[go: up one dir, main page]

Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The average tree value for hypergraph games

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Mathematical Methods of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider transferable utility cooperative games (TU games) with limited cooperation introduced by a hypergraph communication structure, the so-called hypergraph games. A hypergraph communication structure is given by a collection of coalitions, the hyperlinks of the hypergraph, for which it is assumed that only coalitions that are hyperlinks or connected unions of hyperlinks are able to cooperate and realize their worth. We introduce the average tree value for hypergraph games, which assigns to each player the average of the player’s marginal contributions with respect to a particular collection of rooted spanning trees of the hypergraph, and study its properties. We show that the average tree value is stable on the subclass of superadditive cycle-free hypergraph games. We also provide axiomatizations of the average tree value on the subclasses of cycle-free hypergraph games, hypertree games, and cycle hypergraph games.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The position value for graph games is first defined in Meessen (1988) and later studied and axiomatized by Borm, Owen, and Tijs, cf. Borm et al. (1992).

  2. A collection of coalitions \(\mathcal B\) on N is a building set on N if (i) for any \(S,Q\in \mathcal B\) such that \(S\cap Q\ne \emptyset \) it holds that \(S\cup Q\in \mathcal B\), and (ii) \(\{i\}\in \mathcal B\) for all \(i\in \mathcal B\), and therefore, it is also a union stable system, cf. Algaba et al. (2001).

  3. This boils down to player i being a null player in the TU game \(v^H\). Such player is also known as superfluous player in, e.g., Slikker and van den Nouweland (2001).

References

  • Algaba E, Bilbao JM, Borm P, López JJ (2001) The Myerson value for union stable systems. Math Methods Oper Res 54(3):359–371

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Borm P, Owen G, Tijs S (1992) On the position value for communication situation. SIAM J Discret Math 5(3):305–320

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Herings PJJ, van der Laan G, Talman AJJ (2008) The average tree solution for cycle-free graph games. Games Econ Behav 62:77–92

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Herings PJJ, van der Laan G, Talman AJJ, Yang Z (2010) The average tree solution for cooperative games with communication structure. Games Econ Behav 68:626–633

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Koshevoy G, Talman AJJ (2014) Solution concepts for games with general coalitional structure. Math Soc Sci 68(1):19–30

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Meessen R (1988) Communication games, Master’s thesis, Department of Mathematics, University of Nijmegen, The Netherlands. (in Dutch)

  • Mishra D, Talman AJJ (2010) A characterization of the average tree solution for tree games. Int J Game Theory 39:105–111

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson RB (1977) Graphs and cooperation in games. Math Oper Res 2:225–229

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson RB (1980) Conference structures and fair allocation rules. Int J Game Theory 9:169–182

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Owen G (1986) Values of graph-restricted games, SIAM. J. Algebraic Discrete Methods 7:210–220

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Selçuk Ö, Suzuki T, Talman AJJ (2013) Equivalence and axiomatization of solutions for cooperative games with circular communication structure. Econ Lett 121(3):428–431

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley LS (1953) A value for \(n\)-person games. In: Kuhn H, Tucker AW (eds) Contributions to the Theory of Games II. Princeton, Princeton University Press, pp 307–317

    Google Scholar 

  • Slikker M, van den Nouweland A (2001) Social and economic networks in cooperative game theory. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • van den Brink R (2012) Efficiency and collusion neutrality in cooperative games and networks. Games Econ Behav 76:344–348

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • van den Nouweland A, Borm P, Tijs S (1992) Allocation rules for hypergraph communication situations. Int J Game Theory 20:255–268

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dolf Talman.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The research of Anna Khmelnitskaya was supported by RFBR (Russian Foundation for Basic Research) grant #18-01-00780. Her research was done partially during her stay at the University of Twente, whose hospitality is highly appreciated. The research of Guang Zhang was supported by NSFC (National Natural Science Foundation of China) Grant #71901145.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kang, L., Khmelnitskaya, A., Shan, E. et al. The average tree value for hypergraph games. Math Meth Oper Res 94, 437–460 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-021-00762-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-021-00762-w

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification