument is that listed companies are unlikely to be formed for
tax avoidance purposes, but will almost invariably possess economic
substance. The distinction between publicly traded and non-publicly
traded companies is thus obviously relevant to the policy of taxing
share sales, when that policy is motivated by anti-avoidance considerations. But this implies a criticism of the United Nations Model
Convention, which, like the OECD Model Convention, does not
distinguish between listed and non-listed companies among companies that hold substantial immovable property in the source country: 31
the source country is allowed to tax the capital gains realized on the
sale of all such companies in accordance with Article 13 (4). 32
3 .4
Whether to tax foreign exchange gains
Measurements of capital gains or losses are sometimes affected by foreign exchange gains or losses. 33 For example, local assets purchased
31
Article 13 (4) of the United Nations Model Convention. See further
discussion in section 5 below.
32
The United Nations Committee of Experts Paper surveyed a number
of countries regarding how Article 13 (4) was implemented, and one set of
questions posed to the countries related to how shareholders can learn that
the companies they own derive their values principally from immovable
property in a given country. These questions seem to be pertinent mostly for
publicly traded companies, and it seems debatable whether the sale of shares
of these companies should be taxed in the source country.
33
See paragraph 4 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United
Nations Model Convention, quoting paragraph 11 of the Commentary on
144
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
with US$ 1 million may sell later for more than that amount, not
because the assets have appreciated within the local market (they may
even have suffered a slight loss), but because the local currency has
appreciated against the United States dollar. Conversely, a real capital gain may be hidden by a foreign currency loss. In designing the
rules of taxing capital gains, a country will want to consider how to
deal with foreign currency gains or losses. For example, if a country
is expecting a steadily appreciating domestic currency against the
foreign currency in which the investment is initially denominated, it
will collect more revenue by measuring gain in the foreign currency
than in the domestic currency (thereby capturing some of the gain of
currency speculators). Conversely, if a country is expecting a steadily
depreciating domestic currency against the foreign currency in which
the investment is initially denominated, it will collect more revenue by
measuring gain in the domestic currency.
It is worth mentioning in this connection that any capital control
regime adopted by a country may create problems for non-residents in
paying tax on capital gain. If the amount realized on the disposition is
in foreign currency, but tax must be paid in domestic currency, then
the non-resident taxpayer must be allowed to exchange the currency
for purposes of the tax payment. This issue does not normally arise in
connection with passive income, such as dividends, interest or royalties, which has a domestic payer: the payer in these cases should be
able to furnish the local currency required.
4 .
Administering the tax on capital gains of non-residents
Administering a tax on capital gains realized by non-residents faces
three fundamental challenges. First, if the sale and purchase of the
asset occur between two non-residents, the execution of the transaction and the flow of funds may all take place outside the source
Article 13 of the OECD Model Convention. (“The Article does not distinguish as to the origin of the capital gain … . Also capital gains which are due
to depreciation of the national currency are covered. It is, of course, left to
each State to decide whether or not such gains should be taxed.”) See also
paragraph 4 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations Model
Convention, quoting paragraphs 16 and 17 of the Commentary on Article 13
of the OECD Model Convention.
145
Wei Cui
country, making such transactions difficult to detect. 34 Second, even
if a transaction is detected, if the non-resident seller refuses to pay the
tax and becomes delinquent, unless such a seller has other assets in
the source country, it could be very difficult to complete tax collection.
Third— and this is a point that has received little discussion in the
existing literature —it may be difficult to organize tax administration
around taxing capital gains. The non-resident taxpayers typically have
little or no interaction with the tax authority of the source country.
The timing and volume of transactions may be unpredictable, as may
be the revenue intake from levying the tax. Such irregularity may be
felt to be especially severe if tax administration in the source country
is decentralized.
However, none of these challenges need be insuperable.
4 .1
Detection
4.1.1 Reporting by transacting and third parties
Generally, there are three legal mechanisms that enable tax authorities to detect offshore (direct or indirect 35 ) transfers of domestic assets
or shares: self-reporting by the transferor, reporting by the transferee (whether or not accompanied by withholding) and reporting by
third parties.
As regards transferor self-reporting, the source country may
impose penalties on non-reporting transferors to foster compliance.
However, if the chances of detection of taxable transactions are very
low, the expected cost of a penalty for non-reporting may also be too
low to be effective. If most taxpayers do not comply and the tax authority fails to detect most instances of non-compliance, imposing a heavy
penalty on the few detected cases will also seem unfair. It thus seems
surprising that, at least until recently, many countries have solely or
34
It should be noted that this is a potential problem for all taxable transfers among non-residents, and not just for the type of indirect transfers discussed in section 6 below (that is to say, transfers of foreign entities that hold,
directly or indirectly, domestic assets).
35
Indirect transfers are discussed more extensively in section 6 below.
146
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
largely relied on seller reporting for taxing capital gains. 36 In response
to a recent survey conducted by the United Nations Committee of
Experts on International Cooperation in Tax Matters, a number of
countries, both developed and developing, confirmed the relevant
challenges for detection of taxable transfers. 37 For this reason, the
Australian government has announced that “to further improve the
integrity of the foreign residents’ regime in relation to the disposal of
Australian real property interests … a 10 per cent non-final withholding tax [will] apply to the disposal by foreign residents of certain taxable Australian property from 1 July 2016.” 38
As to transferee reporting, if the transferee is a non-resident as
well, the failure of such reporting would be just as hard to detect as
the failure of transferor reporting. A sanction imposed upon a transferee’s failure to report would, in a way, be similar to increasing the
penalties on a transferor’s failure to report—in both cases, the aggregate penalties on non-reporting are increased. The difference is that
the transferee usually has a lot less to lose by reporting, since it is not
the party paying the tax. This may be sufficient to create compliance by
transferees. Interestingly, however, no government seems to have instituted transferee reporting alone (without further requiring withholding) for taxing either direct or indirect transfers. This points to the
magnitude of the collection problem: simply having information that
a non-resident engaged in a taxable transaction is of little value; the
36
As recently as 2015, when the United Kingdom amended the Finance
Act to subject non-residents to tax on the disposal of residential properties in
the United Kingdom, the Government eschewed a proposed system of deduction at source whereby the solicitor for the seller would deduct the amount
of tax. Instead, the amended Finance Act only required the transferor individual to file a non-resident capital gains tax return within 30 days of the
completion of the disposal. See Trevor Johnson, “U.K. Tax Update: Nonresidents’ Capital Gains —The Pendulum Swings, but Too Far?” supra note 25.
37
See Committee of Experts Paper, supra note 7, at 36-39. The countries
confirming difficulties with detection include Australia, Azerbaijan, China,
Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, Norway, Russia, South Africa and Zambia. India
and the United States, by contrast, did not report such problems because they
require transferee withholding.
38
Ibid., at 45. Withholding will apply to both capital and revenue transactions and the withholding obligation will rest with the purchaser.
147
Wei Cui
government still has to make all the efforts to collect the tax. 39
Besides explicit sanctions, market dynamics may also create
incentives to comply with transferee reporting requirements. 40 For
example, when taxing capital gain, the source country generally
needs to keep track of the tax cost or basis of the assets transferred.
If the capital gains realized on a transfer have been subject to tax, the
cost basis of the shares transferred should be adjusted (“stepped up”
in the case of gain) for purposes of future source-country taxation.
Conversely, one can imagine a rule that provides that if a transfer has
not been taxed (other than in a case where the capital gains on a transfer are affirmatively exempted from tax, for example, under an applicable treaty), then the basis of the transferred shares would, for the
purpose of source-country taxation, remain the same. That is to say,
the transferee would not obtain a basis in the shares it acquires equal
to the consideration it pays unless the acquisition has been taxed.
This is different from the normal use of the concept of cost
basis: the cost basis of an asset is normally determined in respect of a
particular owner of the asset. However, the notion can be modified so
as to keep track of the relationship of the asset to the taxing authority: which portion of the value of the asset has been subject to tax by
the source country (in whomever’s hands)? With such a rule in place,
the failure to report a taxable transfer would result in the risk that the
transferee, in the future when it acts as a transferor, would be taxed on
gain that accrued to and was realized by previous owners. Of course,
for this to have an incentive effect, there must be an expectation that
the future transfer itself will be reported or detected. Another complication is that both the tax authority and the non-resident taxpayer
may also have difficulty determining what the original basis was in
39
Canada, India and the United States are some of the countries that
already impose withholding obligations on purchasers. While China nominally “requires” transferees or other payers of consideration (whether domestic or foreign) to withhold on the capital gains realized on a transfer, when
withholding is infeasible, the transferee or payer has no information reporting obligation.
40
See Wei Cui, “Taxing Indirect Transfers: Improving an Instrument for
Stemming Tax and Legal Base Erosion,” supra note 20.
148
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
the hands of previous owners. 41 Nonetheless, the risk of the conversion of a seller tax liability into a potential tax liability of the buyer (as
a future seller) may well be unacceptable to many buyers. They would
then either seek indemnity from the seller, or require, as a matter of
contract, the seller to report the sale to the tax authorities and, in addition, to pay tax if required by law. 42
With regard to third-party reporting, for certain types of property, such as immovable property, shares in companies, mineral
and other licences, and sometimes even ships and aircraft (because
of regulatory requirements), the country in which they are located
may operate ownership registration systems. The transfers of ownership will be recorded in such systems and tax authorities may require
those who maintain the systems to report the transfers. 43 In addition,
third parties in the transfers of financial claims, that is to say, lessees,
borrowers and companies issuing shares, often receive notice of the
transfers under either legal or contractual requirements. It may be
possible to enlist such parties in reporting taxable transfers, even if
they are not party to the transfer.
However, such a requirement could have limits if third-party
contractual rights to notice are not always required in the market. 44
Moreover, should both the purchaser/transferee and third parties be
required (in the sense of having an obligation backed up by penalties)
41
The future transfer might also itself be exempt from tax (for example,
under treaty protection).
42
Dynamics in the tax service market may also contribute to compliance.
For further discussion, see Wei Cui, “Taxing Indirect Transfers: Improving
an Instrument for Stemming Tax and Legal Base Erosion,” supra note 20,
at 680-681, 690-691 and 694. Because the penalties for non-reporting under
China’s policy of taxing indirect transfers of domestic company shares are
very low, most compliance with that policy that has taken place in China
since 2009 may have resulted from buyer and adviser monitoring.
43
It should be noted, however, that the mere transfer of legal ownership
may not be sufficient to constitute an ownership change for income tax purposes under the tax laws of many countries.
44
Nonetheless, a government requirement for third-party reporting may
induce changes in contractual terms, such that third parties will demand
contractually (and receive) notice of transfers.
149
Wei Cui
to report a transaction? Third-party reporting requirements often will
call upon market participants to share information which they would
not otherwise share. 45 Finally, third-party reporting will not by itself
solve the collection problem. 46 Therefore, where it is possible to rely on
transferee/buyer reporting, third-party reporting should arguably not
be used, unless such reporting (for example, to a regulatory authority)
would take place in any case.
4.1.2 Exchange of information among tax authorities
Some recent discussions of the detection problem refer optimistically
to the exchange of information among tax authorities. 47 It seems
exceedingly unlikely, however, that the seller’s resident country will
have more information about an isolated transaction than the source
country where the transferred asset is located.
The question can also be raised whether the new country-bycountry (CbC) reporting regime promoted by the OECD project on
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) is relevant to the detection
of taxable transfers among non-residents. The OECD Final Report
on BEPS Action 13 provides a template for multinational enterprises
(MNEs) to report annually, and for each tax jurisdiction in which they
do business, supplies information to help assess “high-level transfer
pricing risks and other base erosion and profit shifting related risks.” 48
45
For example, shareholders may have reasons to withhold information
about a share sale from the managers of the company sold, because these
managers may soon be fired. To enlist the assistance of these same managers
in notifying tax authorities of the sale could be awkward.
46
See discussion below regarding objections to imposing a substantive
liability on third parties (other than the seller and buyer).
47
See Committee of Experts Paper, supra note 7, at 36-39; IMF Spillovers
Report, supra note 7, at 71; and Lee Burns, Honoré Le Leuch and Emil Sunley,
“Transfer of an Interest in a Mining or Petroleum Right,” in Philip Daniel and
others, eds., Resources without Borders (Washington: International Monetary
Fund, 2014), section 4.1.
48
See OECD, Transfer Pricing Documentation and Country-by-Country
Reporting, Action 13 —Final Report (Paris: OECD, 2015), available at http://
dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241480-en. As at October 2016, 49 countries had
signed the Multilateral Competent Authority Agreement (MCAA) for the
automatic exchange of CbC reports.
150
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
Under the CbC reporting regime, each MNE group required to file
CbC reports needs to provide a “master file” depicting (among other
things) the MNE group’s organizational structure as well as its intercompany financial activities. In addition, “local files” for each country
in which the MNE does business would furnish “information relevant
to the transfer pricing analysis related to transactions taking place
between a local country affiliate and associated enterprises in different
countries and which are material in the context of the local country’s
tax system.” 49 While the primary aim of the CbC reports is to expose
risks of profit shifting through whatever intercompany transactions
there are within an MNE group, changes in corporate structures and
intragroup financial claims may indirectly reveal taxable asset transfers (including indirect transfers, discussed in section 6.2 below).
However, there are various reasons to believe that the impact
of CbC reports on the practice of taxing capital gains realized by
non-residents will be of secondary significance (at best). First, only
MNEs with an annual consolidated group revenue equal or exceeding €750 million or equivalent are required to file CbC reports. Source
countries may directly receive “master files” and “local files” only
from MNEs that have consolidated subsidiaries in their countries. It
is far from clear that this framework captures a population of taxpayers who routinely realize the kinds of capital gains that source countries may want to tax. For instance, although investment funds are
not automatically exempt from CbC reporting requirements, how to
apply the annual revenue threshold and the accounting consolidation requirement to investment funds remains unclear. 50 Moreover,
the CbC reports that countries may exchange under the Multilateral
Competent Authority Agreement contain only aggregate information
and would not be informative with respect to particular transactions,
whereas capital gain taxation crucially depends on the identification of
particular transactions. Finally, information on corporate structures
(including offshore holding structures) is the type of information that
many countries’ tax administrations are already able to obtain from
49
Ibid., paragraph 22.
See OECD, Guidance on the Implementation of Country-by-Country
Reporting: BEPS Action 13 (Paris: OECD, 2016). Investee entities may generally not be included in the consolidated group of a fund if ordinary financial
accounting practice does not require such inclusion.
50
151
Wei Cui
taxpayers directly, either pursuant to domestic legislation or in administrative practice, and it is not clear that the leverage provided by the
CbC reporting regime is really needed.
4 .2
Collection
From a collection and revenue protection perspective, transferee
withholding is clearly a more powerful tool than transferee reporting.
Canada, India and the United States each require the transferee in a
taxable direct (and, in the case of Canada and India, indirect) transfer
to withhold from gross proceeds paid to the transferor, regardless of
whether the transferee is domestic or foreign. 51 Each also makes the
amount required to be withheld the personal tax liability of the transferee if it fails to withhold. Note that when the transferee is made personally liable for failing to withhold a tax that was in the first instance
imposed on the transferor, the implicit penalty of the no-basis-step-up
treatment (which is possible even under transferor reporting) has
merely been made explicit.
In countries with weak legal norms, a view may be held that
the failure of the transferor to pay tax on a transfer creates a de facto
personal liability for the transferee anyway, as the tax authority could
always “go after” the asset located in the country and therefore expropriate its value from the present owner of the asset. Unless the transferee (new owner) is legally made liable for the tax that the transferor
fails to pay, however, this kind of expropriation is against the rule
of law, and is both unnecessary and unproductive for tax administration. Moreover, even when transferees are made liable for failures
to withhold, it is important to observe legal distinctions. For example, if it is the tax on the capital gains realized on the alienation of
51
The United States rule, Internal Revenue Code section 1445, requires
withholding of 10 per cent from gross proceeds. IRC § 1445 (2013); the Canadian rule, Income Tax Act section 116, requires a significantly higher (25 per
cent) rate of withholding, but allows the transferor to prepay or post collateral with the government based on the amount of capital gains. See Income
Tax Act, R.S.C. 1985, c. 1. The Indian rule, Section 195 (1) of the Income Tax
Act, 1961, requires withholding simply of the amount of the tax owed, without addressing the issue of how the transferee would know how much tax is
owed. See Income Tax Act (195/1961) (India).
152
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
a domestic company’s shares that is at stake, it makes little sense to
demand payment from the domestic company itself. To do so would
erase the distinction between shareholder and corporate liabilities
that lies at the core of an indefinite range of transactions (for example, with creditors, customers and employees) that the company may
be engaged in. This would clearly be counterproductive. 52
Several limitations of the withholding approach should be
noted, however. First, if the transferee is a non-resident, the imposition
of a withholding obligation alone does not necessarily enhance the
transferee’s likelihood of compliance. And delinquent non-resident
transferees create collection problems similar to those encountered in
respect of delinquent non-resident transferors. 53 Second, withholding
on capital gains also cannot generally be expected to be accurate with
respect to the ultimate tax liability and therefore is likely to trigger
either an application for refund or examination by a tax authority. The
overall compliance burden for taxing capital gains, therefore, will be
increased by withholding. It also bears mentioning that any obligation
to withhold could only sensibly be formulated with respect to the gross
amount paid and not the capital gains realized by the payee, because
it is only infrequently that a seller would tell a buyer how much profit
the seller has made. 54
4 .3
Voluntary compliance
In other areas of tax administration, a key to success in collection,
beyond adequate sanctions and effective enforcement powers, is the
inducement of voluntary compliance among taxpayers. It would be
surprising if this were not the case in levying tax on non-residents.
52
For these reasons, several suggestions regarding collection techniques
made in the IMF Spillovers Report (for instance, treating the target resident
company as the agent of the non-resident, so that it will be liable if the tax is
not paid by the non-resident, or deeming the resident company to have made
the transfer, so that it is liable for the tax) should be viewed with caution. See
IMF Spillovers Report, supra note 7.
53
Nonetheless, for the reasons discussed in the previous paragraph, it
rarely makes sense to make the target of the transfer liable for tax.
54
See, however, the Indian withholding requirement, Income Tax Act
(195/1961) (India).
153
Wei Cui
However, there has been little government or scholarly research
on voluntary compliance on the part of non-residents. For example,
while, intuitively, a lower rate of tax should produce greater voluntary
compliance, it is not known how low the tax rate would need to be
to produce sufficient compliance. Another suggestion is to increase
the contact of non-residents with the tax authority and with other
compliant taxpayers. For example, allowing losses and expenses to be
taken into account in computing taxable gain may make the contact
of non-residents with the source country less “one-shot” in character. Finally, it may be useful to focus on improving compliance among
multinationals and foreign investors that deal with the source country
on a regular basis. A culture of compliance among such taxpayers (and
their advisers) may be an important step towards creating a culture of
compliance among non-resident taxpayers in general.
4 .4
Organization of tax administration
The occurrence of taxable transfers of domestic assets among
non-residents can be erratic, which makes the decision to assign dedicated tax administration personnel to collect tax on such transfers difficult. At the same time, non-reporting non-residents —whether they
are transferors or transferees — are like domestic taxpayers who do not
file tax returns: special efforts have to be made to detect them and bring
them into compliance. It is not clear that any country’s tax authority
has developed well-articulated strategies for dealing with this predicament. In many OECD countries, where both tax administration and
the study of tax administration are generally more developed than
elsewhere, the scope of capital gains taxation on non-residents tends
to be limited. They therefore offer limited expertise insofar as taxing
capital gains of non-residents is concerned.
In the United States, for example, an Internal Revenue Service
(IRS) publication from 2010 states that a study of the collection of
FIRPTA tax was only “planned” and data was “not yet available.” 55
Moreover, the “planned” study was based only on returns filed by
55
Melissa Costa and Nuria E. McGrath, “Statistics of Income Studies of
International Income and Taxes,” (2010) Vol. 30, No. 1 Statistics of Income
Bulletin, available at http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/10intertax.pdf, at 192.
154
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
transferees who had withheld tax from the gross proceeds of sales of
United States real estate interest (including shares of United States
companies that hold United States real estate) by foreigners. 56 No data
seems to be separately available to the IRS on transferor self-reporting
of sale of United States real property interests, and there is no sign
of any data on audits (if any) of transferors or transferees. In fact,
the United States did not attempt to measure non-resident taxpayer
compliance until 2008, and even the new attempt to do so is designed
only for individual taxpayers. 57
For developing countries that aim to preserve their tax base
consisting of income belonging to non-residents to a greater extent
than OECD countries, effective tax administration strategies may
therefore have to be developed indigenously. One possible approach
is to centralize tax administration in this area so as to allow specialization and economy of scale: the number of taxable transactions as
well the revenue outcome will diminish if averaged over too many tax
administrators, whereas a small number of specialized tax administrators may be able to deal with a relatively large number of taxable transactions because of the one-shot nature of the taxpayers involved. 58
56
Ibid. The most recent IRS Bulletin on Foreign Receipts of United States
Income, relating to the year 2010, also reports only FIRPTA withholding
information and no information about transferor self-assessment. See Scott
Luttrell, “Foreign Recipients of U.S. Income, 2010,” (2013) Statistics of Income
Bulletin, available at http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/13itsumbulforrecip.pdf.
57
See United States Internal Revenue Service, “The Tax Gap and International Taxpayers,” (2008), available at http://www.irs.gov/Businesses/TheTax-Gap-and-International-Taxpayers. See also, United States Government
Accountability Office, “IRS May Be Able to Improve Compliance for Nonresident Aliens and Updating Requirements Could Reduce Their Compliance
Burden,” GAO-10-429 (2010), available at http://gao.gov/products/GAO-10429. The IRS has not developed estimates for the extent of non-resident alien
tax non-compliance.
58
However, in China, where enforcement of the tax on capital gains of
non-residents realized on transfers of domestic company shares (including
indirect transfers, as discussed in section 6 below) has intensified in recent
years, a decentralized approach seems to have emerged: tax administration
staff in local offices take initiatives to find offshore share transfers (which is
not hard to do if listed companies are involved and material transactions
155
Wei Cui
5 .
Article 13 of the United Nations Model Convention
and treaty practices among developing countries
with respect to taxing capital gains
Article 13 of the United Nations Model Convention allocates
non-exclusive taxing rights to the source country in respect of gains
on immovable property (paragraph 1), business assets forming part
of a PE (paragraph 2), ownership interest in entities that derive value
principally from immovable property (paragraph 4) and shares that
represent substantial participation in a resident company (paragraph
5). It assigns exclusive taxing rights to the place of effective management in respect of gains on ships or aircraft operated in international
traffic and boats engaged in inland waterways transport (paragraph
3). 59 It then provides that the gain from the alienation of other property not specifically enumerated shall be taxable only in the residence
State of the alienator (paragraph 6). The threshold decisions of whether
capital gains should be taxed and, if so, of how they are to be taxed, are
left to the domestic law of each contracting State. 60
The United Nations Commentary on Article 13 repeatedly refers
to the “correspondence” between the taxation of gain and the taxation of income, and uses this correspondence to explain the purpose
are required to be disclosed by stock exchanges), and sometimes collect revenue that is sizeable for that particular office, even if not for the country’s tax
administration as a whole. There is no systematic study of this practice, but a
sense of it can be gleaned from practitioners’ reports. See, for example, Jinji
Wei, “Chinese Tax Implications of Indirect Share Transfers,” (2014) Vol. 23,
No. 7 Tax Management Transfer Pricing Report.
59
The practical significance of Article 13 (3) is unclear. Ships, aircraft
or boats as physical vehicles should generally decline in value during their
useful lives, even if the rights to use them may change in value due to fluctuations in demand and supply in shipping and aviation markets. Moreover,
the paragraph is limited to alienation by owners who also operate the ships,
aircraft or boats; such vehicles operated by parties other than such owners
(for example, under dry lease) fall outside the scope of the paragraph. See
paragraph 7 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations Model
Convention, quoting paragraph 28 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the
OECD Model Convention.
60
Paragraph 3 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations
Model Convention.
156
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
of paragraphs 1 and 2 of the Article. 61 Nonetheless, in the restrictions
it imposes on source-country taxing rights, the United Nations Model
Convention does not generally adhere to this correspondence: instead
of being a consistent implementation of the principle of similar taxation of income and gain (given their economic equivalence), Article 13
of the United Nations Model Convention is very much a compromise.
The most salient symptom of this compromise is the structure of the
Article. While the language of the United Nations Model Convention,
following Article 13 of the OECD Model Convention, proceeds to
delineate source-country taxing rights for specific types of property,
and then to provide for exclusive resident-country taxation for properties not specifically enumerated, the United Nations Commentary
on Article 13 acknowledges that “[most] members from developing
countries advocated the right of the source country to levy a tax in
situations in which the OECD reserves that right to the country of
residence.” 62 It therefore mentions an alternative provision allowing
source-country taxation of gains “from the alienation of any property other than those gains mentioned in paragraphs 1, 2, 3 and 4.” 63
This alternative language, adopted with modification in many actual
treaties, leads to some obvious interpretive tensions surrounding the
Article, as discussed below.
The following aspects of the language of Article 13 are especially
relevant to understanding the restrictions that the Article imposes on
source-country taxing rights, as well as the anti-avoidance principles
the Article acknowledges.
5 .1
The definition of “immovable property”
“Immovable property” for purposes of Article 13 is defined by reference to Article 6, which, in the United Nations Model Convention, has
“the meaning which it has under the law of the Contracting State in
which the property in question is situated.” Article 6 (2) of the United
61
See section 3 above.
Paragraph 2 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations
Model Convention.
63
Paragraph 18 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations
Model Convention.
62
157
Wei Cui
Nations Model Convention explicitly states that the term “immovable
property” “shall in any case include … rights to which the provisions
of general law respecting landed property apply, usufruct of immovable property and rights to variable or fixed payments as consideration
for the working of, or the right to work, mineral deposits, sources and
other natural resources.” This broad formulation is likely to capture
the rich variety of “bundle[s] of infinitely divisible rights” 64 that may
be associated with immovable property and transferred at a gain. 65
5 .2
Movable property part of a permanent establishment
Article 13 (2) gives the source country taxing rights on gains from the
alienation of movable property forming part of the business property of a PE (or pertaining to a fixed base available for the purpose
of performing independent personal services). The United Nations
Commentary explicitly notes that “the term ‘movable property’ means
all property other than immovable property … . It includes also incorporeal property, such as goodwill, licenses, etc. Gains from the alienation of such assets may be taxed in the State in which the permanent
establishment [or fixed base] is situated.” 66 This is an important observation, because tangible movable properties — such as machines and
equipment—tend to experience depreciation and thus have limited
64
Richard Krever, “Tax Treaties and the Taxation of Non-Residents’
Capital Gains,” supra note 7, at 224.
65
Nonetheless, Professor Richard Krever has argued that “there are
remarkably wide variances in the different definitions” used in different
jurisdictions, and that “civil law jurisdictions with limited [natural] resources” tend to adopt the narrowest definitions. He warns that “treaties often fail
to operate as broadly as domestic legislation, and domestic legislation itself
may struggle to keep up with new and innovative forms of de facto property
owners, including the use of rights, options, or derivatives.” Therefore, he
suggests that “countries seeking to retain domestic taxing rights through
Article 13 must ensure, first, that domestic law is sufficiently robust to capture all gains related to real property realized by resident and non-resident
taxpayers and, second, that Article 13 in their tax treaties is equally broad.”
Ibid., at 223 –224.
66
Paragraph 6 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations
Model Convention, quoting paragraph 24 of the Commentary on Article 13
of the OECD Model Convention.
158
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
potential for capital gain. It is instead the intangible components of a
business, including contracts with customers, employment contracts
with skilled personnel, brand names, know-how (whether patented or
not) and so forth, that give rise to capital gains on the sale of a business.
This broad definition of movable property under Article 13 (2)
raises a crucial interpretive issue: is movable property that does not
form part of the business property of a PE of a non-resident thereby
carved out from the scope of taxation under Article 13? Consider the
vulture fund that has sold a portfolio of non-performing loans at a
handsome gain. The loans may be viewed as movable property for the
purpose of the fund business, or depending on the fund’s structure,
they may be held as investment assets but nonetheless are “movable
property” in the sense defined above. The fund may have no PE in
the country where the business borrowers are located. Does Article
13 (2) imply that the vulture fund’s gain is not taxable in the country
of the debtors? 67 Since whatever is not immovable property will be
regarded movable property, unless there is a subsequent paragraph in
Article 13 that prescribes a specific rule (for example, for ships, aircraft
and shares), one might infer that capital gains taxation (without PE)
is precluded by paragraph 2. If under the same treaty, interest on
loans (and rent or royalty from leases, licences and other agreements
covered by the “Royalties” article) remain taxable in the source country, a sharp inconsistency between the treatment of income and of gain
from the same asset would result.
As discussed below, this difficulty is not necessarily resolved
even when the contracting States agree to retain residual taxing rights
for the source State over gains not otherwise enumerated in Article 13.
5 .3
Entities holding immovable property
directly or indirectly
Article 13 (4) of the United Nations Model Convention provides taxing
rights over “gains from the alienation of shares of the capital stock
of a company, or of an interest in a partnership, trust or estate, the
67
Similar questions can be raised for transfers of lease contracts with
domestic lessees, or of licences with domestic licensees, and so on, where the
lessor, licensor, etc., has no PE in the source country.
159
Wei Cui
property of which consists directly or indirectly principally of immovable property situated in a Contracting State” to that State. 68 The
United Nations Commentary notes that the provision:
is designed to prevent the avoidance of taxes on the gains from
the sale of immovable property. Since it is often relatively easy
to avoid taxes on such gains through the incorporation of a
company to hold such property, it is necessary to tax the sale
of shares in such a company … . In order to achieve its objective, paragraph 4 would have to apply regardless of whether
the company is a resident of the Contracting State in which
the immovable property is situated or a resident of another
State … . In order to fulfil its purpose, paragraph 4 must apply
whether the company, partnership, trust or estate owns the
immovable property directly or indirectly, such as, through one
or more interposed entities. 69
However, it does not appear that countries have generally
enacted the anti-avoidance measures permitted by Article 13 (4). For
example, as discussed in section 6.2 below, surprisingly few countries —
in the OECD 70 or in the developing world—have enacted domestic
68
Article 13 (4) (b) defines “principally” in relation to ownership of
immovable property to mean “the value of such immovable property exceeding 50 per cent of the aggregate value of all assets owned by the company,
partnership, trust or estate.”
69
Despite the anti-avoidance intent of Article 13 (4), it has been argued
that it may not encompass all the ways in which non-residents may employ
tax structures to avoid taxation. “A convertible debt or option, for example,
may not be viewed by a court to constitute an interest in a company, but
merely a claim to a company’s property in the former case or a right over a
shareholder or the company in the latter.” See Richard Krever, “Tax Treaties and the Taxation of Non-Residents’ Capital Gains,” supra note 7, at 229.
It has therefore been suggested that a source country may want to subject
such claims against a company holding immovable property situated in it to
capital gains taxation also. Canada defines taxable Canadian property (that
is to say, property whose gain realized by a non-resident is taxable in Canada)
as including “an option in respect of” other taxable Canadian property. See
Income Tax Act, RSC 1985, c. 1 (5th Supp.), s. 248.
70
The OECD Model Convention contains a somewhat similar provision
for source-country taxation of the shares of real estate holding companies,
including shares of non-resident companies.
160
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
law for taxing transfers of foreign companies (indirect transfers). The
mere language of Article 13 (4), therefore, sheds little light on the practice of anti-avoidance legislation.
Finally, Article 13 (4) of the United Nations Model Convention
carves out from source-country capital gains taxation transfers of
interests in entities whose property consists directly or indirectly principally of immovable property used by them in their business activities
(but not an immovable property management company, partnership,
trust or estate). The reason for this carve-out, presumably, is that entities that use immovable property in their business activities are not
formed for purposes of avoiding the tax on the sale of immovable property. However, relatively few treaties involving developing countries
have adopted this carve-out; nor has Article 13 of the OECD Model
Convention adopted a similar one. An obvious reason is that there are
important types of companies which derive their value predominantly
from real property, for example, hotel and resort operators, operators of shopping malls and even of restaurants and cinemas, and, of
course, companies that extract natural resources. The appreciation in
the value of the shares of such companies is likely to reflect the appreciation of the underlying real property, and it is not at all obvious why
the source country should give up taxing rights over such shares. This
carve-out can also be regarded as a special case in the inconsistent
treatment between PEs and subsidiaries of non-residents, mentioned
in section 2.2 above and further discussed in the next section.
5 .4
Substantial participation in a company
The Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations Model Convention
notes that “some countries hold the view that a Contracting State
should be able to tax a gain on the alienation of shares of a company
resident in that State, whether the alienation occurs within or outside
that State.” It then claims that “for administrative reasons the right to
tax should be limited to the alienation of shares of a company in the
capital of which the alienator at any time during the 12-month period
preceding the alienation, held, directly or indirectly, a substantial
participation.” 71 This position is reflected in Article 13 (5) of the United
71
Paragraph 9 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations
Model Convention.
161
Wei Cui
Nations Model Convention, where the percentage deemed to constitute
substantial participation is to be established through bilateral negotiations. Article 13 (5) allows that the substantial holding (which leads
to taxability) may be “indirect,” partly as an anti-avoidance device. 72
Under the OECD Model Convention, the alienation of shares
of companies other than those holding domestic real property assets
is not taxable in the country of residence of the companies. As noted
earlier, this produces differential treatment between PEs and subsidiaries, and ignores the anti-avoidance argument for taxing both asset
and share sales. Article 13 (5) of the United Nations Model Convention
can be viewed as constituting an improvement in this regard. What is
less clear, especially in view of the analysis of enforcement and compliance in section 4 above, is why administrative considerations dictate
a percentage ownership approach to having a threshold for taxing
the alienation of shares. For example, if it is the burden of filing a tax
return by the non-resident that is at issue, a monetary amount (that is
to say, exclusion of small gains) would seem more appropriate.
The Commentary on the United Nations Model Convention
also points out arguments against taxing listed shares (that it is “costly,”
and that “developing countries may find it economically rewarding to
boost their capital markets by not taxing gains from the alienation
of quoted shares.” 73 ) It goes on to suggest language for carving out
traded shares from the scope of taxation under paragraph 5. The cost
of taxing exchange-traded shares and the policy of boosting domestic stock markets, however, seem to be issues better addressed through
domestic law. There seems to be little need or justification for negotiating a reciprocal agreement with individual treaty partners.
72
According to paragraph 11 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the
United Nations Model Convention, “It will be up to the law of the State
imposing the tax to determine which transactions give rise to a gain on the
alienation of shares and how to determine the level of holdings of the alienator, in particular, how to determine an interest held indirectly. An indirect
holding in this context may include ownership by related persons that is
imputed to the alienator. Anti-avoidance rules of the law of the State imposing the tax may also be relevant in determining the level of the alienator’s
direct or indirect holdings.”
73
Paragraph 13 of the Commentary on Article 13 of the United Nations
Model Convention.
162
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
5 .5
Residual taxing power
Article 13 (6) of the United Nations Model Convention, like Article 13
(5) of the OECD Model Convention, gives the residence State exclusive
taxing rights over assets not covered by the preceding paragraphs of
the Article. However, as mentioned, the Commentary has noted the
preferences of developing countries to retain taxing power over assets
not specifically enumerated. Such preferences are also reflected in the
treaty practice of many countries — and not just developing ones. 74
This is not surprising insofar as the previous paragraphs of Article 13
do not capture all the important elements of the capital gains tax base
for the source country (see the discussion at the beginning of section 2
above), and insofar as ceding such residual taxing rights would create
disparate treatment between income and gain from the same asset.
However, the way in which residual taxing power is preserved
under Article 13 remains a problematic issue. The Commentary
on Article 13 of the United Nations Model Convention proposes
the language: “Gains from the alienation of any property other than
those gains mentioned in paragraphs 1, 2, 3 and 4 may be taxed in the
Contracting State in which they arise according to the law of that State.”
The question can be raised as to what constitutes a gain “mentioned” in
a previous paragraph. For example, consider the gain from the alienation of shares that fall below the ownership threshold set by the contracting State in a provision similar to Article 13 (5) of the United Nations
Model Convention. Article 13 (5) states only that the gain realized on
the alienation of shares above the threshold is taxable in the source State.
Is gain realized on the alienation of shares below the threshold thereby
“mentioned”? If the position is taken that it is not, then the residual taxing
power paragraph essentially erases the line drawn in Article 13 (5): it is
74
A recent study of Article 13 offers as examples of tax treaties that permit the source State to tax gains from the alienation of property that is not
otherwise covered by Article 13, those concluded by Australia (1989 to 2003),
Argentina, Brazil, China (the tax treaties with Australia, Canada, the Czech
Republic, Germany, Hungary, India, Japan, Malaysia, the Netherlands, New
Zealand, Nigeria and Thailand), India (the tax treaties with Canada and the
United States) and Turkey (the tax treaties with Canada, Italy, Singapore and
Spain). Jinyan Li and Francesco Avella, “Article 13: Capital Gains,” Global
Tax Treaty Commentaries (Amsterdam: International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, 2014), section 3.1.6.2, “Other cases dealt with by domestic law.”
163
Wei Cui
almost as though Article 13 (5) is deleted in its entirety. 75
Interpreted in this way, the approach to drafting in Article
13 would strike many readers as unusual (and unnatural). Even
source-country tax authorities want to refrain from “overlooking”
distinctions made in the previous paragraphs of Article 13 if residual
taxing power is reserved under Article 13 (6). An alternative approach
to applying Article 13 (6) is to deem what is reserved to be taxing rights
over types of property (as opposed to types of gain) not referred to in a
previous paragraph. 76 Thus, shares of resident companies are a type of
property already covered by Article 13 (5), and the alienation of shares
below the threshold would not be taxable even under Article 13 (6). The
question is then what is the “type of property” previously referred to in
the Article. For example, does Article 13 (2) refer to all movable property,
or only movable property used in a business, or, even more narrowly,
only movable property used in a business conducted by a PE? Here,
one faces an interpretative dilemma. On the one hand, the reading of
Article 13 (2) as referring to all movable property would render the class
of “property other than that referred to” in a previous paragraph nearly
empty. On the other hand, reading it as referring to “movable property
used in a business conducted by a PE” would mean erasing the distinctions drawn in (and therefore the point of) that paragraph.
Therefore, the uneasy compromise that the United Nations
Model Convention has tried to delineate between Article 13 of the
OECD Model Convention and the positions of developing countries
seems to have led to an interpretive impasse.
6 .
Preventing avoidance of the tax on
capital gains by non-residents
Section 4 of the present chapter identified detection of taxable transfers
and enforcement against delinquent taxpayers as the main challenges
75
A similar question can be raised about the 50 per cent-of-assets threshold for real property holding entities in Article 13 (4).
76
This interpretation is made explicit in some treaties, through such language as: “Gains derived by a resident of a Contracting State from the alienation
of any property other than that referred to in paragraphs 1 through 5 and arising
in the other Contracting State may be taxed in that other Contracting State.”
164
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
for administering the tax on capital gains of non-residents. These are
the types of challenges more frequently discussed in connection with
tax evasion, but for non-residents and for taxing capital gains, the line
between tax avoidance and tax evasion is especially blurry: it takes
little effort for the taxpayer to hide the relevant taxable transactions
and to dodge enforcement— efforts whose undertaking normally
distinguishes the tax evader. This may be one reason why tactics for
avoiding the tax on capital gains are generally fairly crude. Another
reason is that, as discussed in sections 2 and 5 above, both domestic laws of various countries and tax treaties may sometimes give the
impression that ceding source-country taxing rights over capital gains
(for example, from company shares and from the transfer of other
financial claims or intangibles) is normal. But once such concessions
are made, taxpayers can be expected to exploit them.
6 .1
Treaty shopping
One obvious strategy for avoiding the capital gains tax is to set up
holding companies that otherwise serve little or no business purpose
in jurisdictions with treaties that contain favourable provisions on
the taxation of capital gains. 77 Even for countries that generally tax
transfers of shares of domestic companies (whether all transfers or
transfers of substantial ownership, in accordance with Article 13 (5)
of the United Nations Model Convention), some of their treaties may
exempt such transfers. Still fewer treaties may exempt the transfer of
shares of real estate holding companies (contrary to the provisions of
Article 13 (4) of the United Nations Model Convention). 78 Moreover, a
77
It was recently reported that in 2010, a non-resident company (Heritage Oil) sold a 50 per cent stake in two oil exploration blocks in western
Uganda to a Ugandan company. Evidence from the Panama Papers leak
shows that Heritage Oil not only knew of the impending tax but had planned
aggressively to avoid it, by redomesticating the holding company from the
Bahamas to Mauritius to take advantage of the latter’s tax treaty with Uganda
(which lacks any indirect transfer provision for real estate assets). Ajay Gupta,
“Taxing Indirect Transfers of Real Estate Assets,” (2016) Vol. 82, Tax Notes
International, 820.
78
The carve-out for companies that use domestic real property in their
businesses contained in Article 13 (4) of the United Nations Model Conven-
165
Wei Cui
developing country may not always be able to negotiate the retention
of residual taxing rights under Article 13 (6).
Since a separate chapter in this publication deals with the abuse
of treaties, there is no need to dwell on the issue here. 79 However, one
comment is worth making in connection with Article 13. Unlike some
of the other distributive articles in tax treaties (regarding, for example, interest, dividends, royalties and, increasingly frequently, other
income), which generally deploy the concept of beneficial owner as a
way of preventing treaty abuse, the capital gains article generally does
not refer to beneficial owners. This by no means implies that a more
permissive attitude towards treaty shopping is intended with respect
to capital gains. Instead, it merely reflects the fact that the drafting
of the article uniformly refers to capital gains “derived by” residents
of a contracting State, and never employs the phrase “paid to.” It is
indeed this latter phrase that led to the (perceived) need to stress the
qualification of the payee as a beneficial owner in the other distributive articles. 80
6 .2
Indirect transfers 81
6.2.1 The growing prevalence of taxation of indirect transfers
As discussed in section 2.2 above, if the transfer of an asset is taxable, but the transfer of ownership interest in an entity that holds
tion is not often adopted, but where it is, it also gives rise to incentives for
treaty shopping.
79
See chapter VI, “Preventing tax treaty abuse,” by Graeme S. Cooper.
80
A rare anti-avoidance provision specifically addressing capital gains
is found in Article 14 (6) of the Convention between the Government of the
Italian Republic and the Government of the Republic of Ghana for the Avoidance of Double Taxation with Respect to Taxes on Income and the Prevention
of Fiscal Evasion, of 19 February 2004: “The provisions of this Article shall
not apply if the right giving rise to the capital gains was created or assigned
mainly for the purpose of taking advantage of this Article.”
81
The present section is based on Wei Cui, “Taxing Indirect Transfers: Improving an Instrument for Stemming Tax and Legal Base Erosion,”
supra note 20.
166
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
the asset is not taxable, then the tax on the transfer of the asset can
be indefinitely deferred (thus essentially avoided) by using a holding
entity. This logic applies no matter how many layers of holding entities
are involved and regardless of whether the holding entity (or entities)
is (are) domestic or foreign. This is why Article 13 (4) of the United
Nations Model Convention permits the country where immovable
properties are located to tax foreigners even on transfers of foreign
entities, if such entities principally hold, directly or indirectly (for
example, possibly through multiple layers of holding companies), the
immovable properties. However, it is relatively uncommon for countries to adopt domestic law provisions for taxing non-residents on the
disposition of shares of foreign companies, whether generally or for
real estate holding companies.
There are several possible explanations for this. First, many
developed countries where anti-tax-avoidance policies are most established have chosen not to tax non-residents on capital gains, on grounds
unrelated to tax avoidance. 82 Second, using offshore holding companies to make an investment in a given country may be tax-inefficient
for investors from that country (unless domestic investors can evade
home-country taxes by going offshore). Thus for any asset market
where domestic investors are dominant, it may be unlikely for that
asset market to move offshore. This is probably the reason why the
United States (unlike Australia, Canada and Japan) has not adopted
rules for taxing indirect transfers of United States real property interests: any foreigner investing in United States real estate will want to
use investment structures that future United States buyers would not
reject. 83 Third, and more generally, there may be other legal factors
that either pull the legal structures for foreign investment onshore or
push them offshore. 84 Where such other considerations favour using
onshore structures, the attraction of offshore structures (in terms of
helping to avoid the capital gains tax) may be outweighed.
82
See supra note 15; and Stanford G. Ross, “United States Taxation of
Aliens and Foreign Corporations: the Foreign Investors Tax Act of 1966 and
Related Developments,” supra note 18.
83
See Wei Cui, “Taxing Indirect Transfers: Improving an Instrument for
Stemming Tax and Legal Base Erosion,” supra note 20, 664-666.
84
Ibid., 666-671.
167
Wei Cui
In the past few years, a number of non-OECD countries,
including Chile, China, the Dominican Republic, India, Indonesia,
Mozambique, Panama and Peru, adopted the policy of taxing foreigners on the sale of interests in foreign entities that hold, directly or indirectly, the shares of resident companies. 85 While the background
to these policy developments may be very diverse, 86 what is likely
common among them is the use of active offshore markets to channel
investments into these jurisdictions, making tax avoidance through
indirect transfers a natural strategy.
6.2.2 Specific and general anti-avoidance rules
in taxing indirect transfers
The current approaches to taxing indirect transfers illustrate a
well-known dichotomy in legal design for anti-avoidance, namely
the use of specific anti-avoidance rules (SAARs) versus general
anti-avoidance rules (GAARs). The crucial distinction is that under a
SAAR, the content of the legal rule applicable to the relevant circumstances is specified ahead of time, so that it is clear what the outcome
of applying the rule will be. By contrast, GAARs tend to be statements
of principle, and how the legal standard is applied can be known only
after the fact. India’s policy illustrates the SAAR approach. The 2012
amendment of the Income Tax Act of India provided that “any share
or interest in a company or entity registered or incorporated outside
India shall be deemed to be … situated in India, if the share or interest derives, directly or indirectly, its value substantially from the assets
located in India.” Therefore, the transfer of such shares would result in
the realization of income accruing or arising in India and taxable to a
non-resident transferor. 87 In contrast, China determines the taxability
85
For Mozambique, see IMF Spillovers Report, supra note 7, at 70;
for the other countries, see Wei Cui, “Taxing Indirect Transfers: Improving an Instrument for Stemming Tax and Legal Base Erosion,” supra note
20, 654-656.
86
In India, for example, the policy developed as a consequence of the
Vodafone case, adjudicated by India’s Supreme Court and provoking parliamentary action. In China, by contrast, the taxation of indirect transfers was
launched by a piece of informal administrative guidance.
87
It has been proposed that “substantially” be defined to mean 50 per
cent or more of the total value of a company’s assets.
168
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
of an indirect transfer on the basis of an ex post determination. Under
the relevant administrative guidance, 88 in cases where “an offshore
investor makes abusive uses of organizational forms or arrangements
indirectly to transfer the equity interest in a Chinese resident enterprise,
and such arrangements are without a reasonable business purpose and
entered into to avoid enterprise income tax obligations,” tax agencies
are authorized to “re-characterize an equity transfer according to its
business substance, and disregard the existence of the offshore holding
company which is used for tax planning purposes.” That is to say, only
a tax authority can determine the taxability of an indirect transfer, and
such determination is to be made explicitly on the basis of a finding of
tax avoidance motives. 89 The statutory basis of this determination has
been attributed to the GAAR in China’s Enterprise Income Tax Law. 90
Using the GAAR to deal with potentially abusive indirect transfers has turned out to be unsatisfactory in China in many respects, for
88
Guoshuihan [2009] No. 698 (often referred to as “Circular 698”),
Notice on Strengthening the Management of Enterprise Income Tax Collection on Proceeds from Equity Transfers by Non-resident Enterprises (promulgated by State Administration of Taxation (SAT), China, 2009). Circular
698 has largely been supplanted by SAT Public Notice [2015] 7, issued on 6
February 2015. Public Notice No. 7, relying on the statutory GAAR, extends
China’s policy of taxing indirect transfers to non-resident companies’ gains
on indirect transfers of movable property and immovable property, in addition to ownership interests in Chinese resident companies.
89
This, ironically, implies that there is no legal basis for requiring
transferors to report indirect transfers. Circular 698, a piece of informal
administrative guidance, purported to impose such a legal obligation. The
SAT changed this position when it issued Public Notice No. 7 in 2015, which
eliminated the obligation of transferors to report indirect transfers to the
Chinese tax authorities.
90
Enterprise Income Tax Law, Article 47 (2008) (China). The statutory
language provides: “Where an enterprise enters into [an] arrangement without reasonable commercial purpose and this results in a reduction of taxable gross income or taxable income, tax agencies shall have the authority
to make adjustments using appropriate methods.” An “arrangement without
a reasonable commercial purpose” has been defined as one “the primary
purpose of which is to reduce, avoid or defer tax payments.” See regulation on the Implementation of the Enterprise Income Tax Law, Article 120
(2008) (China).
169
Wei Cui
the fundamental reason that indirect transfers of shares of Chinese
companies occur too often. Many of the entities used in offshore structures for investing into China neither serve substantial functions nor
display a bona fide, operational business purpose. In this context, the
determination that many of the holding companies serve no genuine
business purpose, or that whatever business purpose they serve pales
in comparison to the potential tax savings through indirect transfers,
can be made in a much more routine fashion than case-by-case examinations permit. 91 Furthermore, overreliance on GAARs creates too
many opportunities for negotiation between taxpayers and authorities. An industry of tax advisers on indirect transfers has emerged,
whose routine tool of trade is to persuade foreign parties who have
made indirect transfers first to hire them to report the transfers, and
then to pay them literally to “negotiate” with Chinese tax authorities
on the taxability of the transfers, often regardless of whether the position of non-taxability has any merit.
These phenomena are consistent with the theory that, when a
type of transaction which the law wishes to regulate occurs often, it is
socially optimal to spell out the content of the law ahead of time, thus
minimizing the costs of interpreting the law for regulated subjects,
legal advisers and enforcement personnel. 92 Thus SAARs are likely to
be a superior way of dealing with the majority of indirect transfers,
while a GAAR should be reserved for the relatively rare cases that are
not properly dealt with by SAARs.
However, the existing SAARs adopted by various countries for
taxing indirect transfers —in Australia, Canada and Japan for real
property holding companies, and in India for all companies that hold
sufficient assets in India— are subject to several objections. One is that
many of them do not exempt publicly traded companies, even though
such companies are unlikely to be formed for tax avoidance purposes
91
There are reports of a backlog of indirect transfer cases across China,
in which foreign entities have reported indirect transfers already carried out,
are prepared to make tax payments, but are kept waiting indefinitely by local
tax authorities who have yet to make the determination that the transfers
are taxable.
92
See Louis Kaplow, “Rules versus Standards: An Economic Analysis,”
(1992) Vol. 42, No. 3 Duke Law Journal, at 557.
170
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
(and therefore taxing the transfers of their shares are unnecessary for
maintaining the integrity of source-based taxation). 93 Another objection is that, typically under these rules, transfers of shares of foreign
entities by non-residents are treated as giving rise to items of per se
taxable income: any capital gains on such transfers are explicitly stipulated to have a domestic source.
In Canada, for example, if foreign company A derives more
than 50 per cent of the fair market value of its shares directly or indirectly from real or immovable property situated in Canada, then the
shares of A constitute “taxable Canadian property,” and any capital
gains realized on the disposition of shares of A are deemed to arise
in Canada. Assuming that A is wholly owned by another foreign
company, B, and B has no assets other than the shares of A, the shares
of B would also constitute “taxable Canadian property.” Any capital
gains realized on the disposition of the shares of B are therefore also
taxable income in Canada, and are legally distinct from the capital
gains that have accrued to or been realized on the shares of A. If the
capital gains on the disposition of the shares of A (by B) have been
taxed in Canada, that does not prevent the capital gains realized on the
disposition of the shares of B (by its shareholder(s)) from being taxed
in Canada (or vice versa).
Interestingly, neither Australia, Canada or Japan, nor the
Commentaries to the United Nations and OECD Model Conventions
has addressed this problem of multiple taxation arising from the taxation of indirect transfers of real estate. Nor do they (or the United
States, in its law taxing the transfer of United States companies that
hold United States real property) deal with the issue of proportionality:
if the shares of a holding company derive only 50 per cent of their fair
market value from domestic assets, under most of the existing SAARs,
all of the capital gains realized on the sale of the shares are taxable
in the country of the location of the underlying assets. Although the
recent “Shome Report” in India recommends that any gain realized
on a taxable indirect transfer should be taxed only in proportion to
the value of the Indian assets relative to the entity’s global assets, this
93
See section 3.3 above. China’s policy of taxing indirect transfers was
refined in 2015 to exempt the transfers of shares of publicly traded non-resident
companies as a result of SAT Public Notice No. 7. See supra note 88.
171
Wei Cui
is still different from taxing the gain on the transfer only to the extent
attributable to gains realized on the underlying Indian assets. 94
6.2.3 Multiple taxation and other implementation issues
Are governments justified in their indifference to these problems? One
view is that the decision on how many layers of intermediate companies are interposed between the domestic asset and ultimate investors
is in the control of the taxpayers, as are decisions to make dispositions
at different levels. If governments are wary of convoluted and opaque
offshore structures to begin with, they will have no motivation to go
out of their way to make sure that tax is neutral with respect to the
choice of organizational structure in offshore corporate groups. 95
While this argument is probably correct in itself, there is an
important competing consideration. As discussed in section 4 above,
taxing foreigners on capital gains raises significant challenges for
enforcement. If the tax on indirect transfers leads to arbitrary tax
consequences because of unmitigated multiple taxation, taxpayers
may respond not by simplifying offshore corporate structures, but by
non-compliance and evasion. If a government wants to maintain the
credibility of its anti-avoidance regime without committing indefinite
resources to enforcement, it should try to maximize voluntary compliance. Rationalizing the rules for taxing indirect transfers —including
by mitigating the multiple taxation of the same economic gain—would
seem to be one strategy for increasing voluntary compliance.
Notably, China’s policy for taxing indirect transfers, though
problematic in terms of adopting an approach of case-by-case determination, in fact suggests a solution to the problems characterizing
the existing SAARs. In China, indirect transfers become taxable only
after they have been determined by tax authorities to be, in economic
substance, direct transfers. The layers of offshore holding companies,
94
Expert Committee (2012) (India), Draft Report on Retrospective
Amendments Relating to Indirect Transfer, available at http://www.incometaxindia.gov.in/Lists/Press%20Releases/Attachments/21/Draft_Report.pdf.
95
Advanced income tax systems tend to aim to be neutral with respect
to such choices when the structures are domestic or “onshore,” adopting
special regimes such as corporate consolidation and disregarding intragroup
transactions.
172
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
instead of creating separately and distinctly taxable assets under
Chinese law, must be disregarded. This implies that if the shares of
a Chinese company are treated as having been disposed of indirectly
through the transfer of an offshore entity, the fact that the indirect
transfer has been subject to tax should be reflected by adjusting the
tax cost or basis for the Chinese company’s shares. 96 This eliminates
the possibility of taxing the same economic gain multiple times as a
result of multiple layers of indirect transfers. Moreover, the tax on an
indirect transfer would necessarily always be proportional. The source
country will get to tax only any gain represented by the excess of:
(a) the portion of the purchase price paid on the indirect transfer that
is allocable to the shares of the target company in the source country
regarded as transferred indirectly; over (b) the tax basis, for purposes
of the source country, of such shares of the target company. 97
Overall, it seems possible to improve on all existing practices
for taxing indirect transfers by taking the SAAR approach (if indirect transfers occur frequently), while modifying it to incorporate the
Chinese approach of treating all indirect share sales as sales of the
underlying domestic assets. 98 To implement this approach consistently can be technically complex, and adjusting the tax basis of assets
held by an entity to reflect the transfers of interests in the entity by its
owners (so as to avoid multiple taxation of the same economic gain)
has only recently become feasible for entities with a large number of
96
For example, suppose that foreign investor S forms an offshore company P with equity capital of 200. P, in turn, contributes 200 of equity capital
to Chinese company Q. When the value of Q shares grows from the initial
value of 200 to 250, S sells the shares of P for 250 to buyer B. If China decides
to disregard the existence of P to tax S on the sale, and S is liable for tax on
the gain of 50, then the tax basis or cost of Q shares in the hands of P, and of B,
should each be adjusted to 250. If either P disposes Q shares now for 250, or
B disposes of P shares for 250, there should be no further tax for either P or B.
97
In more technical terms, disregarding an offshore entity and taxing
an indirect transfer is essentially a matter of treating a sale of shares (of the
offshore entity) as a sale of underlying assets (that is to say, the shares of a
target resident company).
98
This is discussed as the “ex ante, look-through” approach in Wei Cui,
“Taxing Indirect Transfers: Improving an Instrument for Stemming Tax and
Legal Base Erosion,” supra note 20, section V.
173
Wei Cui
owners in the United States through specialized accounting software. 99
However, if publicly listed entities are excluded from a tax on indirect transfers, such that most taxable indirect transfers involve only
entities with few owners, the complexity may be manageable. And the
exclusion of shares of publicly listed entities from a tax on indirect
transfers is independently justifiable, as they are unlikely to be used
mainly for tax avoidance purposes.
One final issue that deserves mention is that the policy of taxing
indirect transfers, when implemented by a number of source countries, increases the likelihood that a single share transfer may be taxable in multiple source countries, for example, because subsidiaries in
different countries are indirectly transferred when a holding company
is sold. The tax authorities in the different source countries may have
different assessments of the amount of gain attributable to their country, which may lead to taxation of the same gain by multiple source
countries. 100 Notably, there is currently no international arrangement
for source countries to coordinate their taxes in such situations 101 —
not even in a post-BEPS environment, given that the OECD project on
BEPS did not identify taxation of non-residents’ capital gains as being
an important factor in dealing with base erosion.
6 .3
Issuance of new shares and corporate reorganizations
Sometimes, taxpayers may try to avoid a tax on the sale of shares
(whether direct or indirect) by having the target company issue new
shares to new investors. This may or may not be accompanied by a distribution of the proceeds from the new share issuance to existing shareholders. When it is, there is a barely disguised share sale. But even when
it is not, there can be an effective transfer of the value of the company
99
The author gratefully acknowledges Mr. Ameek Ashok Ponda, adjunct
professor at Harvard Law School, for providing this information.
100
This problem is worsened if, as is likely under traditional practice
in taxing indirect transfers, the source country taxes the entire gain in the
transfer even if only a portion of the gain is attributable to it.
101
The author is grateful to Mr. Peter Barnes, Senior Fellow, Duke University, for providing this information.
174
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
from existing to new shareholders. 102 Such tax planning tactics may be
used within purely domestic contexts as well, and they need to be dealt
with whether used domestically or in cross-border transactions.
Many developed countries adopt tax-deferral regimes for
corporate reorganizations, and businesses are accustomed to using
such regimes to reduce their tax liabilities in mergers and acquisitions. However, to protect the domestic tax base, developed country
corporate reorganization rules tend to impose more stringent requirements when ownership of domestic assets is transferred to or among
non-residents. Developing countries should be equally cautious in
granting deferral treatment for purported reorganizations carried out
among non-residents.
7 .
Taxing former residents on capital gains
The present chapter has mainly focused on capital gains taxation from
a source-country perspective. This section briefly touches on an issue
that properly belongs to the topic of resident country taxation. 103 When
the residence of a taxpayer changes on emigration, the taxing rights of
the former residence State are reduced to those of a source State. In
order to preserve the right to tax gains accrued while the taxpayer is
a resident, many countries impose an “exit tax” (also referred to as
a “departure tax”) and/or a “trailing tax.” Under an exit tax, assets
owned by an emigrant are deemed to be alienated at market value
and reacquired at a cost equal to that value. For instance, under the
Australian domestic law exit tax rules, a person ceasing to be resident
is deemed to dispose of assets other than taxable Australian assets (on
which even non-residents are taxed) at market value.
The last few years have witnessed an expansion in the adoption of exit taxes in OECD countries. In Japan, a law became effective
102
This issue is highlighted in Lee Burns, Honoré Le Leuch and Emil
Sunley, “Transfer of an interest in a mining or petroleum right,” in Philip
Daniel and others, eds., Resources without Borders, supra note 47.
103
For a more detailed discussion, see Jinyan Li and Francesco Avella,
“Article 13: Capital Gains,” supra note 74, section 2.1.8; Hugh J. Ault and
Brian J. Arnold, Comparative Income Taxation: A Structural Analysis, supra
note 17, Part IV, chapter A, section 2.1.
175
Wei Cui
on 1 July 2015, to require permanent residents with Japanese-source
financial assets of at least 100 million yen (US$ 840,000) to pay an
exit tax on any appreciation of the assets if they leave Japan to take
up residence elsewhere. 104 The legislation was driven by concerns that
wealthy Japanese individuals were moving to countries with no capital
gains tax and selling assets that had experienced significant appreciation while they were held in Japan. Similarly, Spain introduced an exit
tax at the beginning of 2015, applicable to taxpayers who have been
Spanish tax residents for at least 10 out of the 15 years prior to their
departure from the country, and who hold large fortunes — specifically, substantial shareholdings the market value of which exceeds
€4,000,000 (or €1,000,000, if the total shareholdings exceed 25 per cent
of the relevant company). Unrealized gain on such holdings is subject
to tax, regardless of the location of the investments.
In the absence of coordination between the treaty States, a
problem regarding the potential double taxation of the accrued gain
may arise. This occurs when the property is actually alienated and the
current residence State taxes the entire gain, computed by reference to
the historical cost basis, which includes the gain that has been subject
to the exit tax in the former residence State. Countries with exit taxes,
such as Australia, Canada, the Netherlands and the United States, may
include special provisions in their tax treaties to resolve the problem
of double taxation. This is usually realized by allowing the taxpayer
to use a tax cost for the asset in the new residence State equal to its
market value at the time of the change in residence. 105
Trailing taxes are taxes levied after a change of residence on
assets that would normally not otherwise be taxed in the hands of a
non-resident, but that are usually taxed under domestic law if alienated within a given period following the change of residence (generally five to ten years). A country may provide for both a trailing tax
104
William Hoke, “Cabinet Proposes Exit Tax on Departing Permanent
Residents,” (2015) Vol. 77, Tax Notes International, 317. Persons subject to the
exit tax include anyone who has been a resident of Japan for at least 5 years
during the 10 years immediately before the date of departure.
105
Indeed, under its domestic law, Australia deems a person who
becomes a resident to acquire assets other than taxable Australian assets at
market value on becoming a resident. Canadian rules are largely similar.
176
Taxation of non-residents’ capital gains
and an exit tax if a taxpayer has an election to be subject to the exit
tax or remain liable to tax for the full gain realized on actual alienation following the change of residence. 106 Special treaty provisions
may also be needed to preserve the taxing rights of the former residence State and prevent double taxation.
8 .
Conclusion
Throughout the discussion in the present chapter, it has not been
assumed that revenue from taxing non-residents on capital gains is
indispensable to many developing countries. 107 Such an assumption
could very well turn out not to be true. For example, in many of the
developing countries that recently led efforts to combat base erosion by
taxing indirect transfers —for example, China, India, Indonesia, Peru
and others —revenue from international taxation in general (not to
mention from capital gains taxation of non-residents in particular) is
likely to represent a very small portion of overall tax revenue. The pursuit of such base protection measures is thus likely to be motivated by
other policy considerations, for example, for maintaining the integrity
and fairness of the tax system. Insofar as the administrative apparatus
of a developing country can handle such taxation in the normal course
of its operation, there should be little that is out of the ordinary.
A core contention of the present chapter is that many of the
conventional arguments for limiting the taxation of non-residents
106
The exit tax introduced in Spain in 2015 has this feature. Taxpayers
can request to defer their exit tax liability if they move to any country which
has a double taxation agreement with Spain and an information exchange
clause. Moreover, if the taxpayer moves, for any reason, to another country in the European Union or the European Economic Area, the gain will
be declarable and taxable in Spain only if they either sell the shares within
10 years of leaving Spain, or if they discontinue residency in the European
Union or the European Economic Area.
107
This can be contrasted with a view expressed in the recent IMF Spillovers Report, whose discussion of capital gains taxation— and the taxation of
indirect transfers in particular—was motivated by its technical assistance
experience, which “provides many examples in which the sums at stake in
international tax issues are large relative to overall revenues [of developing
countries].” See IMF Spillovers Report, supra note 7, at 1.
177
Wei Cui
on capital gains are weak. The conceptual case for generally taxing
non-residents on such gains is essentially as strong as for any other
form of source-based taxation. For example, the claim that only
immovable property has enough of an “economic connection” with
the source country is hard to comprehend, except as an unconstructive attempt to gloss over the traditional political sensitiveness of
foreign ownership of domestic land. Just as significantly, as discussed
in section 5, even Article 13 of the United Nations Model Convention
may have started with a baseline too close to the non-taxation of capital gains, such that source countries either are allocated taxing rights
over only a few enumerated categories of capital gains or, when they
claim broader taxing rights, must struggle against the textual interpretation of the model convention. Insofar as the norms expressed by
the United Nations Model Convention matter, one needs to be aware
of this special bias against source-country taxation on capital gains.
However, there is obviously little point in declaring a
taxing right over capital gains of non-residents if the tax cannot be
enforced. Because many developed countries have abandoned taxing
non-residents on capital gains, they cannot be viewed as experts in
implementing the tax. Whether developed countries can succeed in
enforcing the tax— and more importantly, foster a culture of compliance with it—is yet to be seen. But it is worth stressing that the conventional assumption that capital gains of non-residents should not be
taxed is surely not conducive to producing compliance. Moreover, too
much of the international tax discussion over recent decades has been
centred on whether non-residents should be taxed on capital gains,
rather than on how they are to be taxed. Yet the question of how to
tax capital gains (discussed in section 3 above) should arguably matter
just as much to the legitimacy of such a tax as the question of whether
to tax.
178