[go: up one dir, main page]

Skip to main content
Log in

Hedonic Valuation with Translating Amenities: Mountain Pine Beetles and Host Trees in the Colorado Front Range

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In hedonic valuation studies the policy-relevant environmental quality attribute of interest is often costly to measure, especially under pronounced spatial and temporal variability. However, in many cases this attribute affects home prices and consumer preferences solely through its impact on a readily observable, spatially delineated, and time-invariant feature of the physical landscape. We label such a feature a “translating amenity.” We show that under certain conditions changes in the marginal effect of such amenities on home values over time can be used to draw inference on the implicit price of the unobserved environmental quality of interest. We illustrate this approach in the context of a repeat-sales model and the recently intensified outbreak of the Mountain Pine Beetle in the Colorado Front Range.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To be clear, Phaneuf et al. (2008) specify utility as \(U=U\left( x\left( q\right) , h\left( \mathbf {a},q\right) , z, \epsilon \right) \), where \(h\left( . \right) \) is the housing function, \(\mathbf {a}\) is a vector of housing attributes, and \(\epsilon \) denotes unobserved heterogeneity. The term \(x\left( q \right) \) refers to local recreational opportunities, which are not relevant in our case. Our notation also differs in that we label the housing function as \(H\left( . \right) \), and the housing attributes as \(\mathbf {x}\). We also include preference parameters (\(\varvec{\gamma }\) and \(\varvec{\theta }\)), which are not explicitly captured in their specification. In contrast, unobserved heterogeneity does not play a major role in our context, so their error term \(\epsilon \) is absent from our model. However, both models include environmental quality \(q\) and the numeraire commodity \(z\).

  2. If the relevant policy intervention directly targets trees instead of beetles, for example via the removal of diseased pines, \(\alpha \left( q \right) \) simplifies to \(\alpha \). In that case \(q\) would be the number or biomass of dead trees, and host trees at large would still be the TA.

  3. This is why \(h\) is not a proxy variable in a formal econometric sense, as it can still influence home values independently of the unobserved quality variable \(q\). As discussed e.g. in Wooldridge (2012), p. 67, a genuine proxy variable must be redundant in the underlying structural relationship if the unobserved variable for which it fills in were actually included in the model. We specifically abstract from such a case by allowing trees to affect home values even in absence of MPB damage.

  4. We assume for now that all other components in the price function difference out.

  5. For the less common linear price function with additive attributes we have \(\frac{\partial P\left( . \right) }{\partial f\left( . \right) }=1\), and would thus obtain \(P_{t}-P_{t-1}=\left( \theta _1-\theta _2\right) \left[ \alpha \left( q_{t}\right) -\alpha \left( q_{t-1}\right) \right] h\approx \beta \left( q \right) h\). That is, the coefficient on \(h\) would directly approximate the implicit price of \(q\).

  6. Naturally, the assumption of time-invariance of both characteristics and preferences is crucial for this advantage to be properly exploited. Since the time periods for our analysis are relatively short (9–12 years) we do not expect pronounced shifts in underlying preferences in our data. In addition, we control for changes in home structures by eliminating properties with documented home improvements from our sample, as discussed in the empirical section.

  7. For further details and motivation for this tri-valued indicator approach see, for example, Palmquist (1982) and Case et al. (2006).

  8. Conceptually, both \(\xi \) and \(\varvec{\zeta }\) can be interpreted as elements of the reduced form parameter vector \(\varvec{\delta }\) in our theoretical model [Eq. (1)].

  9. In 2006, 2007, and 2012, the three worst wildfire seasons in history, wildfires consumed over 9 million acres in the US (National Interagency Fire Center 2012).

  10. A full-fledged damage analysis via satellite imagery and visual damage coding by a remote sensing expert for all included properties in our data would have been infeasible given resource constraints and our relatively large sample size. In addition, high-quality satellite images covering our entire research area are only available for a select few years of our research period, which would hamper a seamless analysis of the MPB damage trajectory over time. The ADS, in turn, uses fly-overs and hand-drawn polygons to identify infested areas. Each polygon, in turn, receives an estimate for the total number of infested trees within its boundary. Price et al. (2010) use these polygons for their study of MPB damage and property values in neighboring Grant County to compute the expected number of diseased trees within different perimeters of each residence. Using a cross-sectional regression model with spatial lags they estimate the marginal implicit price per tree for each perimeter. They also report that the accuracy of this polygon-based damage information ranges between 61 and 79 %, based on a 2005 FS assessment. However, MPB damage was more confined and localized in the mid-90s to mid-2010s (the time span of their analysis), generally allowing for tighter, stand-specific polygons. This accuracy has suffered in recent years, as polygons had to be drawn at ever larger scales to keep pace with the dramatic acceleration and expansion of the infestation. For our time frame, which reaches to 2011, a polygon-based estimation approach did not produce reliable results. Too many homes are included within the same large-scale polygon, and thus receive identical damage metrics in the last four to five years of our research period. In addition, a comparison with satellite images for sub-areas and years for which they are available revealed a high degree of imprecision between polygon boundaries and actual damage. The results of the polygon-based version of our model are available upon request.

  11. A comparison of the repeat-sales sample with the general sample (including single-transaction residences) based on basic home features did not reveal any systematic differences between the two groups. We thus conclude that repeat-sales properties do not constitute a systematically different segment of the housing market.

  12. Specifically, we used release 2 of the ESRI StreetMap Premium/NAVTEQ USA software package to geo-code each property. A majority of geocodes provided by this package (greater than 88 % for both counties) are based on exact property centroids, as opposed to uniformly assigned street segments.

  13. Specifically, our GIS layer includes the following groups of pine species: White/Red/Jack, Lodgepole, Longleaf/Slash, Loblolly/Shortleaf, Pinyon/Juniper, Ponderosa, and Western White. Of these, the relevant species for Colorado are Lodgepole, Ponderosa, and Limber (a member of the Western White group). All of them are equally susceptible to an MPB attack (personal communication with Dr. Barbara Bentz, research entomologist at the US Forest Service. Logan, Utah). Since our host tree indicator \(h_i\) is also indiscriminant over these species, the accuracy rating for correctly identifying any host tree community likely exceeds that for specific pine types.

  14. We matched home sales with fire damage based on the assumption that the fire season begins on May 1 of each year. Thus, a home that sold before May in a given calendar year is paired with fire events for the preceding calendar year for the 1-year binary indicator. The remaining indicators for temporally further removed fire occurrences are adjusted in analogous fashion.

  15. The diminished effect of fires within 1 km from a home compared to the 5 km buffer is likely related to the small sample size (less then 1 % of observations) for this distance category. The absence of a stronger effect may also be linked to burn visibility. Stetler et al. (2010) find that fires at any distance from a residence (even 0–5 km) have limited effect on sales prices if the burned area is not visible for a given property. In our case, it is possible that nearby burns are less visible than burns in the 1–5 km range, depending on the morphology of the local landscape. In addition, home owners may perceive a lower future fire risk to their property if close-by fuel has been consumed by a recent fire, which could counter-act the direct amenity effect of nearby burns. This risk-reducing effect may be absent or even reversed for burns in the 1–5 km range. Third, there may be a counter-balancing positive amenity effect related to better views that open up in the short run for close-to-home burns (see Hansen and Naughton 2013). Similarly, the insignificant effect of burns within 5 km, but closer in time (within 1 or 3 years of sale) are likely due to small sample size (less than 0.5 % of observations).

  16. Area 5 (southern Fort Collins, Loveland) produces a counterintuitive positive effect for age-related depreciation. We attribute this to the many new constructions that occurred in that area during our time span. This can produce a large value for \({a_i,}_{\left( t^{\prime },t^0\right) }\), even for pairs of sales that are closely positioned in time, with little to no age-related depreciation. A large enough share of such properties in the data can then produce a positive estimate for the depreciation coefficient \(\delta _s\).

    Table 6 Estimation results for HT and fire effects
  17. Specifically, a home that experienced a recent fire within 5 km between sales appreciated, on average, by \(\left( exp(-0.042)-1 \right) = 4.1\,\%\) less than an otherwise comparable property without a recent fire history.

  18. Estimates from such “erroneously pooled” models are available upon request.

  19. As is the case with most hedonic studies, our model cannot distinguish between actually experienced and expected MPB effects on home prices. Our estimated price trajectories and loss estimates include both components. However, since our time series of home sales starts well before the explosive expansion of the MPB, we are confident that our estimates captures the full MPB effect, that is actual plus expected.

  20. The full set of results for Spokane are available upon request.

  21. This rate is composed of a county-wide conversion factor of 0.0796 that translates assessed market value into “tax-assessed value”(Larimer County Treasurer 2013a) We found the assessed market value to be generally very close to observed sales prices for homes sold in 2011 in our data. Thus, implicitly departing from our predicted sales prices for 2011 before assessing these tax rates appears justified. A district-specific “mill levy” is then applied to this taxable amount. In 2011, mill levies for Estes Park varied between 7 and 8 % for most tax districts (Larimer County Assessor 2013b). We use a mill levy of 7.5 % for our calculations.

    Table 9 Predicted losses for homes with host trees within 0.1 km

References

  • Anselin L, Lozano-Gracia N (2008) Errors in variables and spacial effects in hedonic house price models of ambient air quality. Empir Econ 34:5–34

  • Bentz B, Jacques R, Fettig C, Hansen E, Hayes J, Hicke J, Kelsey R, Negrn J, Seybold S (2010) Climate change and bark beetles of the Western United States and Canada: direct and indirect effects. Bioscience 60:602–613

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle K, Kuminoff N, Zhang C, Devanney M, Bell K (2010) Does a property-specific environmental health risk create a “neighborhood” housing price stigma? Arsenic in private well water. Water Resour Res 46(W03):507

    Google Scholar 

  • Carbone J, Hallstrom D, Smith V (2006) Can natural experiments measure behavioral responses to environmental risk? Environ Resour Econ 33:273–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll A, Taylor S, Régnière J, Safranyik L (2004) Effects of climate change on range expansion by the mountain pine beetle in British Columbia. In: Shore T, Brooks J, Stone J (eds) Mountain pine beetle symposium: challenges and solutions, October 30–31, 2003, Kelowna, British Columbia, Natural Resources Canada, Canadian Forest Service, Pacific Forestry Center, Information report BC-X-399, pp 223–232

  • Case B, Colwell P, Leishman C, Watkins C (2006) The impact of environmental contamination on condo prices: a hybrid repeat-sales/hedonic approach. Real Estate Econ 34:77–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chau K, Wong S, Yiu C (2005) Adjusting for nonlinear age effects in the repeat sales index. J Real Estate Finance Econ 31:137–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho SH, Roberts R, Kim S (2011) Negative externalities on property values resulting from water impairment: the case of the Pigeon River watershed. Ecol Econ 70:2390–2399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dastrup S, Graff Zivin J, Costa D, Kahn M (2012) Understanding the solar home price premium: electricity generation and “green” social status. Eur Econ Rev 56:961–973

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daufresne M, Boët P (2007) Climate change impacts on structure and diversity of fish communities in rivers. Glob Change Biol 13:2467–2478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eidenshink J, Schwind B, Brewer K, Zhu Z, Quayle B, Howard S (2007) A project for monitoring trends in burn severity. Fire Ecol 3:3–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans M, Hastings N, Peacock B (2000) Statistical distributions, 3rd edn. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Federal Highway Administration (2014) Highway traffic and construction noise—regulation and guidance. http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/environment/noise/regulations_and_guidance/. Accessed 27 May 2014

  • Francke M (2010) Repeat sale index for thin markets: a structured time series approach. J Real Estate Finance Econ 41:24–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman A (2003) The measurement of environmental and resource values, 2nd edn. Resources for the Future, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Goetzmann W, Spiegel M (1995) Non-temporal components of residential real estate appreciation. Rev Econ Stat 77:199–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Haefen R (2007) Empirical strategies for incorporating weak complementarity into consumer demand models. J Environ Econ Manag 54:15–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen W, Naughton H (2013) The effects of a spruce bark beetle outbreak and wildfires on property values in the wildland-urban interface of south-central Alaska, USA. Ecol Econ 96:141–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmes T, Murphy E, Bell K (2006) Exotic forest insects and residential property values. Agric Resour Econ Rev 35(1):155–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes T, Murphy E, Bell K, Royle D (2010) Property value impacts of hemlock wooly adelgid in residential forests. For Sci 56:529–540

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim C, Phipps T, Anselin L (2003) Measuring the benefits of air quality improvement: a spatial hedonic approach. J Environ Econ Manag 45:24–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kovacs K, Holmes T, Englin J, Alexander J (2011) The dynamic response of housing values to a forest invasive disease: evidence from a sudden oak death infestation. Environ Resour Econ 49:445–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krinsky I, Robb A (1986) On approximating the statistical properties of elasticities. Rev Econ Stat 68:715–719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larimer County Assessor (2013b) 2011 Larimer County mill levies. http://www.co.larimer.co.us/assessor/2011milllevies_authority.pdf. Accessed 8 Apr 2013

  • Larimer County Treasurer (2013a) Common questions about property taxes. http://www.larimer.org/treasurer/frequent.htm. Accessed 8 Apr 2013

  • Leggett C, Bockstael N (2000) Evidence of the effect of water quality on residential land prices. J Environ Econ Manag 39:121–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Man G (2012) Major forest insect and disease conditions in the United States: 2011. Technical report FS-1000, United States Department of Agriculture, Forest Service

  • Mendelsohn R, Hellerstein D, Huguenin M, Unsworth R, Brazee R (1992) Measuring hazardous waste damages with panel data models. J Environ Econ Manag 22:259–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murdoch P, Baron J, Miller T (2000) Potential effects of climate change on surface-water quality in North America. J Am Water Resour Assoc 36:347–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Interagency Fire Center (2012) Total wildland fires and acres (1960–2009). http://www.nifc.gov/fireInfo/fireInfo_stats_totalFires.html. Accessed 3 Apr 2013

  • Neill H, Hassenzahl D, Assane D (2007) Estimating the effect of air quality: spatial versus traditional hedonic models. South Econ J 73:1088–1111

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmquist R (1980) Alternative techniques for developing real estate price indexes. Rev Econ Stat 62:442–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmquist R (1982) Measuring environmental effects on property values without hedonic regressions. J Urban Econ 11:333–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmquist R (1991) Hedonic methods. In: Braden J, Kolstad C (eds) Measuring the demand for environmental quality. Elsevier, North Holland, pp 71–120

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmquist R (2005) Property value models. In: Mäler KG, Vincent J (eds) Handbook of environmental economics, vol II. Elsevier, North Holland, pp 763–819

    Google Scholar 

  • Phaneuf DJ, Smith V, Palmquist R, Pope J (2008) Integrating property value and local recreation models to value ecosystem services in urban watersheds. Land Econ 84(3):361–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pope J (2008) Buyer information and the hedonic: the impact of a seller disclosure on the implicit price for airport noise. J Urban Econ 63:498–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Price J, McCollum D, Berrens R (2010) Insect infestation and residential property values: a hedonic analysis of the mountain pine beetle epidemic. For Policy Econ 12:415–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruefenacht B, Finco M, Nelson M, Czaplewski R, Helmer E, Blackard J, Holden G, Lister A, Salajanu D, Weyermann D, Winterberger K (2008) Conterminous U.S. and Alaska forest type mapping using forest inventory and analysis data. Photogramm. Eng. Remote Sens 74(11):1379–1388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims C, Aadland D, Finnoff D (2010) A dynamic bioeconomic analysis of mountain pine beetle epidemics. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 34:2407–2419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stetler K, Tyron V, Calkin D (2010) The effects of wildfire and environmental amenities on property values in Northwest Montana, USA. Ecol Econ 69:2233–2243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • US Environmental Protection Agency (2014a) Chesapeake Bay TMDL. http://www.epa.gov/chesapeakebaytmdl/. Accessed May 27 2014

  • US Environmental Protection Agency (2014b) Particulate matter (PM) standards. http://www.epa.gov/ttn/naaqs/standards/pm/s_pm_index.html. Accessed 27 May 2014

  • US Environmental Protection Agency (2014c) Sulfur dioxide (SO2) primary national ambient air quality standards. http://www.epa.gov/ttn/naaqs/standards/so2/s_so2_index.html. Accessed May 27 2014

  • US Environmental Protection Agency (2014d) Watershed priorities, Lake Tahoe, CA & NV. http://www.epa.gov/region9/water/watershed/tahoe/tools-tmdl.html#tmdl. Accessed May 27 2014

  • USDA Forest Service (2012a) Forest type groups of the United States. http://fsgeodata.fs.fed.us/rastergateway/forest_type/conus_forest_type_group_metadata.php. Accessed Apr 3 2013

  • USDA Forest Service (2012b) Monitoring trends in burn severity. http://www.mtbs.gov/documents_references.html. Accessed 4 Apr 2013

  • USDA Forest Service (2012c) Wildland fire decision support system. https://wfdss.usgs.gov/wfdss/WFDSS_Data.shtml. Accessed 4 Apr 2013

  • Whitehead P, Wilby R, Battarbee R, Kernan M, Wade A (2009) A review of potential impacts of climate change on surface water quality. Hydrol Sci 54:101–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2012) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Klaus Moeltner.

Additional information

We thank seminar participants at the 2013 Meetings of the W3133 Western Regional Science Project (Coeur d’ Alene, ID, Feb. 27–March 2), and the US Airforce Academy, Colorado Springs (March 15, 2013), for insightful and stimulating comments. Funding provided by the Southern Research Station, USDA Forest Service, is gratefully acknowledged.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Tables 10, 11, 12, 13 and 14.

Table 10 Price statistics by area, Larimer (2011 dollars, units of 000s)
Table 11 Price statistics by area, Boulder (2011 dollars, units of 000s)
Table 12 Additional estimation results, Larimer
Table 13 Additional estimation results, Boulder
Table 14 Estimation results for HT effects, Spokane

Appendix 2: Details for Loss Predictions

In step one we seek the counterfactual price of a home near host trees in absence of any MPB effects, for each year of our series. From Eq. (16) we have

$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ \frac{ P_{it}\vert h_i=1}{P_{it}\vert h_i=0} \right] = 1 + m3_t=exp\left( \zeta +\beta _t \right) \end{aligned}$$
(19)

For a given home in the HT zone with observed price \(P_{it}\) we then obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{P}_{it}= E\left[ P_{it}\vert h_i=0 \right] = \frac{P_{it}}{1+m3_t}=\frac{P_{it}}{exp\left( \zeta +\beta _t \right) } \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Next, we compute the pure price differential between the final time period \(T\) and year \(t\) in absence of any MPB disturbance. Following the derivation in (14) we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \kappa _{s,t,T}&= E\left[ \frac{P_{iT}-P_{it}}{P_{it}}\vert h_i=0 \right] = E\left[ \frac{P_{iT}}{P_{it}}\vert h_i=0\right] -1 \nonumber \\&= E\left[ exp\left( \xi _s +\alpha _{sT} - \alpha _{st} + \psi \left( F_{iT}-F_{it}\right) + \delta _s a_{i,\left( T,t\right) } + e_{is,\left( T,t\right) }\right) \right] -1\nonumber \\&= exp\left( \xi _s +\alpha _{sT} - \alpha _{st} + \psi \left( F_{iT}-F_{it}\right) + \delta _s a_{i,\left( T,t\right) } + \sigma ^2\right) -1 \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Ignoring the time-invariant spatial index, as well as fire and depreciation effects leaves \(\kappa _{s,t,T} =exp\left( \alpha _{sT} - \alpha _{st} + \sigma ^2\right) - 1\). The counterfactual price of affected home \(i\) in absence of any MPB impacts and projected to the final year \(T\) can then be computed as

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{P}_{iT}&= \tilde{P}_{it}\left( 1+\kappa _{s,t,T}\right) \nonumber \\&= P_{it} \frac{1+\kappa _{s,t,T}}{1+m3_t}\nonumber \\&= P_{it} exp\left( \alpha _{sT}-\alpha _{st}-\zeta -\beta _{t} + \sigma ^2\right) = P_{it}\rho _{s,t,T} \end{aligned}$$
(22)

We implement these predictive steps via simulation along the lines proposed by Krinsky and Robb (1986) as follows: We take 100,000 draws of each contributing coefficient in the last line of (22) from their respective finite sample distribution, taking account of all involved covariances. For each draw we then compute \(\rho _{s,t,T}\) as given in the last line of (22) and capture the mean, 2.5th, and 97.5th percentile of the resulting empirical distribution. We repeat this procedure for every \(t \ne T\). We then multiply observed price \(P_{it}\) by the appropriate year-specific mean conversion factor [term \(\rho _{s,t,T}\) in the last line of (22)] as well as by the confidence bounds for all HT homes in our data. This produces an estimate and confidence bounds for the predicted “MPB purged” sales price \(\tilde{P}_{iT}\) in 2011.

In a final step, we then apply the point estimate of MPB loss in 2011 (see Tables 7, 8) to each predicted mean price, the lower bound of the MPB loss estimate to each upper bound for predicted price, and the upper bound of MPB loss estimate to each lower bound for predicted price to derive a point estimate and confidence bounds for predicted MPB losses, in 2011 dollars, for each property.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cohen, J., Blinn, C.E., Boyle, K.J. et al. Hedonic Valuation with Translating Amenities: Mountain Pine Beetles and Host Trees in the Colorado Front Range. Environ Resource Econ 63, 613–642 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9856-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9856-y

Keywords

Navigation