[go: up one dir, main page]

Academia.eduAcademia.edu
Factor Tariffs and Income Henry Thompson June 2016 A change in the price of an imported primary factor of production lowers and rearranges output and redistributes income. Consider a factor tariff in a competitive small open economy producing two traded goods combining imported energy with domestic capital and labor. Suppose export production is energy intensive, and import competing production labor intensive. A tariff shifts production toward the import competing good, raises the wage, and lowers the capital return. The present paper shows that under some conditions the decreased import spending can outweigh the decreased value of output. Keywords: Factor tariffs, income, general equilibrium Special thanks go to Leland Yeager, Roy Ruffin, Charlie Sawyer, Tom Osang, and Randy Beard for insightful discussions. Andy Barnett, Olena Ogrokhina, Alex Sarris, and George Chortoreas provided comments as well. Any shortcomings remain with the author. Contact information: Department of Economics, Auburn University AL 36849, 334-844-2910, henry.thompson@auburn.edu 1 Factor Tariffs and Income A tariff on an imported factor of production lowering the import shrinks the production frontier as outputs and domestic factor prices adjust. Consider an economy producing two goods under constant returns with two domestic factors of production and an imported factor. Assume the small open economy is a price taker in international markets for the two traded goods and the imported factor. Assume imported energy is combined with domestic capital and labor to produce an export and an import competing good. Energy is the most intensive or extreme factor in export production, and labor in import competing production. An energy tariff lowers import, shifts production toward the import competing good, and raises the wage. The return to capital falls as it is released from export production. These effects are strengthened if energy and capital are technical complements, a possibility noted in the production literature. The present paper shows that the decrease in energy import spending may outweigh the decrease in output. The potential increase in income depends on substitution and factor intensity between the three inputs as well as the state of the economy. This result is a characteristic of models with many goods and many factors of production, applying to imports of capital or natural resources as well as energy. The first section reviews the fundamental production model of Mundell (1957) with an international factor of production available at an exogenous world price. The second section presents the present comparative static model of Thompson (1983) followed by a section focused on adjustments to a factor tariff. 2 1. A factor tariff, output, and income The literature on an internationally mobile facto of production in general equilibrium models of production for a small open economy includes Kemp (1966), Jones (1967), Chipman (1971), Caves (1971), Jones and Ruffin (1975), Ferguson (1978), Srinivasan (1983), Svensson (1984), and Ethier and Svensson (1986). An increase in the exogenous price of an international factor lowers it import and leads to adjustments in production and domestic factor prices. In a related model, Ruffin (1969) considers an imported intermediate good entering production in fixed proportions. Panagaria (1992) finds a tariff on the intermediate good has an ambiguous effect on utility. The present model finds an analogous ambiguous effect on income based on substitution between the imported factor and two domestic factors of production. Adjustments to a tariff are pictured with the production frontier in Figure 1. Endowments of domestic factors and the level of the imported factor along with the two production functions determine position of the production frontier. The economy produces at point P given the terms of trade tt and the price w1 of the imported factor. Export of good 1 must at least cover factor import spending w1v1 where v1 is the import level. Real income in terms of good 1 is determined at the intercept y0 on the x1 axis. * Figure 1 * Assume the imported factor is energy and export production is energy intensive. An energy tariff reduces import v1 shrinking the production frontier and lowering export production x1. Import competing output x2 may increase as in Figure 1 but both outputs may fall. Increased real income is illustrated at y1 as import spending w1v1 falls more than the value of output. Payments to the three factors exhaust output, x  jpjxj = (1 + t)w1v1 + w2v2 + w3v3, 3 (1) where x  output xj  output of good j pj  price of good j wi  price of factor I v1  import of factor 1 v2, v3  domestic factors endowments t  tariff rate. Income is the value of output less import spending, equivalent to the sum of tariff revenue and domestic factor payments, y = x – w1v1 = tw1v1 + w2v2 + w3v3 (2) where y  income. An increase in the tariff t lowers import and leads to adjustments in outputs and domestic factor prices. The resulting adjustment in income depends on factor intensity and substitution as well as prices, domestic factor endowments, and the tariff rate. 2. Production in general equilibrium with an imported factor This section develops the comparative static model of production with an imported factor of production. Imported energy is utilized in the two sectors according to v1 = ja1jxj for j = 1, 2 where a1j is the flexible cost minimizing input per unit of output. Adjustments occur according to dv1 = j(a1jdxj + xjda1j). Letting the prime ‘ denote percentage change, v1 = j1j(a1j + xj), (3) where a1j  input per unit of output 1j  a1jxj/v1 = industry share of factor 1 in sector j. 4 Homothetic production implies unit inputs a1j are functions of factor prices only. Industry shares of each factor sum to one across goods, jij = 1. The imported factor price f1  (1 + t)w1 changes with a tariff according to df1 = w1dt assuming the exogenous world price w1 is constant, leading to   df1/f1 = dt/(1 + t). (4) where   percentage change in the domestic price of factor 1 due to a tariff. Substitution elasticities reflect adjustments in the factor mix due to changing factor prices. The cross price substitution elasticity of imported factor 1 relative to the price of domestic factor i is the industry share weighted cross price elasticity, 1i  j1j(a1j/wi). The three own substitution elasticities are negative due to Shephard’s lemma and concavity of the cost functions. Linear homogeneity implies elasticities for each input k sum to zero across changes in factor prices, iki = 0. In practice, cross price elasticities are estimated from production or cost functions and the own elasticity is derived. Substitution between two inputs implies positive cross price elasticity. With three factors, one pair may be complements with a negative cross price elasticity. Concavity of the cost function in factor prices requires positive principle minors of the substitution matrix with own effects outweighing cross effects, iikk - ikki > 0 for i, k = 1, 2, 3. The cost minimizing input of the import adjusts according to a1j = 12w2 + 13w3 + 11 expanding import adjustment in (3) to v1 = 12w2 + 13w3 + 11 + j1jxj, where 1i  substitution elasticity of factor 1 relative to price of factor i. 5 (5) Adjustments to changes in domestic factor endowments v2 and v3 similar to (5) are included in the comparative static system (8). Revenue is paid to the factors of production in each sector according to pjxj = (1 + t)w1v1j + w2v2j + w3v3j for j = 1, 2 from (1). Divide by xj to find pricing conditions linking goods and factors, pj = (1 + t)w1a1j + w2a2j + w3a3j. Differentiate to find dpj = w1a1jdt + a2jdw2 + a3jdw3 + [(1 + t)w1da1j + w2da2j + w3da3j]. The bracketed expression disappears due to the cost minimizing envelope property leading to pj = θ1j + θ2jw2 + θ3jw3, (6) where θij  aijwi/pj = factor i share in revenue of good j. Factor shares of each good sum to one across factors due to competitive pricing, iθij = 1. Income y expressed in terms of tariff revenue and factor payments in (2) changes according to y = 1(v1 + T) + 2(v2 + w2) + 3(v3 + w3), (7) where T  (1 + t)/t 1  tw1v1/y = the imported factor income share k  wkvk/y = income share of domestic factor k = 2, 3. Combine conditions for employment in (5), competitive pricing in (6), and income in (7) into the comparative static system (8) with exogenous variables on the right, 6 -1 12 13 λ11 λ12 0 v1 -11 0 22 23 λ21 λ22 0 w2 v2 – 21 0 32 33 λ31 λ32 0 w3 0 θ21 θ31 0 0 0 x1 p1 – θ11 0 θ22 θ32 0 0 0 x2 p2 – θ12 -ϕ1 -ϕ2 -ϕ3 0 0 1 y = v3 – 31 (8) ϕ2v2 + ϕ3v3 + ϕ1T . Factor intensity is critical to the comparative static adjustments. Assume the factor intensity θ11/θ12 > θ21/θ22 > θ31/θ32, (9) with the import the most intensive or extreme factor for good 1, domestic factor v3 extreme in good 2 production, and v2 the middle factor. Define an intensity term between factors 1 and 2 as θ12  θ11θ22 – θ12θ21 > 0 with similar positive intensity terms θ23 and θ13. Factor intensity is also reflected by industry shares in the positive terms λ12, λ13, and λ23. The comparative static model solves for the effects of changes in an exogenous variable in the right hand vector on the endogenous variables with Cramer’s rule. The negative determinant of the system matrix is Δ = -θ23λ23. Assume energy is the extreme factor in export production, labor in import competing production, and capital the middle factor as in (9). Thompson (1983) shows an increase in the international price of the imported factor lowers the import and at least one output, raises the wage, and lowers the capital return given the present factor intensity. The production frontier is concave in the relative price of outputs. Factor import cannot be positively related to prices of both goods. An increase in the capital endowment raises factor import and export production, and lowers import competing production. An increase in the labor endowment has opposite effects. The following sections extend these results to include the effect of a factor tariff on income. 7 3. The effects of a factor tariff A tariff lowers import in the general equilibrium system (8) according to v1/ = -Δ32/Δ < 0, (10) where Δ32 is the determinant of the model with three domestic factors. Neoclassical concavity and cost minimization imply Δ32 < 0 as shown by Chang (1979) and Thompson (1985). The implication of (10) is that demand for the import slopes downward allowing all markets in the economy to adjust. The effects of a tariff on domestic factor prices depend only on factor intensity, w2/ = -θ13/θ23 < 0 (11) w3/ = θ12/θ23 > 0, where the intensity terms are positive due to (9). The wage w3 rises with a tariff as capital is released from export production increasing the marginal product of labor in the import competing sector. The return w2 to middle factor capital falls as it is released from export production. If imported energy were the middle factor, both domestic factor prices would fall. Output adjustments on the shrinking production frontier are x1/ = (λ12σ3 – λ22σ4)/ (12) x2/ = (λ21σ4 – λ11σ3)/, where σ3  (θ13 + θ23)σ21 + θσ23, σ4  (θ12 – θ23)σ31 + θσ32, and θ  (θ12 + θ13). Thompson (1983) shows at least one of these output adjustment must be negative. Income adjusts according to y/ = ϕ1(T + v1/) + ϕ2(w2/) + ϕ3(w3/). (13) The first term in (13) reflects the ambiguous change in tariff revenue tw1v1 that would be summarized by the import elasticity. The second and third terms are weighted effects of 8 domestic factor price adjustments in (11). An increase in income is favored by a lower tariff level or higher T, inelastic import demand, a higher labor income share ϕ3, stronger import intensity θ12 relative to middle factor 2, and stronger intensity between the domestic factors θ23. To illustrate the potential of a tariff to raise income, consider an economy facing unit world prices w1 = p1 = p2 = 1 with unit factor endowments v2 = v3 = 1. Equilibrium levels are outputs x1 = 2.50 and x2 = 0.83, domestic factor prices w2 = 0.77 and w3 = 1.10, and energy import v1 = 1.33. Assume tariff rate t = 0.10 generating tariff revenue tw1v1 = 0.13. The value of output x = 3.33 in (1) less import spending equals income y = 2.00 in (2). The factor share and industry share matrices are θ11 θ12 0.55 0.11 λ11 λ12 0.94 0.06 θ21 θ22 = 0.23 0.23 λ21 λ22 = 0.75 0.25 θ31 θ32 0.66 λ31 λ32 0.50 , 0.22 0.50 (14) consistent with the factor intensity in (9). Cost minimizing inputs aij equal the derived factor shares in (14). Assume the substitution elasticities 11 12 13 -0.9 -0.6 1.5 21 22 23 = -0.2 -0.3 0.5 31 32 33 0.2 -0.4 , 0.2 (15) satisfying concavity conditions with energy and capital technical complements. These elasticities are consistent with the static equilibrium and would be derived as industry share weighted averages of substitution elasticities in each sector. Sector elasticities in practice are derived from estimates of production or cost functions. The elasticities in (15) can be derived in the present specification from the quadratic cost functions in the two sectors c1 = -w12 – w22 – w32 + 0.86w1w2 + 1.72w1w3 + 0.89w2w3 and c2 = -w12 – w22 – w32 + 0.29w1w2 + 1.72w1w3 + 1.41w2w3. 9 Solving the resulting comparative static model (8) for a change in the factor tariff, energy import adjusts according to v1/ = -0.33. The elastic domestic factor price adjustments are w2/ = -3.35 and w3/ = 1.00. An increase in the tariff induces substitution toward labor, raising the wage w3 as substitution away from complementary capital strongly lowers the capital return w2. Elastic adjustments in outputs x1/ = -3.48 and x2/ = 5.22 shift production toward import competition favoring its extreme factor labor. Income increases with the tariff according to y/ = 0.05 due to elastic adjustments in outputs and domestic factor prices and the inelastic decrease in imported energy. 5. Conclusion The effects of a factor tariff in a competitive small open economy depend on factor intensity substitution, factor shares of income, and the state of the economy. A factor tariff lowers import spending and shrinks the production frontier. When there are three or more factors of production, a potential increase in income arises due to the flexibility of substitution and outputs. In the present model with three factors and two goods, a tariff on imported energy favors the import competing sector and raises the price of its intensive factor. Export production falls as does the return to the middle intensity factor. Under some conditions, factor import spending falls more than the reduced value of output resulting in increased income. If imported energy is a complement with capital, the higher domestic price of energy strongly reduces capital demand and its return. Strong substitution of labor for energy generates a large increase in labor demand. The inelastic reduction in energy import coupled with elastic adjustments in outputs and domestic factor prices account for an increase in income. 10 Other arguments favoring a tariff can be mentioned. For a large economy, a tariff lowers the international price raising the possibility of a Metzler (1949) paradox with a lower price including the tariff. Thompson (2016) shows a tariff can raise income in an economy that has import competing domestic factor supply. Facing a foreign monopoly, a tariff transforms foreign profit into tariff revenue. Finally, a tariff reduces any externalities associated with the imported factor. 11 References Caves, Richard (1971) International corporations: The industrial economics of international investment, Economica 38, 1-27. Chang, Winston (1979) Some theorems of trade and general equilibrium with many goods and factors, Econometrica 47, 790-26. Chipman, John (1971) International trade with capital mobility: a substitution theorem, in Trade, Balance of Payments, and Growth, edited by Jagdish Bhagwati, Ron Jones, Robert Mundell, and Jaroslav Vanek, North Holland. Ethier, Bill and Lars Svensson (1986) The theorems of international trade and factor mobility, Journal of International Economics 20, 21-42. Ferguson, David (1978) International capital mobility and comparative advantage: The twocountry, two-factor case, Journal of International Economics 8, 373-96. Jones, Ron (1967) International capital movements and the theory of tariffs and trade, Quarterly Journal of Economics 81, 1-38. Jones, Ron and Roy Ruffin (1975) Trade patterns with capital mobility, in Current Economic Problems, edited by M. Parkin and A. Nobay, Cambridge. Kemp, Murray (1966) The gains from international trade and investment: A neo-Heckscher-Ohlin approach, American Economic Review 56, 788-809. Metzler, Lloyd (1949) Tariffs, international demand, and domestic prices, Journal of Political Economy 57, 345-51. Mundell, Robert (1957) International trade and factor mobility, American Economic Review 47, 321-35. Panagariya, Arvind (1992) Input tariffs, duty drawbacks and tariff reforms, Journal of International Economics 26, 132-47. Ruffin, Roy (1969) Tariffs, intermediate goods, and domestic protection, American Economic Review 49, 261-9. Srinivasan, T.N. (1983) International factor movements, commodity trade and commercial policy in a specific factors model, Journal of International Economics 12, 389-12. Svensson, Lars (1984) Factor trade and goods trade, Journal of International Economics 16, 36578. 12 Thompson, Henry (1983) Trade and international factor mobility, Atlantic Economic Journal 11, 45-8. Thompson, Henry (1985) Complementarity in a simple general equilibrium production model, Canadian Journal of Economics 18, 616-21. Thompson, Henry (2016) A tariff on a productive factor with import competing supply, Journal of International Trade and Economic Development (2016) 71-9. 13 x2 tt P w 1v1 y0 y1 Figure 1. A factor tariff and income 14 x1