6243197
6243197
6243197
uk
Provided by Research Papers in Economics WPS4326
Public Disclosure Authorized
Augusto de la Torre
Juan Carlos Gozzi
Public Disclosure Authorized
Sergio L. Schmukler
Public Disclosure Authorized
Abstract
Interest in access to finance has increased significantly a limited role for the public sector in financial markets,
in recent years, as growing evidence suggests that lack but contends that there might be room for well-designed,
of access to credit prevents lower-income households restricted interventions in collaboration with the private
and small firms from financing high return investment sector to foster financial development and broaden
projects, having an adverse effect on growth and poverty access. The authors illustrate this view with several recent
alleviation. This study describes some recent innovative experiences in Latin America and then discuss some open
experiences to broaden access to credit. These experiences policy questions about the role of the public and private
are consistent with an emerging new view that recognizes sectors in driving these financial innovations.
This paper—a product of the Office of the Chief Economist, Latin America and the Caribbean Region, the Development
Research Group, and the Financial and Private Sector Development Vice Presidency—is part of a larger, Bank-wide effort
to enhance the understanding of analytical and policy issues in access to financial services. Policy Research Working Papers
are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at adelatorre@worldbank.org,
juan_carlos_gozi_valdez@brown.edu, and sschmukler@worldbank.org.
The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development
issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the
names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those
of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and
its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.
Augusto de la Torre
and
Sergio L. Schmukler*
*
Authors are with the World Bank. Gozzi is also with Brown University. We would like to thank all the
people that helped us with our interviews and, in particular, Remigio Alvarez Prieto, Carlos Budar, Javier
Gavito, Timoteo Harris, Miguel Hernández, Francisco Meré, and Jaime Pizarro. We are grateful to Aquiles
Almansi, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, Patrick Honohan, and Marilou Uy (the study’s peer reviewers), who
provided detailed and very useful comments. We also received useful comments and suggestions from Stijn
Claessens, Carlos Cuevas, Giovanni Majnoni, Martin Naranjo, Guillermo Perry, Luis Serven, and Jacob
Yaron. We would also like to thank Leonor Coutinho for helping us in the initial stages of this project and
José Azar and Francisco Ceballos for excellent research assistance. The findings, interpretations and
conclusions expressed in this study are entirely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the
views of the World Bank. E-mail addresses: adelatorre@worldbank.org,
juan_carlos_gozi_valdez@brown.edu, and sschmukler@worldbank.org.
Innovative Experiences in Access to Finance:
Market Friendly Roles for the Visible Hand?
Contents
1. Introduction 1
5. Final Remarks 37
Appendices
An Overview of Microfinance 41
BANSEFI’s Experience 43
NAFIN’s Reverse Factoring Program 50
FIRA’s Structured Finance Transactions 56
References 66
1. Introduction
Academic and policy interest in financial development has risen in step with the
accumulation of evidence supporting the view that a sound financial system is not just
correlated with a healthy economy, but actually causes economic growth. 1 By and large,
the empirical work behind this evidence has used financial sector depth, typically
expressed as the ratio of financial assets to GDP, as the “independent variable,” thereby
implicitly assuming that depth is a good proxy for financial development. 2 This may be a
justifiable assumption when it comes to empirical work, given the arguably strong
correlation between financial depth and financial development, and considering data
constraints. But it is clear that the intricate web of institutional and market interactions
that are at the heart of financial development can hardly be reduced to a single dimension.
It is financial development in all of its dimensions—and not just financial depth—which
lubricates and boosts the process of growth. It is not surprising, therefore, that the
discussion of finance and growth has naturally widened to consider other dimensions of
finance that appear crucial to economic and social development. These include stability,
diversity, and—the focus of this study—access to finance. Of these dimensions, access to
finance is, so to speak, the “new kid in the block.” 3
Although a relatively new field, the study of financial development from the
perspective of the breadth of access to financial services has mushroomed. 4 There are a
number of factors that have contributed to this. First, there is some empirical evidence,
albeit still limited, that the expansion of access may reduce poverty. Burgess and Pande
(2005), for instance, find that a 1 percent increase in the number of rural banked locations
in India reduces rural poverty by 0.34 percent (see also Department for International
Development, 2004, and references therein). 5
1
The literature on the finance-growth nexus is vast. Reviews of such literature can be found in a variety of
forms that can suit all sorts of different tastes. A comprehensive review is found in Levine (2005). Rajan
and Zingales (2001; 2003a), by contrast, provide shorter reviews in less technical language. Caprio and
Honohan (2001) offer an excellent rendition that emphasizes the World Bank contributions to the empirical
literature.
2
A notable exception is Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2005), who collect several indicators of
banking sector outreach and find that outreach is associated with lower firm-level financial constraints,
even after controlling for financial sector depth.
3
The study of financial stability is arguably a more mature endeavor that includes such well-researched
topics as regulation and supervision, early warning systems, crisis prevention, crisis management and
resolution, and monetary and financial sector linkages. The study of financial system diversity is arguably
also a relatively more mature subject, inasmuch as financial sub-sectors (e.g., banking, capital markets,
insurance, and pensions) are the object of specialized disciplines.
4
A large number of recent studies have focused on quantifying the lack of access of households and firms
and trying to determine its causes. In the case of developing countries, these studies include: Kumar (2005)
for Brazil; World Bank (2003a) for Colombia; Srivastava and Basu (2004) for India; Atieno (1999) for
Kenya; Aliou and Zeller (2001) for Malawi; Caskey et al. (2004) and World Bank (2003b) for Mexico;
Beegle, Dehejia, and Gatti (2003) and Satta (2002) for Tanzania. Halac and Schmukler (2004) present data
for various Latin American countries. In addition, Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Maksimovic (2002),
Francisco and Kumar (2004), IADB (2002), Tejerina (2004), and Schulhofer-Wohl (2004) analyze
measures of access to finance for small firms.
5
A broader group of studies has shown a link between financial market depth and poverty reduction, but
does not identify whether this is caused by a simultaneous expansion in the breadth of access, or simply by
1
Second, the interest in access also comes from the fact that arguments about the
channels through which financial development may lead to growth often include access-
related stories. Most prominent in this regard is the Schumpeterian argument,
compellingly restated by Rajan and Zingales (2003a), that financial development causes
growth because it fuels the process of “creative destruction,” and it does so by moving
resources to efficient uses and, in particular, to the hands of efficient newcomers. What is
relevant in this perspective is the access dimension of financial development—it is
through broader access to finance that talented newcomers are empowered and freed from
the disadvantages that would otherwise arise from their lack of inherited wealth and
absence of connections to the network of well-off incumbents. In other words, financial
development can stimulate the process of creative destruction—and thus the growth
process—by expanding economic opportunities and by leveling the playing field, that is,
by giving the outsiders and the poor a chance. It is on the strength of this type of
reasoning that Rajan and Zingales (2003a) confidently say that “healthy and competitive
financial markets are an extraordinarily effective tool in spreading opportunity and
fighting poverty.”
A third reason for the increasing interest on the study of access is the sheer lack of
access to financial services in emerging economies, particularly when compared to the
extent of access in developed countries. Recent World Bank country-specific reports
suggest that more than 70 percent of the Latin American population lacks access to such
basic financial services as a checking or savings account. 6 In industrial countries this
statistic is typically below 20 percent. 7 By implication, the Latin Americans that have
access to the more sophisticated financial services—long-term credit, mutual funds,
insurance products, etc.—are truly few and far between. 8 The differences in access across
countries are also illustrated by studies showing that firms in developing countries,
especially SMEs (small and medium enterprises), use formal sources of finance much
less than similar firms in industrial countries (see, for example, Beck, Demirguc-Kunt,
and Maksimovic, 2002).
In light of the increasing awareness of the importance of access, not only among
policymakers but also academics, this study aims at filling in one of the many gaps in this
still emerging literature, by addressing specific issues related to access to finance. In
particular, this study has two objectives. The first one is to discuss some conceptual
issues in access to finance. The second one is to describe some recent experiences to
broaden access to credit. These experiences seem to be driven by an emerging new view
on the role of the public sector in financial development, which tends to favor restricted
an increase in income levels that favors lower income sectors. Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2004),
for example, find that in countries with higher financial sector depth the income of the poorest 20 percent
of the population grows faster than average GDP per capita and income inequality falls at a higher rate.
6
See relevant references in footnote 3.
7
Household surveys that compile data on access to financial services across countries are surveyed in
Peachey and Roe (2004) and Claessens (2005). The percentage of households without a checking account
is estimated to be about 30 percent in Italy, 12 percent in the U.K., nine percent in the U.S., eight percent in
Spain, and less than two percent in Scandinavian countries (Peachey and Roe, 2004).
8
One exception among credit services, however, appears to be consumer credit (including the micro
variety), the access to which is broadening at a fast pace.
2
government interventions in collaboration with the private sector in non-traditional ways.
We illustrate this new view with several recent initiatives in Latin America and discuss
some open policy questions about the role of the public and private sectors in light of
these experiences.
Among the wide set of products covered under the “financial services” label—
including savings, payments, insurance, and credit products—we focus our analysis on
credit services. We believe that, regarding issues of access, these services are the most
interesting and challenging from an analytical point of view and from policymakers’
perspective, as the provision of credit entails many complexities that lead providers to
exclude very diverse groups of borrowers.
We start by noting that the observation that a certain share of the population does
not use financial services, which we identify as lack of access, does not necessarily mean
that there is a problem of access. This distinction has often been ignored or understated in
the recent literature, even though the failure to recognize it can lead to the wrong policy
advice. Lack of access is simply the fact that financial services are not being used. To
conclude that this observation entails a problem is not easy, as there is no clear definition
of what such a problem is. To conduct our study, we adopt a working definition of a
problem of access to credit. In our definition, a problem of access to credit exists when a
project that would be internally financed if resources were available, does not get external
financing. This happens because there is a wedge between the expected internal rate of
return of the project and the rate of return that external investors require to finance it.
This wedge is mainly introduced by two well-known constraints that hamper the ability
to write and enforce financial contracts, namely, principal-agent problems and
transaction costs.
The institutional framework of the economy affects the ability of agents to deal
with these problems and therefore has a significant impact on financial development and
access to finance. In environments with weak institutions, agency problems tend to be
mitigated through arrangements that rely on personalized relationships, group
monitoring, and fixed collateral. These instruments work, by definition, within a
circumscribed network of participants, excluding creditworthy borrowers that lack
collateral and/or connections. In contrast, a strong institutional environment enables the
expansion of arm’s-length financing by using impersonal contracts that rely on rules of
general application, effectively freeing borrowers from the tyranny of collateral and
personalized connections.
3
broaden access to credit, as private markets fail to expand access. In contrast, the laissez-
faire view contends that governments can do more harm than good by intervening
directly in the financial system and argues that government efforts should instead focus
on improving the enabling environment.
The main message of pro-market activism is that there is a role for the visible
hand of the government in promoting access in the short run, while the fruits of ongoing
institutional reform are still unripe. However, the government must be highly selective in
its interventions, always trying to ensure that they promote the development of deep
domestic financial markets, rather than replace them. Careful analyses to identify market
failures and their causes should precede any intervention. And even if a market failure is
identified, government intervention can only be justified if it can solve the failure in a
cost-effective manner. There must also be mechanisms in place to prevent political
capture that may undermine the temporary nature of the interventions or their
compatibility with the long-run objective of institutional reform and financial market
development.
4
innovation, as illustrated by the structured finance products created by FIRA, a Mexican
development financial institution, to provide financing to the agricultural sector. In other
cases the instruments used have been similar to those promoted by proponents of the
interventionist view (i.e., public credit, subsidies, and guarantees). However, pro-market
interventions tend to differ from previous ones in important aspects of their design—
especially regarding sustainability, time limits, governance, and transparency—and even
in terms of their objectives, as they seek to complement and promote private financial
intermediation, rather than replace it. This is the case of BancoEstado’s intervention in
the microfinance market in Chile, which was designed to promote financial innovation
and foster the participation of formal private financial institutions in this market. Other
pro-market interventions using traditional government instruments include the FOGAPE
guarantee system in Chile and the SIEBAN subsidy designed by FIRA to cover the initial
costs of serving small borrowers.
We conclude with some open questions raised by these experiences that are key to
understanding whether the pro-market activism view can constitute a viable alternative to
broaden access to finance in developing countries. First, a relevant question is whether
idiosyncratic experiences can lead to more general policy guidelines. The experiences we
describe may be the result of a specific environment that favors government innovation
and reduces the risk of political capture and may also be inherently related to certain
characteristics of the development-oriented financial institutions that have implemented
them. This raises the question of to what extent these experiences can be replicated in
other countries. Second, the analysis of the experiences suggests that it might be
necessary to rethink some institutional features of development-oriented financial
institutions to ensure that interventions succeed in fostering private financial
intermediation and broadening access. Some features that may be helpful in this regard
include: separating subsidies from funding and functioning more as development
agencies—with an initial endowment from the government but no annual budget
allocations—than financial intermediaries; redefining their mandates in dynamic terms,
so that institutions move on to new interventions once the market they were promoting
becomes self-sustainable; and modifying the way in which their performance is
evaluated, away from criteria based on the volume of guarantees or loans provides and
towards indicators based in the amount of financial intermediation promoted. Third, the
pro-market view poses certain risks. Pro-market interventions may reduce incentives for
institutional reform and detract resources away from efforts to achieve institutional
efficiency, which is the economy’s first best. Pro-market interventions may also lead to
inefficient equilibriums due to the existence of path dependence in financial
development. Furthermore, even if interventions are designed to be time-bound and
government support is restricted to the provision of seed capital, the creation of vested
interest entailed in any government intervention raises significant political economy
issues, as the government may face pressure to provide additional financial support in the
future. Finding adequate instruments to effectively minimize these risks is one of the
most important factors for the success of pro-market interventions. Fourth, an open
question is whether pro-market interventions are just short-term solutions to broaden
access while institutions are taking time to build, or if there is role for these interventions
even in countries with a good enabling environment. Finally, further research is needed to
5
understand the adequate roles for the public and private sectors in fostering financial
innovation and broadening access.
Let us start by noting that the phenomenon that a certain proportion of the
population does not use financial services, which here we identify as lack of access, does
not necessarily mean that there is a problem of access. A lack of access and a problem of
access are two very different things. This distinction, unfortunately, has often been
ignored or understated in most of the recent literature, even though the failure to
recognize it can lead to the wrong policy advice. As defined above, a lack of access is
simply the fact that financial services are not being used. To conclude that this
observation entails a problem is not easy, not least because that would require a clear
definition of what such problem is. Additionally, even if we agreed on a definition, it is
difficult to identify a problem of access in practice and isolate it from the mere lack of
access. In other words, data might reveal an equilibrium outcome of lack of access, but
this may reflect either supply or demand factors. For example, households and firms may
be observed not to use credit simply because they may not need to borrow (either because
they lack viable investment projects or because they find it beneficial to use internal
funds to finance their investments). To complicate matters, the problem in some cases
may be not the lack of access to credit but rather the imprudent access to it. Many
financial crises have in fact originated in exuberant lending that did not internalize
appropriately the risks involved. Hence, that some borrowers are observed to be excluded
from credit may actually be a good thing, as their projects may not generate, under most
states of the world, the returns needed to pay back the debt. Finally, what may appear to
be a problem of access to credit for the disenfranchised poor may be mainly a problem of
poverty. In such a case, the policy solution would not be to artificially increase the flow
of credit to those segments of the population but rather to seek other means of reducing
poverty.
6
to problems of access to credit services only. We believe that, in what regards problems
of access to financial services, this particular class of products is the most interesting and
challenging from an analytical point of view and from policymakers’ perspective.
Products belonging to other categories, like savings and payment services, are just some
of the many services that the poor cannot afford to pay. On the other hand, the provision
of credit services entails many more complexities that sometimes lead providers to
exclude very diverse groups of borrowers.
Note that our definition abstracts from any factors that may affect the level of
interest rates, and thus the opportunity cost of funds. For example, a lower interest rate
stemming from a reduction in macroeconomic volatility will reduce the opportunity cost
of funds, increasing the number of viable projects (i.e., those that would be internally
financed if resources were available) and the amount of financial contracting. However,
this will not necessarily reduce the wedge between the internal rate of return and that
required by external investors. Although in this example there would be an increase in the
observed use of financial services and arguably major welfare gains, it would not entail a
mitigation of the problem of access according to our definition.10 In effect, our definition
does not focus on the number of projects that are viable or on the number of projects that
are observed to receive external financing, per se. An increase in those numbers would of
course be highly desirable and beneficial to society, but it is outside the scope of our
definition. For us, as the share of viable projects that are able to obtain external finance
increases, the problem of access is reduced.
9
See Lombardo and Pagano (2002) for a simple model showing the impact of principal-agent problems on
the equilibrium rate of return.
10
Note that our working definition also allows us to abstract from the level of competition in the financial
sector. The market structure of this sector may affect the cost of financing faced by borrowers, but even in
an monopolistic environment, in the absence of transaction costs and principal-agents problems, all projects
that would be internally financed (if the resources were available) should get external finance. The level of
competition in the financial sector, however, will affect how the profits are divided among borrowers and
creditors.
11
The canonical analysis of principal-agent problems in finance is due to Stiglitz and Weiss (1981).
7
risk borrowers (not just those that may be unable to repay their debt under a relevant
range of states of the world, but also those that might be unwilling to do so) are the ones
that are more willing to look for external finance. A financer may be willing to provide
financing to some projects/debtors by increasing the risk premium charged, but this
approach can backfire at some point due to the adverse selection problem. This is because
as the risk premium required by lenders rises, so does the riskiness of the pool of
interested borrowers. High-risk borrowers are “adversely selected” by higher risk
premiums. In effect, the higher the interest rate, the lower its usefulness and reliability for
creditors as a device for sorting out the good projects/borrowers from the bad ones. The
situation is one where the debtor may know ex-ante whether her project is good or bad,
and may have incentives to window-dress the bad ones, but the creditor cannot screen the
projects adequately because she cannot extract or verify this information. Faced with the
risk of adverse selection, lenders will try to use non-price criteria to screen
debtors/projects and ration and apportion credit, rather than further increasing the risk
premium.
The moral hazard problem, by contrast, concerns the situation after the agent
(e.g., the debtor) has received the resources (e.g., the loan) from the principal (e.g., the
lender). The problem here is that an agent may have informational advantages and
associated incentives to use the resources in ways that are inconsistent with the
principal’s interests. Acting on such incentives, the agent may divert resources to riskier
activities, strip and loot assets, or simply run away with the money, and the creditor may
not have an effective way to monitor and prevent such behavior. Note, however, that the
moral hazard problem can arise even when the agent does not have informational
advantages over the principal—i.e., when information is symmetrically shared—if the
principal faces high costs of enforcing the contract subscribed with the agent. Faced with
the moral hazard risk, a principal (e.g., a financer) would try to find ways to align the
incentives of the agent with its own. If unable to do so, principals may just not provide
funding—i.e., curtail access.
Consider, next, transaction costs. Even assuming that there are no principal-agent
problems, a problem of access to finance may still exist where the transaction costs
involved in the provision of finance exceed the expected risk-adjusted returns. Such a
scenario may arise due to the inability of financial intermediaries to reduce costs by
capturing economies of scale and scope. The result would affect disproportionately such
outsiders as poor households and small enterprises, as providing finance to them could be
rendered unprofitable by high costs per transaction. Cost barriers could also stem from
deficiencies in institutions and market infrastructure that make it expensive to gather
information on debtors/projects, value assets appropriately, and monitor and enforce
contracts.
8
obtain better lending terms from new creditors. Similarly, once a new lending technology
is introduced and proves to be successful, it can be easily adopted by others, who will not
share the research costs. Due to these dilemmas, research and investment in these areas
will be below the social optimum, unless a coordinating device is introduced to distribute
costs and benefits in an efficient way.
12
The threat of violence and the resort to physical intimidation and punishment are also commonly
observed devices—especially used by loan sharks—to deal with agency problems in financially
underdeveloped markets.
13
Rajan and Zingales (2003a), for instance, argue (p. 34) that “insider-lending practices [are] a solution to
primitive informational and contractual infrastructure,” and note that “historical studies indicate that
lending to related parties reflects financial underdevelopment (…) rather than some cultural propensity
towards being devious.” There is in effect a great deal of fascinating literature on how agency problems
have been dealt with through relationship-based arrangements in earlier stages of financial development.
For example, Greif (1993) provides an illuminating analysis of how the Maghribi traders were able to
monitor agents involved in distant trading by forming a community of merchants who were mutually bound
by a set of rules (the Merchant’s Law). Haber and Maurer (2004) analyze the rapid expansion in bank
lending to the textile industry in Mexico during 1876-1911 which was mostly accounted for by lending to
insiders. They show that due to certain rules of the game (which, inter alia, required lenders to have
substantial own resources at risk, enabled minority shareholders to monitor controlling shareholders, and
boosted reputation effects), such lending to insiders did not degenerate into looting or the misallocation of
credit. La Porta et al. (2003), in contrast, illustrate the perverse incentives of related lending by showing
that, in the Mexico of more recent times, related borrowers have been 33 percent more likely to default on
their debts than unrelated ones, and that recovery rates have been 30 percent lower for related loans than for
unrelated ones.
9
of its own resources at risk, which aligns its incentives better with those of the
principal. 14 In a context where collateral repossession is unduly cumbersome, opacity is
high, accounting rules are unreliable, and asset markets are illiquid, financers will only
accept fixed collateral, preferably real estate. Finally, in the case of group monitoring—a
device extensively used in the context of microfinance—the agency problems are
mitigated because the group is collectively liable for the failure to pay of one member,
which encourages group members to police each other and to exclude the risky ones from
participating (Morduch, 1999). Relationship finance, fixed collateral, and group
monitoring do enable the broadening of access, but only up to a point, as they work, by
definition, within a circumscribed network of participants, excluding viable
projects/creditworthy borrowers that lack fixed collateral and/or connections.
14
See Rodriguez-Meza (2004) for a discussion of the role of collateral. IADB (2004) discusses the issue of
over reliance on collateral in Latin America.
15
Credit scoring is an automated statistical technique used to assess the credit risk of loan applicants. It
involves analyzing a large sample of past borrowers to identify the characteristics that predict the likelihood
of default. Scoring systems usually generate a single quantitative measure (the credit score) to evaluate the
credit application.
10
is characterized by “path dependence” (North, 1990). Path dependence reflects the fact
that institutional arrangements are self-reinforcing (although not always efficient) due to
substantial increasing returns—the large set up costs of new institutions, the subsequent
lowering of uncertainty and transaction and information costs, and the associated
spillovers and externalities for contracting. An important corollary of path dependence is
that an isolated legal or regulatory feature that may be functional under a given
institutional matrix and at a given stage of financial development may produce
unintended effects when transplanted to another institutional milieu. 16
Standard arguments for government intervention in the financial sector stress that
financial markets are different from other markets because they rely heavily on
information and produce externalities that cannot be easily internalized by market
participants. 17,18 When information is asymmetric between lenders and borrowers and is
costly to obtain, or when the social benefit of a project is higher than the private benefit,
the market may fail to provide adequate financing.
16
Empirical studies suggest that legal traditions help explain cross-country differences in investor
protection laws, contracting environment, and financial development (see, for example, Beck, Demirguc-
Kunt, and Levine, 2003; Levine, 1998, 1999; and La Porta et al., 1997, 1998), with countries of English
legal origin presenting better creditor and shareholder rights protection and more developed financial
markets. This evidence suggests the existence of a high level of path dependence in financial development.
However, other researchers reject the view that legal origin is a central determinant of investor protection
and stress the role of politics in determining regulations and contract enforcement (see, for example,
Pagano and Volpin, 2001; Rajan and Zingales, 2003b; and Roe, 1994).
17
Stiglitz (1994) discusses the main arguments for public intervention in the financial sector. Besley (1994)
presents a critical review of the arguments for government intervention in financial markets, with a focus
on rural credit. Also, see Zingales (2004) for a critique of the traditional rationale for government
intervention based on Coase’s (1960) arguments and their application to financial regulation.
18
Another common argument for government intervention in financial markets is related to the need to
maintain the safety and soundness of the financial system, given the large costs and externalities generated
by financial crises. This argument, however, has been invoked to justify the need for government regulation
and supervision, rather than direct public involvement in financial markets.
11
from other investors, who will not bare the initial screening costs. 19 The failure to
appropriate the returns of information causes financial intermediaries to under invest in
information acquisition. The sub-optimal stock of information gathered by the financial
sector leads to a sub-optimal level of investment: viable projects will be underfinanced
(or not financed at all) due to the lack of adequate information. Similar effects are present
when lenders invest in new credit technologies. While they will bare all the costs in case
of failure, it is often difficult to prevent other investors from adopting the new technology
once it has proven successful, reducing incentives for innovation.
Finally, some financial instruments may need to achieve a certain scale in order to
be profitable. This is the argument behind the protection of infant industries. The failure
to coordinate efforts may lead to a prisoner’s dilemma type of game in which gains only
materialize if all investors invest in one project simultaneously, and the one that invests
alone incurs a large loss. In this type of game, without a coordination mechanism, no
investment will take place in equilibrium.
While most economists would agree that some type of government intervention to
foster financial development is warranted, there is less consensus regarding the specific
nature of this intervention. Answers to this question tend to be polarized in two highly
contrasting but well-established views: the interventionist and the laissez-faire views.
The interventionist view argues that an active public sector involvement in mobilizing
and allocating financial resources, including government ownership of banks, is needed
to broaden access to credit, as private markets fail to expand access. In contrast, the
laissez-faire view contends that governments can do more harm than good by intervening
directly in the financial system and argues that government efforts should instead focus
on improving the enabling environment, which will help to reduce agency problems and
transaction costs and mitigate problems of access.
19
Additionally, since the likelihood of default increases with the amount borrowed, further borrowing by
the debtor may have a negative impact on the first creditor (Arnott and Stiglitz, 1991).
12
institutions are taking time to build and consolidate, some government actions undertaken
in collaboration with market participants may be warranted. This is the view of pro-
market activism. We now turn to a more detailed characterization of each view.
The interventionist view is a very old view, which was popularized by the import
substitution policies of the 1950s and 1960s. This view regards the problems of access to
finance as resulting from widespread market failures that cannot be overcome in
underdeveloped economies by leaving markets forces alone. 20 For the proponents of this
view, it is less important to gain an adequate understanding of why private markets fail
than to recognize that they do fail, and badly. The key contention, therefore, is that to
expand access to finance beyond the narrow circle of privileged borrowers—mainly large
enterprises and well-off households—the active intervention of the government is
required. The government is thus called upon to have an intense, hands-on involvement
in mobilizing and allocating financial resources.
The interventionist view was closely related to the predominating thinking at the
time about the role of the government in the development process. The early development
literature drew attention to the constraints imposed by limited capital accumulation and
argued that markets tended to work inadequately in developing countries (see, for
example, Gerschenkron, 1962; Hirschman, 1958; Rosenstein-Rodan, 1943; and Rostow,
1962). 21 Consistent with these view, the growth strategies of most developing countries
in the 1950s and 1960s focused on accelerating the rate of capital accumulation and
technological adoption through direct government intervention. The role of the
government was to take the “commanding heights” of the economy and guide resource
allocation to those areas believed to be most conductive to long-term growth. This led to
import substitution policies, state ownership of firms, subsidization of infant industries,
central planning, and a wide range government interventions and price controls.
Confidence in government intervention was, at least partially, based on its perceived
success in expanding production during World War II and its role in the reconstruction of
Europe and Japan. Moreover, memories of the Great Depression made policymakers
skeptical about the functioning of markets.
13
assets of the ten largest banks in the former and around 65 percent in the latter (banks
were fully government owned in transition economies). Public banks became key policy
vehicles, used by governments to support the pursuit of their social and developmental
agenda through the selective allocation of (often subsidized) credit. Consistently with the
market failure rationale, public banks tended to focus on areas where private markets are
typically missing, such as long-term finance, lending to SMEs, housing finance, and
agricultural credit.
Governments can cross-check information with income tax systems and other
official records, or compel the disclosure of information that is not available to private
investors. This gives publicly owned banks an advantage in selecting and monitoring
borrowers, reducing the fixed costs of providing loans, and therefore reducing the break-
even rate of return of external finance.
The government can also help to solve the problems generated by externalities.
As mentioned above, if the social rate of return of a project is higher than its private rate
of return, private creditors may not be willing to finance it, even if it would be beneficial
for society as a whole to do so. This happens because it is difficult for the private sector
to internalize the social benefits that may be generated by the project. This instead can be
achieved by the government, through the tax system (intra-generational risk sharing) or
through government debt (inter-generational risk sharing).
Apart from the direct provision of credit through public banks, another
widespread tool for broadening access in developing countries was the imposition of
lending requirements, which obligated private banks to allocate a certain share of their
loans (or even absolute amounts) to specific sectors or regions. In Brazil, for example,
22
Note that the government could also increase trust in the banking sector through adequate regulation and
supervision of private banks, as well as through the creation of deposit insurance systems. Which type of
intervention will have a larger impact in terms of increasing public trust in the financial system depends on
the public’s perception of the government’s ability to provide incentives and monitor private banks relative
to its ability to monitor its own agents.
14
commercial banks were required to allocate between 20 and 60 percent (depending on
bank size) of their sight deposits to agriculture. In India, 50 percent of bank deposits had
to be invested in government bonds at below market rates and most of the remaining
funds had to be directed to priority sectors like agriculture and small enterprises, with
only about 20 percent of bank resources being freely allocated. In Thailand, bank
branches established outside Bangkok after 1975 were subject to “local lending
requirements,” mandating them to lend at least 60 percent of their deposit resources
locally (Booth et al., 2001). Many countries also established refinance schemes, which
allowed commercial banks to discount loans to selected sectors at preferential rates with
the Central Bank. The rationale for these interventions is similar to that for the creation of
public banks discussed above: private banks cannot internalize the positive externalities
generated by some investments, and therefore, without government intervention, may fail
to allocate enough funds to those projects with the highest social returns.
Another commonly used tool was the regulation of interest rates. Governments
often established preferential rates for commercial lending to priority sectors, which were
significantly lower than those on regular loans. In Colombia, for example, interest rates
on directed credit were, on average, about 12 percentage points lower than those on non-
preferential credit over the period 1983-1987 (World Bank, 1990a). In the case of
Turkey, this differential reached 36 percentage points between 1980 and 1982 (World
Bank, 1989). A variation of this tool was the establishment of interest rate ceilings on
deposits and/or loans, which could apply across the board or vary by sector or type of
loan. Interest rate controls were expected to result in lower costs of financing and greater
access to credit. 23
23
Broadening access to credit was not the only reason for the imposition of interest rate controls and
directed lending requirements. Strict control and regulation of the banking system was also supposed to
give monetary authorities a better control over the money supply and provided the government with easily
accessible resources to finance public expenditures (see Roubini and Sala-i-Martin, 1992).
15
economic growth, and recurrent fiscal drains. 24,25 The perceived failure of public banking
in developing countries contrasts with evidence suggesting that development banks
played an important role in the rapid industrialization of Continental Europe and Japan
(Cameron, 1953, 1961; Gershenkron, 1952). 26
While cross-country studies tend to find a negative or, at best, neutral impact of
government bank ownership, it is necessary to consider that public banks are highly
heterogeneous, both across and within countries. Detailed case studies highlight some
success stories, such as the Village Bank system of Bank Rayat in Indonesia
(Charitonenko, Benjamin, and Yaron, 1998) or the Bank for Agriculture and Agricultural
Cooperatives in Thailand (Townsend and Yaron, 2001). 27
24
IADB (2004) revises the empirical evidence on the impact of public banks and finds that, while the
results that government-owned banks have a negative impact are not as strong as previously thought, there
is no indication that government ownership has a positive effect. It concludes that public banks, at best, do
not play much of a role in financial development.
25
The interpretation of these findings in terms of causality is rather difficult, as the association between
government participation in the banking system and poor financial development and macroeconomic
performance could stem either from the need for more government intervention in countries with severe
market imperfections that prevent financial development, or from a negative impact of public intervention
on financial markets. Galindo and Micco (2004) try to address the problem of causality by using the
methodology devised by Rajan and Zingales (1998) and find that government-owned banks do not promote
the growth of those industries that rely more on external finance, nor do they promote the growth of
industries that, due to reduced collateral, face more financial constraints. They conclude that what matters
for growth is the development of private financial institutions.
26
Armendariz de Aghion (1999a) compares the successful development banking experience of Credit
Nationale in France with the relatively unsuccessful more recent experience of Nacional Financiera in
Mexico. She argues that the requirement to engage in co-financing arrangements with private financial
intermediaries in the case of Credite Nationale and the type of government involvement (subsidized credit
and loan guarantees in the case of France, direct ownership in Mexico) are among the factors that explain
the contrasting results.
27
Following Yaron (1992), these papers use a comprehensive framework to evaluate the performance of
development banks and their lending programs, mainly in terms of the outreach to their targeted clientele
and the degree to which their operations are dependent on subsidies.
16
al., 2005). In Mexico, the government had to recapitalize Banrural, a development bank
providing financing to the rural sector, with about 1.1 billion U.S. dollars in 1999, even after
having significantly downscaled its operations in previous years (Brizzi, 2001). 28
Moreover, it has been extremely difficult for public banks to break free from the
inherent contradiction between their social policy mandates, on the one hand, and
pressures to avoid losses, on the other. Public banks are charged with social policy
mandates which, by definition, expose them to high-risk clientele and limit their capacity
to diversify risks across economic and geographic sectors or across segments of
population with different income levels. With subsidies typically hidden in below market
interest rates, these institutions tend to incur low profits or losses—often magnified by
weak risk management systems, wasteful administrative expenses, and vulnerability to
political interference—and hence require repeated recapitalizations. To minimize
operational losses and the associated fiscal costs, these banks are often placed under the
same regulatory and supervisory standards as private commercial banks. This leads them
to enter into less risky and more lucrative lines of business, in competition with private
banks, reducing losses. However, this tends to be unsustainable as their activities become
increasingly inconsistent with their social policy mandate, prompting political pressures
to re-orient their activities towards meeting their mandate, which leads to a new cycle of
losses and recapitalizations. 29
The experience with directed credit programs has also been unsuccessful in most
cases (World Bank, 1989, 2005a). Although some East Asian countries like Japan, Korea,
and Taiwan seem to have achieved some success with directed lending to manufacturing,
in most developing countries the results have been poor. 30 Directed credit programs often
failed to reach their intended beneficiaries. Within priority sectors, larger and more
influential borrowers were favored. Lenders misclassified loans to provide credit to other
sectors and borrowers diverted credit to other uses. One extreme example is the case of
Korea, where an active market developed for borrowers with access to preferential
lending to on-lend funds to firms without it. Directed credit programs were often used not
to correct market failures, but to provide funds to politically-connected sectors and firms.
Once directed credit programs were established, they created a strong constituency of
beneficiaries, making it very difficult for governments to reduce their support to these
programs, regardless of how inefficient or costly they were. The cost of subsidies on
directed credit programs has often been substantial: in Brazil, for example, this cost was
28
Banrural is currently being liquidated. The World Bank has provided support of 505 million U.S. dollars
to the Mexican government to replace Banrural with a non-bank financial institution, Financiera Rural. The
total cost of government intervention in the rural financial system in Mexico, mostly through different
development banks, during the 1983-1992 period has been estimated at approximately 28.5 billion U.S.
dollars, 80 percent of which is associated with interest rate subsidies. The annual average of these costs
represents about 13 percent of agricultural GDP (Brizzi, 2001).
29
This phenomenon is what de la Torre (2002) calls the “Sisyphus syndrome” of public banks.
30
See World Bank (1993) for a description of the experience of East Asian countries with credit controls.
Also, Vittas and Cho (1996) try to extract the main lessons from the experience of these countries with
directed credit programs. They conclude that these programs should be small, narrowly focused, and of
limited duration. Several authors (see, for example, Cho, 1997; Santomero, 1997; Vittas, 1997; and World
Bank, 1993) point out that the relative success of directed credit programs in East Asian countries was
achieved at the expense of a slower development of more complete financial markets.
17
estimated at between 7 and 8 percent of GDP in 1987. In Korea, the subsidy provided by
directed credit was approximately 1 percent of GDP during the 1980s (Booth at al.,
2001). Directed lending requirements in many cases left little power or responsibility on
credit allocation to private banks, resulting in low investments in credit assessment and
monitoring. Also, extensive refinance schemes at low interest rates reduced the incentives
for financial institutions to mobilize resources on their own, leading to a lower level of
financial intermediation.
Over the last decades, mostly as a reaction to the mentioned problems of public
banking and direct government intervention in the financial sector, a second, entirely
opposite view has gained ground: the laissez-faire view. This view also stems from an
increasing awareness of the role played by institutions and market infrastructures in
financial development. The laissez-faire view contends that, due to incentive issues,
bureaucrats will never be good bankers and that governments can do more harm than
good by intervening directly in credit allocation and pricing. According to this view,
although there may be market failures in the financial industry, these are not as extensive
31
A number of cross-country studies have attempted to measure the impact of financial repression on
growth. Most of these papers use real interest rates (or variables based on threshold values of real interest
rates) to measure financial repression, as controls on lending and deposit rates resulted in low or negative
real interest rates in many developing countries (Agarwala, 1983; Gelb, 1989). These studies tend to find a
negative relation between financial repression and economic growth (see, for example, Easterly, 1993;
Lanyi and Saracoglu, 1983; Roubini and Sala-i-Martin, 1992; and World Bank, 1989). Galindo, Micco, and
Ordoñez (2002) measure the extent of financial liberalization using indices based on financial system
regulations and find that financial liberalization, mainly in the domestic financial sector, increases the
relative growth rate of those industries that rely more on external finance.
18
as assumed by proponents of the interventionist view and private parties by themselves,
given well-defined property rights and good contractual institutions, may be able to
address most of these problems. Additionally, the costs of government failures are likely
to exceed those of market failures, rendering direct interventions, at best, ineffective and
in many cases, counterproductive. Therefore, this view recommends that governments
exit from bank ownership and lift restrictions on the allocation of credit and the
determination of interest rates. Instead, the argument goes, government efforts should be
deployed towards improving the enabling environment—e.g., providing a stable
macroeconomic framework, enhancing creditor and shareholder rights and their
enforceability, upgrading prudential regulation, modernizing accounting practices, and
promoting the expansion of reliable debtor information systems (Caprio and Honohan,
2001; Klapper and Zaidi, 2005; Rajan and Zingales, 2001; World Bank, 2005a).
The laissez-faire view is consistent with the general shift on thinking about the
role of the government in the development process over the last decades. The experiences
of developing countries in the 1970s and 1980s showed that widespread government
intervention in the economy, through trade restrictions, state ownership of firms, financial
repression, price controls, and foreign exchange rationing, resulted in the waste of large
resources and impeded, rather than promoted, growth. Confidence in the ability of the
government to foster economic development diminished dramatically, as growing
evidence showed that government failure was widespread in developing countries and in
many cases outweighed market failure (see, for example, Krueger, 1990; Srinivasan,
1985; and World Bank, 1983). 32 This led economists and policymakers to conclude that
constraining the role of the public sector in the economy and eliminating the distortions
associated with protectionism, subsidies, and public ownership was essential to fostering
growth. 33 Much of this vision was reflected in the so-called “Washington Consensus” and
guided most of the reform programs during 1990s. 34 Governments focused on creating a
stable macroeconomic environment by reducing fiscal deficits and improving monetary
policies. In line with the objective of reducing the role of the state in the economy,
countries privatized government-owned enterprises, deregulated domestic industries,
eliminated quantitative restrictions and licensing requirements, and dismantled
agricultural marketing boards and other state monopolies. Many countries also reduced
tariffs and other restrictions on imports and liberalized regulations on foreign investment.
In recent years, the focus of the reforms has turned away from macroeconomic
stabilization and liberalization and shifted towards improving the institutional
environment (World Bank, 1999, 2002), consistent with the growing empirical evidence
32
The theoretical literature also started to focus on the causes of government failure, such as rent-seeking
and capture by special interests (see, for example, Buchanan, 1962; Krueger, 1974; Stigler, 1971; and
Tullock, 1967)
33
The view that better policies would lead to higher growth was also motivated by endogenous growth
theories developed by Lucas and Romer in the mid-1980s which imply that government policies can
influence not just the income level, but also countries’ steady-state growth rates. This literature provided
the foundation to empirical work based on cross-country regressions to analyze the effects of policies on
growth, which was started by Barro (1991). Durlauf, Johnson, and Temple (2005), Easterly (2005), and
Temple (1999) provide critical surveys of this literature. See also Rodrik (2005).
34
The term “Washington Consensus” was coined by Williamson (1990). See World Bank (2005b) for a
review of the reforms during the 1990s and a discussion of their policy lessons.
19
on the impact of institutions of economic development (see, for example, Acemoglu,
Johnson, and Robinson, 2001; Easterly and Levine, 2003; Hall and Jones, 1999; and
Rodrik, Subramanian, and Trebbi, 2004).
The failure of the financial repression policies led many countries to liberalize
their financial systems, reducing direct government intervention in the allocation and
pricing of credit. Financial liberalization was carried out both on the domestic and
external fronts. Regarding the domestic financial system, liberalization policies included
the elimination or downscaling of directed lending programs, the reduction of reserve
requirements, and the deregulation of interest rates. On the external front, many countries
lifted restrictions on foreign borrowing by financial institutions and corporations and
dismantled controls on foreign exchange and capital transactions. Despite stops, gaps,
and some reversals, the process of financial liberalization has advanced through much of
the world over the last decades. 35 Countries in all income groups have liberalized,
although developed countries were among the first to start this process and have
remained more liberalized than lower-income economies throughout. In developing
countries, the pace and timing of financial liberalization has differed across regions. In
Latin America, Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay liberalized their financial systems in the
late 1970s, but these reforms were reversed in the aftermath of the 1982 debt crisis, and
financial systems remained repressed during most of the 1980s. Latin American countries
carried out substantial financial liberalizations in the late 1980s and early 1990s. In the
case of East Asia, the liberalization process was more gradual. A number of countries
started slowly rationalizing their directed credit programs and liberalizing their interest
rates during the 1980s and the process in many cases stretched for over a decade.
The laissez-faire view led to a barrage of reforms aimed at creating the proper
institutions and infrastructure for financial markets to flourish. Governments tried to
35
See Williamson and Mahar (1998) for an overview of the financial liberalization process around the
world. Kaminsky and Schmukler (2003) construct indices of financial liberalization for a large number of
developing and developed countries.
36
See Megginson (2005) for a review of the empirical literature on bank privatization.
20
mitigate principal-agent problems in credit markets by reforming bankruptcy laws and
enacting new legislation regarding creditor rights. Many countries also tried to improve
information sharing among lenders by fostering the development of credit bureaus. Credit
bureaus make borrowers’ loan payment history available to different lenders, facilitating
information exchanges and reducing screening costs. Credit bureaus also increase
incentives for repayment, since borrowers know that their reputations will be shared
among different creditors. 37 Governments tried to create a supportive environment for
private credit bureaus by enacting credit reporting laws that allow the sharing of
information among creditors and in many cases created public credit registries. Miller
(2003) reports that 15 countries, including nine Latin American countries, have
established public credit registries since 1989 and that several developing countries in
other regions are actively considering similar initiatives. Private credit bureaus have also
experienced a significant growth over the last decades, with approximately half of the
private credit reporting firms around the world covered by Miller (2003) starting their
operations after 1989. In some countries, governments also modified collateral laws and
created registries for moveable property in order to allow these assets to be used as
collateral, which was expected to benefit smaller firms that are less likely to own fixed
assets. 38
37
McIntosh and Wydick (2004) show that the total effect of credit bureaus can be decomposed in two
separate effects (a screening effect and an incentive effect) and that credit bureaus can improve access to
financing for the poorest borrowers. Empirically, Japelli and Pagano (2002) find that the presence of credit
bureaus, irrespective of whether they are public or private, is associated with deeper credit markets and
lower credit risk. Love and Mylenko (2003) find that the existence of private credit bureaus is associated
with lower financing constraints, while public credit registries do not seem to have a significant effect.
38
In most developing countries, legal impediments restrict the use of movable property as collateral, as
there is little or no information on whether other creditors have claims on the same asset and the
repossession process is usually cumbersome (often exceeding the economic life of the movable good). In
contrast, lending secured by movable property is widespread in developed countries, reaching almost 40
percent of total credit in the U.S. (Fleising, 1996).
39
See World Bank (2004a) for a description of the evolution of securities markets and related reforms over
the last decades, with a focus on Latin America.
40
See Capaul (2003) for an overview of corporate governance reforms in Latin America.
41
Bhattacharya and Daouk (2002) find that 39 developing countries have established insider trading
regulations since 1990.
21
Despite the intense reform effort, access to finance does not seem to have
increased significantly in most developing countries since the early 1990s. 42 While many
countries experienced a strong growth in deposits, this growth did not translate into an
increase of similar magnitude in credit to the private sector, as most of the additional
loanable funds were absorbed by higher holdings of public sector debt (Hanson, 2003). 43
Similarly, the performance of domestic securities markets in many emerging economies
has been disappointing (World Bank, 2004a). Although some countries experienced
growth of their domestic securities markets, this growth in most cases was not as
significant as that witnessed by industrialized nations. Other countries experienced an
actual deterioration of their securities markets. 44
The general perception of lack of results from the reform process contrasts with
empirical evidence suggesting that reforms did in fact have a positive impact on financial
development. For instance, Djankov, McLiesh, and Shleifer (2006) find that
improvements in creditor rights and the introduction of credit bureaus are associated with
increases in credit to the private sector. Similarly, de la Torre, Gozzi, and Schmukler
(2005) find that capital market-related reforms tend to be followed by significant
increases in stock market capitalization, trading, and capital raising. The contrast between
this evidence and the general perception may be explained by excessively high
expectations at the beginning of the reform process. 45 The gap between expectations and
outcomes may also be ascribed to a combination of insufficient reform implementation
with impatience. 46 In effect, despite what many claim, key reforms were in some cases
not even initiated, while other reforms were often implemented in an incomplete or
inconsistent fashion. In many cases, only laws were approved, but they were not duly
implemented, nor were they adequately enforced. Moreover, policymakers have been too
impatient, often expecting results to materialize sooner than warranted. While the
42
From a more general perspective, Easterly (2001) points out that despite significant policy reforms,
developing countries have on average stagnated over the last two decades. He argues that worldwide
factors may have contributed to this stagnation and says that this evidence deals a significant blow to the
optimism surrounding the “Washington Consensus.”
43
The increase in public sector debt holdings was driven by several factors, including central banks’
growing use of bonds as monetary policy instruments, post-crisis bank restructurings in several countries,
and increasing fiscal deficits. In countries where banking crises where not massive and government deficits
were limited, credit to the private sector grew reasonably well (Hanson, 2003).
44
Stock markets in many developing countries have seen listings and liquidity decrease, as a growing
number of firms have cross-listed and raised capital in international financial centers, such as New York
and London. Karolyi (2004) and Moel (2001) offer evidence on how the use of American Depositary
Receipts (ADRs) can affect stock markets in emerging economies. Levine and Schmukler (2006a,b)
analyze the impact of migration to international markets on domestic market trading and liquidity.
45
Loayza, Fajnzylber, and Calderon (2005) analyze whether the growth outcome of the reforms of the
1990s in Latin America can be interpreted as a disappointment. They estimate the expected impact of the
reforms on economic growth using cross-country regressions and then compare the predicted growth rate of
Latin American countries on the basis of the reforms with their observed growth during the 1990s. They
find that most Latin American countries experienced growth rates consistent with the extent of the reforms
and thus conclude that reforms had the predicted impact. However, the estimated pay-offs of the reforms in
many cases are quite small, suggesting that initial expectations may have been overly optimistic.
46
Renditions of this view, in the more general context of assessing the impact of reforms on economic
development, can be found in Fernandez Arias and Montiel (2001), Krueger (2004), Singh et al. (2005),
and World Bank (1997).
22
expectation of a rapid payoff may be justified with respect to some first-generation
reforms, more complex second-generation reforms have long gestation periods. 47
Proponents of the laissez-faire view also point out that, even in environments
where there are institutional deficiencies that negatively affect financial contracting, there
has been some progress in expanding access. One example of this is the strong growth of
microfinance in developing countries. Microfinance consists in the provision of financial
services to low-income individuals and informal firms. 48 Microfinance institutions have
developed several mechanisms to deal with principal-agent problems and help reduce the
transaction costs of serving small borrowers (see Appendix 1 for a general overview of
microfinance). Unsecured consumer credit, including credit card lending, has also
experienced significant growth in many developing countries in recent years (see, for
example, BIS, 2005a and The Economist, 2006), fostered by advances in information
systems and scoring methods. 49
Although the arguments of the laissez-faire view are quite compelling and have
attained widespread support, the associated policy prescription is not free of problems.
Improving the enabling environment is easier said than done. Even if we knew exactly
what needs to be done, and in what sequence, there is no denying that the actual reform
implementation would be full of glitches and affected by the two-steps-forward-one-step-
backward phenomenon. But the reality is that we do not know with precision all that
needs to be done, as there is no ex-ante formula to achieve access-enhancing financial
development. Financial development is not amenable to one-size-fits-all or a “template”
approach, not least because of its evolutionary, path-dependent nature, as noted above. A
good enabling environment is in effect the historical result of a complicated and rather
delicate combination of mutually reinforcing institutional innovations and market
dynamics—which cannot be transplanted at will from one country to another. Hence,
financial reforms that are partial, inadequately complemented, or wrongly sequenced may
lead to dysfunctional yet self-reinforcing institutional hybrids, which may be
subsequently hard to dislodge. Learning and re-learning will be needed along the way,
including through the cleansing aspects of financial crises and the pressures of
competition, in order to re-route the process of financial development.
47
In general terms, first-generation reforms concern those taken as part of the initial wave of efforts to
regain macroeconomic stability while de-regulating the economy. In the financial sector, first-generation
reforms focused mainly on liberalizing the domestic financial market and on allowing freer cross-border
capital mobility. Second-generation reforms concern the subsequent wave of reforms that are, by and large,
much more intensive in institution building. In the financial sector, these entail, for instance, strengthening
prudential oversight and transparency, improving creditor rights systems, enhancing corporate governance
practices and minority shareholder protection, modernizing market infrastructures, etc.
48
As CGAP (2003a) emphasizes, while microfinance originally focused on working-capital loans to micro-
entrepreneurs, it has now expanded to include all sorts of financial services provided to low-income
individuals, including savings, credit, insurance, and money transfer services. See also Honohan (2004).
49
This rapid expansion may create some risks in the absence of prudent credit policies, as illustrated by the
case of Korea where a credit card lending boom, partially fuelled by tax incentives, led to significant losses
(see BIS, 2005a and The Economist, 2003).
23
environment and see any results in terms of broader access to credit. Even innovative
solutions like microfinance that, at least partially, help to overcome institutional
deficiencies are unlikely to broaden access significantly in the short term. 50 It seems
rather naive to expect governments to remain completely disengaged from any direct
intervention geared at broadening access during the long transition to a developed
financial system. For one, governments are likely to face increasing political pressures to
do something. As mentioned above, there is a growing disillusionment with the reform
process of the 1990s as reforms have failed to meet the (possibly excessive) initial
expectations. While it can be questioned whether this disillusionment is warranted or not,
reform fatigue is in any case likely to boost pressures for government intervention.
Second, in many countries governments are still so engaged in the financial system that a
quick withdrawal may not be possible. Existing public financial institutions have
institutional incentives to continue intervening in financial markets and in many cases
closing them or significantly downscaling their operations may not be politically feasible
or even desirable, given existing linkages among markets and institutional arrangements.
Finally, one could reasonably argue that certain government interventions may help to
smooth the transition towards a developed financial system or even speed it up, without
distracting from the long-run policy objective of institutional reform.
The pro-market activism view is an emerging new view that rationalizes a series
of recent government interventions. Given that this view is quite recent and just emerging
it is difficult to accurately characterize it. It may be easier to understand it by contrasting
it with the two well-established views described above. In contrast with the
interventionist view, the pro-market activism view does not assume that market failures
are widespread and that therefore direct government intervention in the allocation and
pricing of credit is necessary. Much to the contrary, this view argues that markets can and
do broaden access to finance and therefore the adequate role of the government is to
promote the development of deep and efficient financial markets, not to replace them.
This view recognizes that direct government interventions may be warranted in some
cases, but argues that careful analyses to identify market failures and specify their causes
should precede interventions. The observation that a certain group lacks access to credit
does not constitute by itself an indication of a market failure and therefore cannot justify
interventions in credit markets. Interventions should be directed at solving market failures
underlying problems of access, not at increasing the use of financial services per se. And
50
Despite its strong growth over the last years, microfinance penetration is still quite low in most countries.
For instance, Daley-Harris (2003) reports that the ratio of borrowing clients of microfinance institutions to
the total population exceeds two percent in only eight countries and in most developing countries this ratio
is below one percent.
24
even if a market failure is identified, public sector interventions can only be justified if
they can solve this failure in a cost-effective manner. According to the pro-market
activism view, government interventions should be designed to complement or facilitate
the development of financial markets through the adequate choice of instruments
(subsidies, funding, etc.) and institutions (private financial intermediaries, NGOs, public
banks). This view is well aware of the risks of government lending, and therefore favors a
wide range of instruments beyond lending. If subsidies are deemed necessary to solve a
specific market failure, they should be restricted to seed capital to launch a project or be
limited by sunset clauses and in all cases must be transparently budgeted to avoid the
price distortions that have characterized past government interventions in financial
markets.
Thus, the main message of pro-market activism is that there is indeed a market
friendly role for the visible hand of the government to promote access in the short run,
while the fruits of ongoing institutional reform are still unripe. The important qualifier is,
however, that the government needs to be highly selective in its interventions, always
trying to ensure that they work with the market, never against it. Interventions should be
relatively small and temporary, being terminated when the underlying causes of the
problem of access have been removed. There must also be mechanisms in place to
prevent political capture that may undermine the temporary nature of the interventions or
their compatibility with the long-run objective of institutional reform and financial
market development. Pro-market activism, moreover, favors a policy strategy that
explicitly creates room for a process of discovery and learning-by-doing as the
interventions are implemented, and may be useful to give the authorities a first hand
understanding of what legislation or enforcement mechanisms are missing for certain
innovations to take off. For pro-market activism, the ultimate goal is to foster the
broadening of access in ways that simultaneously create financial markets where they are
missing or enhance the functioning of the existing ones.
25
anchored in two strategies: an investment strategy designed to kick-start growth, and an
institution building strategy (…)” Similarly, Zagha (2004) argues that reviewing the
experience of the 1990s “confirms the importance for growth of fundamental principles:
macro-stability, market forces in the allocation of resources, and openness” and also
shows that “selective government interventions can contribute to growth when they
address market failures, when and where they are carried out effectively, and are subject
to institutional checks.” As mentioned above, this emerging view is still far from
providing clear guidelines on development policies. It is a more nuanced view that calls
for policy diversity, selective and modest reforms, and experimentation. In fact, its main
characteristic seems to be the recognition of the need to avoid one-size-fits all strategies
and to follow a more targeted approach taking into account country specificities. World
Bank (2005b), for instance, argues that “there is no unique set of rules (…) [W]e need to
get away from formulae and the search for elusive ‘best practices’ (…)” While a more
nuanced approach to development policies may be necessary, this view runs the risk of
degenerating into an “anything-goes” approach. The main challenge for this emerging
view is translating its recommendations into specific operational guidelines for promoting
development, without degenerating into a rigid blueprint.
For all of its potential appeal, pro-market activism raises many questions. Are
there actually cases where government interventions do not displace financial market
activity, but rather crowd it in? Can direct interventions indeed be designed so as to
ensure that at least no harm is done? If a given government intervention is efficient, in
the sense that it leads to greater, mutually beneficial financial contracting, why don’t
private financial intermediaries take the initiative? Is direct government intervention
necessary or, given the right incentives, private financial intermediaries would take the
initiative? While it is very difficult to provide a definite answer to these questions, we
will try to address them in the next section by analyzing how pro-market activism has
worked in a number of recent experiences in Latin America. It is necessary to stress that
we do not attempt to make a comprehensive assessment of these interventions or to claim
that they have been successful. Rather, we use them to illustrate how pro-market activism
has worked in practice and understand to what extent actual experiences have conformed
to the stylized description of this view presented so far. This analysis will also help us to
identify potential implementation problems, as well as pitfalls that must be avoided in the
design of pro-market interventions.
26
4. Recent Pro-Market Interventions in Latin America
This section describes a number of recent experiences from Latin America that
illustrate the approach of the pro-market activism view to government interventions. To
guide the discussion, we group these experiences in terms of the type of instrument used
in each case. However, most interventions are not as clear-cut in practice, as they tend to
combine several instruments. This bundling of different instruments is in most cases the
result of institutional design and incentives. An open question is whether these
components can be effectively unbundled. The classification by type of instrument is
used mainly for presentational purposes, to help depict the nature of the intervention
under analysis and highlight the relevant policy issues. Two additional caveats are
necessary before turning to the description of these experiences. In the first place, some
of the instruments used in these interventions are similar to those promoted by
proponents of the interventionist view (i.e., public lending, subsidies, and credit
guarantees). However, pro-market interventions tend to differ from previous ones in
important aspects of their design—especially regarding sustainability, time limits,
governance, and transparency—and even in terms of their objectives, as they seek to
complement and promote private financial intermediation, rather than replace it. Second,
we focus on extracting the main policy lessons from these interventions, rather than on
describing them in detail. Detailed descriptions of each experience are available in a
number of appendices and several papers.
27
kind of arrangements, as they can (and do) take place among private parties. 51 However,
in many developing countries some of the largest networks of non-financial outlets are
owned or regulated by the public sector. Therefore, in order to achieve a wide geographic
coverage it is necessary for the government to allow financial institutions to use some of
these networks to distribute their services. In the case of Brazil, lottery houses have been
used by the federal savings bank Caixa Economica Federal (CEF) to distribute financial
services. The right to provide banking services through the post office was granted to
Banco Bradesco, the largest private bank in Brazil, through a public bidding process. The
use of correspondents significantly reduces the cost of servicing remote locations.
According to Kumar et al. (2006), initial investments for a correspondent outpost in
Brazil can be as low as 0.5 percent of those for a traditional bank branch, and operating
costs are negligible if existing employees and communication networks are used. This
has resulted in a significant geographic expansion in access to financial services. While in
2001 29 percent of the municipalities in Brazil had no bank services (branches or bank
service outposts), by 2004 all municipalities had access to these services, with 31 percent
of them being served exclusively by bank correspondents.
51
Even if direct government intervention is not necessary to promote correspondent banking, regulatory
changes in several areas, including the use of electronic payment systems, account opening requirements,
and agency relationships, may be required (CGAP, 2006). In the case of Brazil, for example, a number of
Central Bank resolutions between 1999 and 2000 were key in the development of correspondent banking,
by allowing correspondents to provide banking services, clarifying existing rules, and eliminating certain
restrictions (Kumar et al., 2006).
52
BANSEFI was established in 2001 to replace PANHAL (Patronato Nacional del Ahorro), a government-
owned narrow bank that focused exclusively on mobilizing savings by capturing deposits, mostly among
small rural clients, and investing these funds in government debt securities.
53
See Appendix 2, Coutinho (2006), and Taber (2005) for more detailed descriptions of BANSEFI’s
operations.
54
BANSEFI has a second, separate mandate to promote savings by acting as a narrow bank, which it
inherited from its predecessor, PANHAL. This second mandate may place it in competition with some of
the popular savings and credit institutions it is supposed to support, generating some conflicts of interest
(see CGAP, 2005a).
28
services, debit and credit card services, and foreign exchange and derivatives transactions
to the popular savings and credit institutions to allow them to capture economies of scale
and scope that they may not be able to achieve individually. In the case of liquidity
services, for instance, BANSEFI can consolidate the liquidity of all the participant
institutions and invest it on their behalf in the commercial banking system, securing a
higher rate of return than what the institutions could negotiate individually. BANSEFI is
developing a technological platform to allow the sector to operate effectively as a
network and to help institutions minimize operation and supervision costs. These
centralized services are offered at fee and can be voluntarily contracted by the
institutions. BANSEFI has also created a commercial alliance among several popular
savings and credit institutions (L@Red de la Gente, The People’s Network) to share
branches and facilitate the distribution of financial products. 55 This network uses a
common technological platform to distribute financial products, helping to generate
homogenous products that are offered under an umbrella trademark, significantly
reducing distribution and marketing costs. L@Red de la Gente is also used to distribute
several government programs and operates with traditional money transfer companies
that use its network to distribute remittances. This increases the revenues of member
institutions through distribution fees and helps to attract new customers and bring them
into the financial system.
55
This network is currently integrated by 68 institutions with a total of 1,170 branches, including 548
branches that BANSEFI inherited from PANHAL.
56
See Appendix 3, Naranjo (2005), and Klapper (2005) for detailed descriptions of this program.
29
not a loan. There is no debt repayment and no additional liabilities on the supplier’s
balance sheet. An alternative to ordinary factoring is reverse factoring. In this case, the
factor only purchases accounts receivable issued by certain buyers. Reverse factoring
reduces information problems, as the factor only needs to assess the credit worthiness of
a specific group of large firms. A significant advantage of factoring, especially in
developing countries, is that it does not require good collateral laws, just the legal ability
to sell, or assign, accounts receivables.
NAFIN was responsible for the development, production, and marketing costs
related to the electronic platform. It operates the system and also handles all the legal
work. NAFIN requires all participating financial institutions to use its second-tier funding
to provide credit through the system. 57 In fact, NAFIN does not charge a fee for the
factoring services, but rather covers its costs with the interest it charges on its loans.
NAFIN’s factoring program has been very successful, extending over nine billion U.S.
dollars in financing since its inception in September 2001 and brokering more than 1.2
million transactions, 98 percent by SMEs. More than half of NAFIN’s second-tier
lending in 2004 corresponded to the financing of factoring transactions originated from
this program. NAFIN has entered into agreements with development banks in several
Latin American countries, including Colombia, El Salvador, and Venezuela, to
implement similar programs and development banks in other countries in the region are
considering replicating this program. See Appendix 3 for more details on NAFIN’s
reverse factoring program.
30
or SPV), which in turn issues securities backed by this asset pool. Typically, several
classes of securities (called tranches) with distinct risk-return profiles are issued. 59
Innovations abound in this market and several types of assets have been included in the
collateral pool, ranging from cash instruments (e.g., mortgages, loans, bonds, credit card
receivables) to synthetic exposures (e.g., credit default swaps). The structured finance
market in developed countries has experienced significant growth over the last years (see
BIS, 2005b). In the case of developing countries, although the volume of transactions
has also increased significantly, structured finance markets are still small and
underdeveloped. 60
59
Some authors (see, for example, Alles, 2001, and BIS, 2005b) differentiate between securitization (which
only involves the pooling and transfer of assets to a third party and subsequent issuance of securities) and
structured financing (which also involves the creation of different classes of securities). In keeping with
common usage, we use the term structured finance to refer to both types of instruments.
60
See Meddin (2004) for an overview of structured finance in emerging markets and the role it may play in
fostering capital market development.
61
See Appendix 4 for a more detailed description of FIRA’s structured finance operations.
62
Ocean Garden is one of the main exporters of Mexican shrimp to the U.S. It handles approximately one
quarter of Mexico’s shrimp production and has annual sales of about 250 million U.S. dollars. The firm
was owned by the Mexican government and was recently privatized.
63
This happens when credit losses exceed approximately 32 percent of the total asset pool, see Appendix 4
for details.
31
arranger in this transaction, but also as a financial guarantor providing guarantees to
partially cover credit losses once the liquid guarantees from industry participants are
exhausted. FIRA charges a fee for its services as arranger and also for the provision of
the guarantees. FIRA requires all investors participating in this scheme, which are
financial institutions, to use its second tier lending to purchase the securities issued by the
SPV.
Credit guarantee systems are mechanisms in which a third party, the guarantor,
pledges to guarantee loans to a particular group of borrowers. Credit guarantee systems
reduce the lender’s expected credit losses—even if the probability of default remains
unchanged—acting as a form of insurance against default. Public credit guarantee
systems are widespread: according to a survey conducted by Graham Bannock and
Partners, in 1995 there were at least 85 countries with some type of government credit
guarantee program. 64 The largest and more established guarantee schemes are mostly in
developed countries, including Canada, Japan, the U.S., and several European countries.
The general experience with credit guarantee systems, especially in developing countries,
has been poor to mixed, at best: most systems have depleted their reserves due to high
64
Graham Bannock and Partners (1997) find that in 14 countries there is no public credit guarantee system
and in another 76 countries it is not possible to tell whether operating guarantee schemes exist. See also
Herrero Calvo and Pombo Gonzalez (2001) for an overview of public credit guarantee systems around the
world.
32
credit losses and bad investment decisions and in many cases they have been designed to
channel funds to certain sectors without due regard to loss rates.
There is significant debate in the literature regarding the role fulfilled by credit
guarantees and the need for this type of government intervention (see for example, Green,
2003; Holden, 1997; Levitsky, 1997a; Rodriguez Meza, 2004; and Vogel and Adams,
1997). The most frequent cited justification for credit guarantee schemes is as a substitute
for collateral where the collateral market operates imperfectly due to cumbersome and
costly repossession processes, political difficulties in the realization of assets pledged by
certain sectors, or uncertainty about the value of collateral, which lead to excessive
collateral requirements. 65 However, one could reasonably argue that imperfections in the
legal system should be addressed through improvements in collateral laws and
enforcement mechanisms, rather than through direct government intervention (Holden,
1997; Vogel and Adams, 1997). Nevertheless, both strategies are not necessarily
exclusive, at least in the short-term (Graham Bannock and Partners, 1997), and therefore
collateral guarantee systems could help to reduce problems of access to finance while
institutional reform is taking time to mature. 66 An alternative argument contends that
credit guarantee systems work as subsidies to cover the costs of learning how to provide
loans to a new group of borrowers by financial intermediaries. However, as Vogel and
Adams (1997) point out, there is no evidence of public programs that have been able to
eliminate guarantees after a certain period. Critics of public credit guarantee systems also
argue that these schemes cannot decrease asymmetric information problems in credit
markets, and are even likely to increase them. Public guarantee systems may increase
moral hazard for both borrowers and lenders: borrowers that know that their loans are
guaranteed by the government may not feel obligated to repay them and lenders may
have fewer incentives for screening and monitoring borrowers, as guarantees cover their
credit losses. An open question therefore is whether credit guarantee systems can be
designed in a market-friendly way, minimizing their unintended consequences while at
the same time promoting private financial market activity. 67
65
Public credit guarantee systems have also been justified in terms of market failures, although the nature
of these failures is usually not identified (Vogel and Adams, 1997). And even if a market failure is
identified, it is not clear whether credit guarantee schemes are the best form of addressing it. One possible
market failure could be the absence of credit insurance markets (Rodriguez Meza, 2004).
66
Benavente, Galetovic, and Sanhueza (2006) develop a theoretical model showing that under certain
conditions, credit guarantee systems can improve access to credit for borrowers with viable projects that
would otherwise be excluded due to lack of collateral, without increasing moral hazard.
67
See Levitsky (1997b) for a review of best practices in operating guarantee schemes. Bennett, Billington,
and Doran (2005) analyze some recent successful experiences of credit guarantee systems in developing
countries.
33
Banco Estado, a public commercial bank, which charges a fee for its services. FOGAPE
functions as a classical guarantee fund, sharing the risk of default on eligible loans and
charging a guarantee premium. The commercial relationship is between FOGAPE and the
banks. Banks select those loans that the wish guaranteed and FOGAPE only checks
whether they meet eligibility criteria. 68 According to Benavente, Galetovic, and Sanhueza
(2006), several features of FOGAPE’s operations have been key in reducing moral
hazard problems. First, commercial banks share part of the risk of default, as guarantees
only cover between 70 and 80 percent of credit losses. Second, and more important, to
allocate the available guarantees Banco Estado conducts auctions four to six times per
year among participating banks. Each bank has to submit a bid indicating the amount of
guarantee it wants to receive and the maximum coverage rate as a percentage of lending.
The bids are selected by the lowest coverage required until the total amount auctioned has
been assigned; therefore the biding process determines how the risks are shared among
FOGAPE and financial intermediaries. 69 Banks with high default rates on previously
guaranteed loans can be permanently or temporarily excluded from participating in the
bidding process (this has already happened in one case). This helps to reduce moral
hazard, as banks that reduce screening and monitoring today lose profitable opportunities
in the future. Also, the use of a bidding process increases competition among financial
institutions. The risk share taken by commercial banks has increased from 21 percent in
2001 to 29 percent in 2003 (Bennett, Billington, and Doran, 2005). Third, the amount of
FOGAPE guarantees each bank can obtain is limited: no bank can be awarded more than
two thirds of the total rights auctioned. This also helps to reduce moral hazard, as the
amount that can be gained by reducing screening and monitoring today is reduced.
Following the bidding process, banks have three months to grant the corresponding loans.
68
The main eligibility criteria are related to borrower and loan size. Also, total exposure of the guarantee
fund to each borrower through loans from all banks is limited to UF 5,000 (approximately 120,000 U.S.
dollars).
69
FOGAPE establishes maximum guarantee coverages of 80 and 70 percent for long- and short-term loans,
respectively.
70
In comparison, default rates for the banking system as a whole stood at 1.01 percent.
71
Graham Bannock and Partners (1997) claim that in practice no government credit guarantee scheme has
been found to be able to cover administrative costs and default claims with fees collected. There is some
34
4.4 Transaction Cost Subsidies
The provision of a subsidy like SIEBAN could be justified on the basis of one of
the arguments mentioned above for the creation of public credit guarantee systems, that
is, subsidizing the costs for financial institutions of learning how to provide loans to a
new group, in this case low-income rural borrowers. However, SIEBAN has several
design features that address the limitations of credit guarantees in achieving this
objective. First, as Vogel and Adams (1997) point out, there is no evidence of public
debate on this issue as Riding (1997), for instance, argues that the Canadian Small Business Loan Act , the
Small Business Administration in the U.S., and the Loan Guarantee Scheme in the U.K. operate, in some
cases, on a break-even basis.
35
guarantee programs that have been able to eliminate guarantees after a certain period. In
contrast, SIEBAN is designed to be temporary: after three years borrowers no longer
receive any subsidy. Second, SIEBAN does not generate moral hazard. As discussed
above, credit guarantee systems reduce incentives for financial institutions to screen and
monitor borrowers, as the guarantee covers part of their credit losses. In the case of
SIEBAN, there is no risk shifting to the public sector Financial intermediaries only
receive a (relatively small) fixed initial subsidy and have incentives to adequately assess
borrowers’ credit quality, since they face all the costs in case of default. Another
important feature of SIEBAN is that it requires financial intermediaries to register
borrowers in the credit bureau, consistent with the idea of reducing the information
asymmetries that typically characterize small borrowers. An open question, however, is
how effective SIEBAN has actually been in improving access to credit and whether small
borrowers continue to receive credit once the subsidy ends. Also, the program is provided
by FIRA, which finances it with the profits from other operations. To increase
transparency, subsidies should be explicitly budgeted and separate from the provision of
financial services.
As described above, the general experience with the provision of credit by public
banks has been negative, resulting in high subsidies, recurring fiscal drains, and retarding,
rather than fostering, financial market development. Major incentive and governance
problems in the operation of public banks have tended to surface, leading to poor loan
origination and even poorer loan collection, wasteful administrative expenditures,
overstaffing, plain corruption, and political manipulation of lending. An open question is
whether there is any role for the provision of public credit in fostering financial
development and if this type of intervention can be designed in a way that ensures that at
least no harm is done.
Yaron, Benjamin, and Charitonenko (1998) argue that some experiences from
Asia, such as the Village Bank program of the Bank Rayat Indonesia, show that public
institutions can provide credit to rural producers in an efficient, market-friendly way and
that subsidies are not necessary for the provision of financial services to these producers.
They highlight the role of several mechanisms in increasing efficiency, such as shifting
from disbursing credit to motivating loan recovery, establishing a hard budget constraint,
increasing management autonomy, introducing innovative systems for both clients and
employees to encourage repayment, and increasing staff accountability.
36
situation, as Besley (1994) argues, there might be a role for the government to subsidize
innovation. A key factor for the success of Banco Estado’s microfinance program has
been the implementation of a new organizational structure tailored to meet the needs of
micro entrepreneurs. Banco Estado also established new incentive systems for
employees. An important change in this respect has been the increase in the fixed portion
of the remuneration of account executives, in order to reduce incentives to focus solely
on loan disbursement. Banco Estado’s microfinance operations are managed by a
separate business unit with its own profit and loss statement. The program was designed
to be self-sustainable, without providing any subsidies. In fact, this program achieved
break-even by the third year of operations and has remained profitable since then.
5. Final Remarks
One of the objectives of this study was to once more call the attention of
policymakers, development institutions, and academics alike to the fact that there are
many problems of access to credit in developing countries, generated by the difficulties
of solving principal-agent problems and reducing transaction costs in weak institutional
environments. As a result, the penetration of formal credit in most developing countries is
low and banks are disengaged from many economic activities.
37
sustainable interventions that aim to foster market activity, not replace it. However, one
could reasonably question to what extent these experiences are the consequence of a
specific institutional environment that favors government innovation and reduces the risk
of political capture. Also, these interventions may be a result of certain characteristics of
the public financial institutions that have implemented them, such as their management
quality. A better understanding of these issues is key to determining to what extent these
experiences can be replicated in other countries. As we have emphasized throughout this
study, financial development is intrinsically linked to the institutional environment and
therefore, government interventions that work under a given institutional matrix and at a
given stage of financial development may produce unintended effects when transplanted
to another institutional milieu. This suggests that interventions should be modified to take
into account the idiosyncrasies of the institutional arrangements and market conditions in
each country. A related question is whether, even if experiences can be replicated with
some adjustments to local conditions, the government should try to create organizational
capabilities to implement pro-market interventions where these capabilities do not exist.
38
institutions to combine more innovative market friendly interventions with the provision
of loans, even if liquidity is not a constraint for private financial intermediaries. The
bundling of more innovative instruments with traditional ones— such as second-tier
lending, guarantees, and subsidies—motivated by the use of traditional performance
indicators, makes it very difficult to analyze the individual merits of each instrument.
Bundling also carries the risk of distorting prices and incentives. Fostering the
proliferation of new market friendly instruments may require basing the evaluation of
development-oriented financial institutions on a new set of indicators, including measures
of the increase in financial activity generated by their interventions and indicators of their
impact on economic activity and the socio-economic environment of the targeted
population. These new indicators may be more difficult to design and estimate than
traditional ones, and it may take time and a process of trial and error to find the correct
indicators to evaluate each type of intervention.
39
Fourth, an open question is whether there is a need for pro-market interventions in
the long run. As discussed throughout this study, the economy’s first best is achieving a
good enabling environment that allows financial markets to flourish. In this context, pro-
market interventions are seen as short-term solutions to broaden access while institutional
reforms are taking time to mature and may even help to speed up the process. However, it
is not clear whether once a good enabling environment is achieved there is a need for
direct government interventions. If there are long-term market failures that even in a good
contractual environment cannot be dealt with by private parties, there could be a role for
pro-market interventions in the long run. The widespread intervention of the public sector
in financial markets in developed countries suggests that this could be the case. However,
one could question to what extent the persistence of these interventions is the result of
political capture and self-reinforcing institutional arrangements that make it very difficult
to dismantle them, even if they are no longer useful for fostering financial market
development. Further research is needed to clarify this issue.
40
Appendix 1
An Overview of Microfinance
As microfinance has evolved, there has been an increasing flexibility in the use of
techniques, with business models and lending technologies now differing widely across
countries and even across microfinance institutions within a given country. This is partly
the result of the still experimental nature of microfinance and also reflects the need to
adapt to local conditions. As the practices of microfinance institutions have changed,
their lending techniques have become increasingly similar to those of mainstream
financial institutions (Honohan, 2004).
72
See, for example, Hardy, Holden, and Prokopenko (2002) for a description of how the availability of
debtor information systems combined with scoring technologies has allowed Banco del Trabajo in Peru to
become a commercially-viable microfinance institution. CGAP (2003b) presents an overview of how
scoring works and its application to microfinance.
41
governments (Hardy, Holden, and Prokopenko, 2002). However, there has been an
increasing trend towards microfinance operations becoming self-sustainable and
commercially viable. Between 1992 and March 2003, 39 NGOs in 15 countries have
transformed into full-fledged banks, while another 200 have become supervised non-bank
financial institutions, either permanently or as an interim step towards becoming a bank
(Krebsbach, 2003). Some of these microfinance institutions have even been able to
successfully issue bonds in local capital markets (Jansson, 2002). Also, several
commercial banks have started to enter the microfinance market, either by providing
financial services directly to low-income customers or acting through existing
microfinance institutions (see, for example, CGAP, 2005b; Littlefield and Rosenborg,
2004; and The Economist, 2005). These trends have been particularly pronounced in
Latin America, where by 2001 commercial banks provided around 29 percent of
financing to micro enterprises, while NGOs that became licensed financial institutions,
together with other non-bank licensed financial intermediaries, provided an additional 45
percent (CGAP, 2001). 73
Despite its strong growth over the last years, microfinance penetration is still
quite low in most countries. For instance, Daley-Harris (2003) reports that the ratio of
borrowing clients of microfinance institutions to the total population exceeds 2 percent in
only eight countries and in most countries (35 out of a total of 55 developing countries
covered by the study) this ratio is below 1 percent. CGAP (2004) analyzes the penetration
of all institutions that focus on expanding financial services to the poor, including not
only microfinance institutions, but also postal savings banks, financial cooperatives, rural
banks, and development banks. Its results indicate that the number of savings and loan
accounts in these institutions as a percentage of the total population reaches 4 percent in
Africa, 5 percent in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, and 3 percent in Latin America.
Coverage is much higher in East and South Asia, reaching 17 percent of the population.
73
In 2001 the microfinance industry in Latin America served approximately 1.5 to two million clients and
had a total loan portfolio of about 1.5 billion U.S. dollars. There were 97 specialized regulated financial
institutions operating in this segment, most of which were created through the transformation of NGOs,
with a combined portfolio of 914 million U.S. dollars (Jansson, 2002).
42
Appendix 2
BANSEFI’s Experience
1. Introduction
Access to financial services in Mexico is very limited. World Bank (2003b), for
instance, estimates that three quarters of the adult population of Mexico City has no bank
account or any dealings with a financial institution. In the case of rural areas, access to
financial services is even more reduced, with only 6 percent of households using formal
financial savings instruments and less than 3 percent having access to credit from a
financial institution (World Bank, 2001). Bank density rates are low, with a country-wide
average of one branch per 12,000 people. Around 74 percent of municipalities,
representing 22 percent of the population, have no bank branch (World Bank, 2004b).
Between 1996 and 1999 the Mexican government tried to encourage commercial
banks to extend their presence in rural areas by subsidizing the costs of opening and
operating new branches. However, this project failed to induce a significant expansion of
branch networks, partly as a result of the consequences of the 1994-1995 financial crisis,
but also due to the availability of alternative profitable opportunities for commercial
banks. Also, opening new branches in rural areas represented a significant investment in
74
See Table 2.1.
43
new infrastructure and staff for commercial banks and required them to develop
knowledge on rural economic activities.
The failure of these attempts to increase access to financial services in rural areas
led the Mexican government to focus on strengthening popular savings and credit
institutions in order to help them increase their outreach. Since these intermediaries were
already working in rural areas and had knowledge of rural economic activities, the
incremental cost of extending client outreach for them was expected to be smaller than
for commercial banks. To this end, the government developed a new regulatory and
supervisory framework for popular savings and credit institutions. The decision to create
a new legal framework was also motivated by the failure of several of these institutions
due to fraudulent activities in the late 1990s (Taber, 2005).
The new legal framework, enacted through the Ley de Ahorro y Credito Popular
(Savings and Popular Credit Act), became effective in June 2001. This law provides for
the gradual incorporation of popular savings and credit institutions into the new legal
framework over a four-year period. Under this law, two types of popular savings and
credit institutions will be authorized to mobilize deposits from the public: Sociedades
Cooperativas de Ahorro y Credito (Savings and Credit Cooperatives) and Sociedades
Financieras Populares (Popular Financial Associations). The main difference between
the two is that the former are non-profits owned by their members, while the later are
partial for-profits owned by shareholders. The scope of financial intermediation activities
allowed, as well as the regulatory and supervisory standards applied, depends on several
characteristics of institutions, including asset size, number of clients, number of branches,
geographic location, and technical and operational capabilities, with four distinct
categories. The CNBV (Comisión Nacional Bancaria y de Valores, National Banking and
Securities Commission) is responsible for regulating and supervising the sector and
licensing the different popular savings and credit institutions. The new legal framework
establishes an auxiliary supervision scheme, with federations (voluntary groupings of
popular savings and credit institutions) enforcing secondary regulations and carrying out
some supervision and oversight tasks. 75 To be licensed by the CNBV an institution must
first receive a favorable rating from the supervision committee of its federation.
Federations are grouped in confederations, which are responsible for operating a deposit
insurance fund. This fund will be created using an initial government contribution and
will subsequently be strengthened with contributions from popular savings and credit
institutions. Both federations and confederations are licensed by the CNBV.
2. BANSEFI’s Role
As part of its strategy of fostering the development of the popular savings and
credit sector, in April 2001 the government created BANSEFI (Banco de Ahorro
Nacional y Servicios Financieros, National Savings and Financial Services Bank), a
development bank with the objective of providing support to this sector. BANSEFI was
created out of PANHAL (Patronato Nacional del Ahorro), a government-owned narrow
75
This system of auxiliary supervision is based on the models of financial cooperative supervision
employed in Germany and Canada.
44
bank that focused exclusively on mobilizing savings by capturing deposits, mostly among
small-scale rural clients, and investing these funds in government debt securities.
BANSEFI has two main mandates: first, promoting savings by acting as a narrow bank (a
function it inherited from PANHAL) and second spearheading the development of the
popular savings and credit sector.
BANSEFI has also created a commercial alliance among several popular savings
and credit institutions (L@Red de la Gente, The People’s Network) to share branches and
facilitate the distribution of financial products. 76 This network uses a common
technological platform to distribute financial products, helping to generate homogenous
products that are offered under an umbrella trademark, significantly reducing distribution
and marketing costs. L@Red de la Gente is also used to distribute several government
programs and operates with traditional money transfer companies that use its network to
distribute remittances. 77 This provides additional revenues to member institutions
through distribution fees and helps to attract new customers and increase financial
76
This network is currently integrated by 68 institutions with a total of 1,170 branches, including 548
branches that BANSEFI inherited from PANHAL.
77
Remittances are a major source of income in Mexico. In 2004 Mexicans received 16.6 billion U.S.
dollars in remittances and estimates for 2005 are around 20 billion. About 75 percent of the 25 million
emigrants living abroad have no access to financial services (BANSEFI, 2006).
45
services penetration. The distribution of government programs is linked to the opening of
savings accounts for beneficiaries, helping to introduce them into the financial system. At
the end of 2003, for instance, more than 80 percent of the beneficiaries of the
Oportunidades government program who received their benefits through L@ Red kept
positive balances in their accounts.78 There is no exclusivity agreement or legislation
restricting competition for the distribution of government programs and therefore L@Red
de la Gente must provide its distribution services on a competitive basis.
3. Policy Discussion
78
The Oportunidades program provides cash transfers for health and education expenses to lower-income
families.
46
However, it argues that this would take a long time and therefore some type of
government intervention is necessary to speed-up the process (see BANSEFI, 2003).
79
Although the law authorizes BANSEFI to lend to the popular savings and credit institutions and their
clients, it has concentrated on providing fee-based services and does not take any credit risk exposure, as
this could threaten its sustainability. Also, providing credit to the public would place BANSEFI in direct
competition with private institutions, which runs contrary to its objective of fostering financial market
development. While the fact that BANSEFI has avoided providing credit is commendable, one could
reasonably argue that the best option to reduce political risk would be to explicitly prohibit BANSEFI from
extending credit.
47
this sale are currently under analysis (BANSEFI, 2006) and many sector representatives
have expressed interest in taking part (CGAP, 2005a).
On aspect of BANSEFI’s experience that raises some questions is the fact that, as
described above, it performs two tasks in relation to popular savings and credit
institutions: giving them technical support to help them become formal financial
institutions and providing them with centralized services to help them achieve economies
of scale and scope. An open question is whether having a single institution fulfill both
tasks may not generate some incentive problems. For instance, since BANSEFI provides
popular savings and credit institutions with technical support and training, they might feel
pressured to use its centralized services, even if these services do not add much value or
are not competitively priced. Of course, constructing a technological platform to help
informal institutions to reduce their costs may not make much sense if these institutions
are not sustainable and lack adequate capabilities. Therefore, upgrading informal
institutions may be a pre-condition to the provision of centralized services, and both
functions may complement each other, to the extent that sustainable institutions may be
better able to take advantage of the cost reductions generated by the centralized provision
of back-office services, and lower costs may increase sustainability. However, while
admitting that both tasks are necessary, one could reasonably question whether they
should be performed by the same institution. In the case of BANSEFI, this problem may
be compounded by the fact that it has second separate mandate. As mentioned above,
BANSEFI inherited a wide network of branches from PANHAL that capture deposits and
invest them in government securities. The participation of BANSEFI in the retail savings
sector may place it in competition with popular savings and credit institutions. In fact,
according to CGAP (2005a), some of the largest institutions have opted not to use
BANSEFI’s centralized services because they see it as a potential competitor. In contrast
with this perception, BANSEFI does not believe it competes with popular savings and
credit institutions, as it does not provide credit services and many of its branches are
located in areas where they are not present.
48
Table 2.1: Overview of Popular Savings and Credit Institutions
(June 2001)
Legally
Number of Authorized to
Number of Clients Receive
Type of Institution Instituions (Thousands) Deposits? Regulated?
Credit unions 32 19 Yes Yes
Savings and Loans Associations 11 675 Yes Yes
Cooperatives 157 1,081 Yes No
Social Credit Institutions 210 190 No No
Populer Credit Institutions 208 344 No No
Source: BANSEFI
Total 360
Rating Categories
Category A: Institutions that meet the requirements to apply for authorization.
Category B: Institutions that require an improvement program to be authorized.
Category C: Institutions that are in need of overhaul and that require financial support to
strengthen their capital. This includes institutions that will require a merger, spin off, or
major reorganization process.
Category D: Institutions that are incapable of meeting the minimum requirements for
operating pursuant to the Savings and Popular Credit Act. These institutions shall be
liquidated or dissolved.
49
Appendix 3
1. Factoring
In many countries, small businesses find it difficult to finance their production cycle,
since they lack access to bank credit and most buyers usually take between 30 and 90
days to pay. After delivery, sellers issue an invoice, recorded as an account receivable by
the seller and an account payable by the buyer. Factoring is a type of financing in which
firms sell their accounts receivable at a discount (equal to interest plus service fees) to a
financial firm (called the factor) and receive immediate cash. Factoring is an asset sale,
not a loan. There is no debt repayment and no additional liabilities on the supplier’s
balance sheet. Most factoring is done “without recourse,” meaning that the factor
assumes the default risk, as it does not have recourse against the supplier if the buyer
defaults. Thus, the credit risk that the factor faces is that of the buyer.
80
Despite this advantage, creditor rights and contract enforcement are not irrelevant for factoring
transactions, as they affect the factor’s ability to collect payment from the buyer. Also, in emerging
economies there may be additional legal, tax, and regulatory issues that limit the ability to conduct
factoring transactions (see Klapper, 2005 for a discussion).
81
See Bakker, Klapper, and Udell (2004) for an overview of worldwide factoring markets, with a focus on
Eastern European countries. Klapper (2005) analyzes the determinants of factoring market development.
50
2. Description of NAFIN’s Reverse Factoring Program
NAFIN was responsible for the development, production, and marketing costs
related to the electronic platform. It operates the system and also handles all the legal
work, such as document transfers, preparing and signing documents, etc. NAFIN requires
all participating financial institutions to use its second-tier funding to provide credit
51
through the system. In fact, NAFIN does not charge a fee for the factoring services, but
rather covers its costs with the interest it charges on its loans. Banks are allowed to
charge a maximum interest rate of 7 percentage points above the rate at which they get
funding from NAFIN. This limit seems to be non-binding, as banks charge on average
five additional percentage points (which is about 8 percentage points below commercial
lending rates).
Several factors have contributed to the success of NAFIN’s program (see Naranjo,
2005). A key element was the consistency between strategy and resource deployment.
The creation of the Cadenas Productivas program required NAFIN to change from a
model where its focus was affecting the supply of credit through second-tier lending to a
model where it had to affect the demand for funds by promoting financial intermediation.
The promotion of the factoring program had to be made mostly at the firm level and
required different human and technical resources than acting as a second-tier bank,
namely a new and larger retail sales staff and promotional resources. Deploying the
required resources to establish the productive chains was one of the main drivers of the
success of NAFIN’s program. Second, the use of a non-lending contract like factoring
helped to overcome institutional deficiencies and reduce principal-agent problems,
fostering financial intermediation. Finally, the success of the program depended on the
availability of technology to implement the electronic platform which significantly
reduces transaction costs. The use of this electronic system was facilitated by the
existence of adequate legislation regulating electronic transactions.
3. Policy Discussion
52
program’s introduction, some financial firms were providing factoring services in
Mexico, but none had developed a system integrating a large number of firms and
financial intermediaries. A possible explanation for this lack of private sector initiative is
that financial innovation in many cases can be hampered by the fact that once a new
lending technology is introduced and proves to be successful, others can easily adopt it.
Therefore, there is little incentive for lenders to invest in new credit technologies. In this
situation, as Besley (1994) argues, there might be a role for the government to subsidize
innovation. Furthermore, the system created by NAFIN may present significant network
effects, since the value for firms of participating increases with the number of financial
institutions that take part, and vice versa. This type of network effects may give rise to a
“chicken and egg” problem: to attract buyers and suppliers, the program needs a large
base of registered financial intermediaries, but these will be willing to register only if
they expect many firms to participate. Also, note that financial intermediaries are most
likely to have the know-how to create a program of this type, but they may not be willing
to allow their competitors to participate, reducing the incentives for buyers and suppliers
to take part. Without a coordination mechanism, no innovation may take place in this
situation. As mentioned above, a key factor in the success of NAFIN’s program has been
the development of a large retail sales staff and promotional resources to reach firms and
establish the productive chains, which requires different human and technical resources
than financial intermediation.
There are several characteristics of NAFIN’s Cadenas Productivas program that may
hold important lessons for the design of pro-market interventions. First, the program is
designed to foster competition among financial institutions and increase information
availability. Once a transaction is posted online, all participating banks can bid to factor it
by posting an online quote. The system also increases transparency, as all banks can
access historical information on the performance of suppliers which helps them to
establish a credit history. NAFIN’s experience suggests that in order to foster competition
through this type of intervention, it is necessary to facilitate the participation of all
financial intermediaries and to avoid giving preferential access or other advantages to
larger banks or public institutions.
Second, as mentioned above, NAFIN requires all financial institutions that participate
in the Cadenas Productivas program to use its funds for lending through the system and
does not charge any fees for the use of the electronic platform, covering its costs with the
interest it charges on its loans. This reduces transparency and makes it difficult to
evaluate whether the program’s services are adequately priced. Also, there is no reason
for NAFIN to provide funds to the participating financial institutions. The requirement to
use loans from NAFIN seems to be the result of institutional incentives: since NAFIN is a
second-tier development bank, its performance is evaluated in terms of the volume of
loan disbursements. In fact, as Naranjo (2005) highlights, the creation of the factoring
program seems to have been driven, at least partially, by the loss of NAFIN’s traditional
cost advantage in lending to the financial sector and the resulting need to increase
demand for its loans through other means. As the financial system recovered from the
1994-1995 financial crisis and overall macroeconomic conditions improved, the spread
between bank rates and the Mexican sovereign rates decreased significantly and
NAFIN’s financing became relative expensive. It was no longer possible for NAFIN to
53
promote credit to SMEs using second-tier lending. Therefore, it tried to increase its loan
volume by fostering financial intermediation through the reverse factoring program.
NAFIN’s experience suggests that in order to foster pro-market interventions and avoid
distortions, it may be necessary to develop new ways of evaluating the performance of
public institutions that go beyond the volume of credit provided and rather focus on the
amount of financial intermediation promoted.
82
An alternative would be creating a separate institution to operate the program, but this may create
additional costs and generates some agency and incentive problems of its own. Also, this would imply
missing an opportunity for capacity building in public development institutions, which could be useful for
conducting other direct interventions.
54
Figure 3.1: The NAFIN Reverse Factoring System
Factoring
Day 1 Day 10 Day 50 Day 80
55
Appendix 4
1. Structured Finance
As described above, structured finance transactions have three main features: (i)
pooling of assets; (ii) transfer of the asset pool from the originator to a finite-lived
standalone entity (SPV); and (iii) tranching of securities that are backed by this asset
pool. Each of these features may create significant benefits for both issuers and investors.
First, the transfer of assets from the originator to the SPV provides collateral for the
transaction. This transfer also de-links the performance of the instrument for that of the
originator: payments to investors only depend on the cash flow generated by the asset
pool, but not on the performance of the originating firm. Another advantage is that the
SPV is a bankruptcy remote entity, in the sense that if the originator files for bankruptcy,
the assets in the pool do not come under court jurisdiction. All these benefits taken
together make it possible to issue securities with well-defined risk characteristics and
returns that may be more predictable than those of the originator. Pooling may improve
83
Accurately defining structured finance is quite difficult, as even among market participants there is no
agreement on exactly what it encompasses. See Davis (2005) for a survey of alternative definitions.
84
Some authors (see, for example, Alles, 2001, and BIS, 2005b) differentiate between securitization (which
only involves the pooling and transfer of assets to a third party and subsequent issuance of securities) and
structured financing (which also involves the creation of different classes of securities). In keeping with
common usage, we use the term structured finance to refer to both types of instruments.
85
See Meddin (2004) for an overview of structured finance in emerging markets and the role it may play in
fostering capital market development.
56
the liquidity of many types of assets by increasing the number of potential buyers (Duffie
and Garleanu, 2001). Finding a buyer for a specific asset (e.g., a specific loan) may be
difficult and generate high costs. By pooling homogenous assets, transaction costs can be
reduced and liquidity improved. Tranching can add value by creating securities that cater
to specific investor groups (Oldfield, 2000). Furthermore, tranching may also help to
mitigate adverse selection problems. If the originator has private information on the
quality of the assets, investors who do not know the true quality of those assets will
demand a premium (Akerlof, 1970). To reduce this problem, risk averse investors and
those with less information can purchase senior tranches (those that are more protected
from default and only face residual losses), which are less affected by adverse selection.
Also, the originator, the arranger, and the servicer may retain subordinated exposure (i.e.,
the first losses in the pool) to alleviate investor concerns. 86
In recent years, FIRA has tried to increase access to finance through the use of
structured finance transactions. The structured finance transactions arranged by FIRA can
be classified in two groups: asset backed securities (ABS) and collateralized loan
obligations (CLO). FIRA’s ABS transactions are typically designed to help transform
movable assets, such as commodity inventories, into viable collateral for financial
institutions. These transactions involve the securitization of loans backed by movable
collateral and the sale of participations in the trust fund that owns these loans to investors,
typically financial institutions. They also involve an operational agent, usually a large
commercial firm, that shares the risk, screens producers, monitors inventories, and
provides an outlet for the liquidation of the collateral in case of default. FIRA’s CLO
transactions, on the other hand, are usually designed to provide working capital financing
(there is no physical collateral in this case). In this type of transactions, a large
commercial firm acts as originator, granting working capital loans to its suppliers. These
credit rights are then transferred to an SPV and securities backed by this asset pool are
issued. To help align incentives and reduce adverse selection and moral hazard problems,
various participants in the supply chain provide liquid guarantees to cover eventual credit
losses. We now turn to the description of two specific structured finance transactions
arranged by FIRA, which illustrate how structured finance can solve problems of access
to finance and also help us to understand the role played by FIRA.
86
See De Marzo (2004), De Marzo and Duffie (1999), Mitchell (2005), and Riddough (1997) for analyses
of issues related to asymmetric information in structured finance transactions.
87
FIRA is composed of four trust funds which work in coordination with one another to provide financial
services and technical assistance to the rural sector. The services provided by FIRA include second-tier
lending, credit guarantees, technical assistance, and several subsidy programs.
57
3.1 Collateralized Loan Obligation (CLO) Transaction to Provide Financing to
Shrimp Producers
88
Ocean Garden is one of the main exporters of Mexican shrimp to the U.S. It handles approximately one
quarter of Mexico’s shrimp production and has annual sales of about 250 million U.S. dollars. The firm
was owned by the Mexican government and was recently privatized.
89
Ocean Garden has developed scoring methods to evaluate the credit quality of small producers and also
has historical data on their performance that allows it to construct credit histories.
90
Shrimp feed suppliers agreed to participate in this transaction and provide guarantees because before they
were the main source of financing to producers, which required them to invest more capital and face a
higher credit risk. Also, note that since the guarantee provided by shrimp feed suppliers are linked to
specific loans (it is not a general guarantee as the one provided by Ocean Garden), these firms have
incentives to screen and monitor shrimp producers.
91
The average credit loss in the shrimp sector, according to FIRA, has been around 4.2 percent.
58
Credit losses not covered by these liquid guarantees are divided between FIRA
(90 percent) and the banks that purchase the securities (10 percent), as shown in Table
4.1. The total net risk exposure of the banks in this scheme is 5.1 percent, while that of
FIRA is 45.9 percent, in both cases after first losses. FIRA charges a 1 percent premium
for the provision of this guarantee.
As described above, FIRA not only acts as an arranger for the transaction
(charging a fee of 0.75 percent for this service), but also as a financial guarantor,
covering second losses. Furthermore, since FIRA is a second-tier lending institution, it
requires all banks participating in this transaction to use its funding to purchase the
securities issued by the SPV.
FIRA has been successful in using similar CLO transactions to improve access to
credit for small producers in several sectors (including wheat, corn, and sorghum
production) by using large commercial firms as originators and the loans provided
through this type of transactions now account for 5 percent of its total portfolio.
3.2 Asset Backed Securities (ABS) Transaction to Provide Financing to Sugar Mills
FIRA designed an ABS transaction to provide financing to sugar mills with the
collaboration of Cargill Mexico. The general structure can be summarized as follows (see
Figure 4.2). Sugar mills store their sugar inventories in warehouses previously selected
and authorized by Cargill. Cargill then gives credit to the sugar mills by making a
repurchase agreement (repo) for the certificates of deposit issued by these warehouses. 93
92
Another possible source of financing was Ocean Garden. However, at the time this firm was facing
financial difficulties that significantly constrained its ability to finance its suppliers.
93
A repurchase agreement (or repo) is an agreement in which one party sells an asset to another at a certain
price with the commitment to buy back the asset at a later date for another price. A repo is legally a sale
59
These loans are for an amount equivalent to 80 percent of the value of the sugar
inventories stored in the warehouse and have a maturity of 45 days, renewable for
successive periods of 45 days up to a maximum of 270 days. The implicit interest rate on
these loans is equal to LIBOR (London Interbank Offered Rate) plus 4.75 percentage
points, without any differentiation across mills. Cargill then sells the certificates of
deposit to investors, mostly commercial banks, through a funded participation agreement.
FIRA acts as an arranger in this transaction and also provides a credit guarantee to
investors, which covers 96 percent of the total value of the loans. FIRA charges a 1
percent premium for the provision of this guarantee. To reduce its risk exposure, FIRA
has an agreement with Cargill, who guarantees that it will purchase any repossessed
inventories from FIRA in case of default. Under this agreement, Cargill covers 80 percent
of the total credit losses, reducing FIRA’s exposure to 16 percent. 94 Since FIRA is a
second-tier lending institution, it requires all banks to use its credit to purchase the
participations in the fund.
This structured finance transaction improves access to finance for sugar mills by
transforming their inventories into viable collateral for financial institutions. The use of
these inventories as collateral faces several difficulties. The first one, which applies to
most forms of movable collateral, especially in developing countries, is that this type of
collateral if difficult to secure. Sugar mills could pledge their inventories as collateral and
then easily sell those inventories without the bank knowing about it. In the case of
Mexico, this problem was compounded by the lack of a reliable warehousing market that
could guarantee the value and the quality of the inventories stored. Cargill’s know-how to
select and monitor commodity warehouses is crucial in this respect. The second problem
of using sugar inventories as collateral is the high volatility of sugar prices in Mexico.
There are no derivatives markets in Mexico for sugar, therefore financial institutions
and subsequent repurchase, effectively transferring the property of the asset to the creditor. However, from
an economic perspective, it is similar to a secured loan.
94
The fact that FIRA provides the guarantee to banks and then gets a guarantee from Cargill, instead of
Cargill directly providing the guarantee to the banks, is explained by regulatory arbitrage: since FIRA is a
public institution, capital requirements on loans guaranteed by FIRA are significantly lower than those on
loans guaranteed by a private party.
95
FIRA estimates that, given the historical volatility of sugar prices, the maximum expected loss during a
three day period, at a 95 percent confidence level, is 2.82 percent.
60
could not protect themselves from this risk.96 The solution to this problem adopted in this
scheme is creation of the system of margin calls administered by Cargill. Third, in many
cases financial institutions may be unwilling to grant credit even if collateral is available
due to the high costs of liquidating that collateral. In this ABS transaction, this problem
was solved by the participation of Cargill, who provides an outlet for the liquidation of
sugar inventories. As described above, in case of default FIRA can sell 80 percent of the
reposed sugar inventories to Cargill. Another important feature of this transaction is the
use of a repurchase agreement which effectively transfers legal ownership of the
inventories to Cargill, eliminating the need to go through the cumbersome collateral
repossession process in case of default.
FIRA has been successful in using similar ABS transactions to improve access to
credit for rural producers in several sectors (including corn, wheat, sorghum, shrimp, and
love cattle) and the loans provided through this type of transactions now account for 10
percent of its total portfolio.
61
unfamiliarity of market participants with its techniques and its seeming complexity may
further difficult the development of private solutions. Second, one could question to what
extent FIRA’s interventions actually foster financial market development as they seem to
leave very little room for private financial intermediation. In both of the transactions
described above, FIRA provides second-tier financing to banks and also gives them credit
guarantees that limit their risk exposure to about 5 percent. In more recent transactions
FIRA has reduced the level of credit enhancement, but it still remains quite high. As
discussed below, some of these features seem to be the result of institutional incentives,
as FIRA is evaluated on the basis of its loan disbursements and the volume of guarantees
it provides. It is still an open question whether these transactions would work without
such extensive FIRA involvement. Regarding the provision of second-tier lending,
interviews with banks suggest that they would be willing to participate in these
transactions without receiving FIRA’s funding. In fact, for some of the largest banks
FIRA’s financing is no longer cost-competitive, as they can get capital in financial
markets at similar or even lower rates. In the case of credit guarantees, the evidence is
less clear. The high level of guarantees provided by FIRA seems to be explained not by
banks’ risk aversion, but rather by regulatory arbitrage: since FIRA is a public institution,
capital requirements on loans guaranteed by FIRA are significantly lower than those on
regular loans. Banks would be willing to take more credit risk, but this would lead to
higher costs as lower FIRA guarantees would mean higher capital requirements. Finally,
in the case of the ABS transaction one could reasonably question whether it would be
better to improve the collateral market, by fostering the development of a reliable
warehousing system and improving collateral repossession laws and judicial procedures,
instead of designing a structured transaction to solve the problems of using inventories as
collateral. However, both measures are not mutually exclusive. The ABS transaction may
be a short-term solution while the warehousing market takes time to develop. Also, the
ABS scheme may contribute to the development of the warehouse market by providing
adequate incentives to warehouses and helping authorities to understand what regulations
or enforcement mechanisms are necessary for this market to develop.
There are several characteristics of FIRA’s structured finance transactions that may
hold important lessons for the design of pro-market interventions. First, as described
above, FIRA not only acts as an arranger in these transactions, but also provides credit
guarantees and second-tier lending. This bundling of several instruments makes it very
difficult to analyze the individual merits of each instrument and carries the risk of
distorting prices and incentives. It is not possibly to analyze whether the different
services provided by FIRA are adequately priced, as financial institutions cannot buy
them separately. The requirement to use FIRA’s second-tier lending and its credit
guarantees seems to be the result of institutional incentives: since FIRA is a second-tier
development financial institution, its performance is evaluated in terms of the volume of
loan disbursements and the amount of guarantees provided. FIRA’s experience suggests
that in order to foster pro-market interventions and avoid distortions, it may be necessary
to develop new ways of evaluating the performance of public institutions that go beyond
the volume of credit and guarantees provided and rather focus on the amount of financial
intermediation promoted.
62
Second, FIRA provides guarantees that cover most of the credit risk faced by
financial institutions. FIRA reduces its risk exposures by buying guarantees from private
parties and only taking second losses, decreasing the amount of risk shifting to the public
sector that actually takes place. As mentioned above, the high level of credit guarantees
provided by FIRA seems to be the result of regulatory arbitrage: since FIRA is a public
institution, capital requirements on loans guaranteed by FIRA are significantly lower than
those on regular loans. One of the main functions of FIRA’s guarantees therefore seems
to be reducing regulatory capital requirements. This highlights the fact that there might be
a conflict of interest in the public sector between the roles of regulator and promoter of
new activities. Finding the adequate equilibrium between both roles may not be easy.
Also, the fact that banks only face residual credit risk may reduce incentives to invest in
improving their risk assessment capabilities. Furthermore, the provision of guarantees by
FIRA may prevent the development of a private guarantors market. In developed
countries, guarantees in structured finance transactions are usually provided by private
financial guarantors (so called monolines). Since FIRA provides guarantees covering
most of the credit risk and its guarantees have a significant advantage in terms of capital
requirements, there may be little incentive for developing an active private market for
guarantees. 97
Finally, although structured finance transactions can help to overcome some of the
limitations of the contracting environment in developing countries, they require having an
appropriate legal framework that accommodates the numerous legal relationships that
must be established for these transactions to work. The lack of an adequate legal
framework for structured finance may be a significant constraint for the replication of
FIRA’s experience in other developing countries. 98
97
The lack of a private guarantors market also makes it difficult to assess whether FIRA’s guarantees are
accurately priced.
98
See Alles (2001) for a general discussion of the elements of the legal framework that may prevent the
development of structured finance in developing countries.
63
Figure 4.1: Description of CLO Transaction to Provide Financing to Shrimp
Producers
Transfer of
credit rights +
OCEAN 3 $100 5
BANKS
GARDEN
$100
4
6
TRUST Participation
FUND certificates
Working
Supply
capital loan
agreement Second loss
$100
guarantee 7
2 1
Payments
SHRIMP
FIRA
PRODUCERS
SHRIMP FEED
Feed SUPPLIERS
Total Risk
Exposure 24 25 45.9 5.1
64
Figure 4.2: Description of ABS Transaction to Provide Financing to Sugar Mills
5
SUGAR 4 Portfolio sale
(Funded BANKS
MILL $80 participation
agreement)
3 6
CD Repo $80 7
CARGILL
1 2 Guarantee
Inventories Certificate of
$100 deposit (CD)
$100
8
Screening Guarantee
and FIRA
monitoring
WAREHOUSES
Margin calls
65
References
Adrianova, S., D. Panicos, and A. Shortland, 2002. State Banks, Institutions and
Financial Development, mimeo, University of Leicester.
Akerlof, G. A., 1970. The Market for “Lemons:” Quality Uncertainty and the Market
Mechanism, Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, 488-500.
Alles, L., 2001. Asset Securitization and Structured Finance: Future Prospects and
Challenges for Emerging Market Countries, IMF Working Paper WP/01/147.
Agarwala, R., 1983. Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries, World Bank
Staff Working Paper 575.
Aliou, D. and M. Zeller, 2001. Access to Credit and Its Impact on Welfare in Malawi,
International Food Policy Research Institute Research Report 116.
Anjali K., A. Parsons, A. Nair, and E. Urdapilleta, 2006. Expanding Bank Outreach
through Retail Partnerships: Correspondent Banking in Brazil, mimeo, World Bank.
Armendariz de Aghion, B., 1999b. On the Design of a Credit Agreement with Peer
Monitoring, Journal of Development Economics 60, 79-104.
Atieno, R., 1999. Access to Credit by Women in Agribusiness Trade: Empirical Evidence
on the Use of Formal and Informal Credit Sources in Rural Kenya, Institute for
Development Studies, University of Kenya.
Bakker, M. R., L. Klapper, and G. F. Udell, 2004. Financing Small and Medium-size
Enterprises with Factoring: Global Growth and Its Potential in Eastern Europe, World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3342.
66
Barro, R. J. 1991. Economic Growth in a Cross-section of Countries, Quarterly Journal
of Economics 106, 407–443.
Barth, J., G. Caprio, and R. Levine, 2001. Banking Systems around the Globe: Do
Regulation and Ownership Affect Performance and Stability? in F. Mishkin (ed.),
Prudential Regulation and Supervision: Why is it Important and What are the Issues?
National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA.
Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and M. S. Martinez Peria, 2005. Reaching Out: Access to
and Use of Banking Services across Countries, mimeo, World Bank.
Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and R. Levine, 2003. Law and Finance: Why Does Legal
Origin Matter? Journal of Comparative Economics 31, 653-675.
Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and R. Levine, 2004. Finance, Inequality and Poverty:
Cross-Country Evidence, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3338.
Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and V. Maksimovic, 2002. Financial and Legal Constraints
to Firm Growth: Does Size Matter? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2784.
Beegle, K., R. Dehejia, and R. Gatti, 2003. Child Labor, Income Shocks and Access to
Credit, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3075.
Bennett, F., H. Billington, and A. Doran, 2005. Do Credit Guarantees Lead to Improved
Access to Financial Services? Recent Evidence from Chile, Egypt, India, and Poland,
Department for International Development, London, Financial Sector Team, Policy
Division Working Paper.
Besley, T., 1994. How do Market Failures Justify Interventions in Rural Credit Markets?
World Bank Research Observer 9, 27-47.
Besley, T. and S. Coate, 1995. Group Lending, Repayment Incentives, and Social
Collateral, Journal of Development Economics 46, 235-264.
Bhattacharya, U. and H. Daouk, 2002. The World Price of Insider Trading, Journal of
Finance 57, 75-108.
67
BIS 2005a. BIS 75th Annual Report.
BIS, 2005b. The Role of Ratings in Structured Finance: Issues and Implications,
Committee on the Global Financial System Publication No. 23.
Boehmer, E., R. C. Nash, and J. M. Netter, 2005. Bank Privatization in Developing and
Developed Countries: Cross-sectional Evidence on the Impact of Economic and Political
Factors, Journal of Banking and Finance 29, 1981-2013.
Brizzi, A., 2001. Rural Development and Agriculture, in M. Guigale, O. Lafourcarde and
V. H. Nguyen (eds.), Mexico: A Comprehensive Development Agenda for the New Era,
World Bank: Washington, DC.
Buchanan, J. M., 1962. Politics, Policy, and the Pigovian Margins, Economica 29, 17-28.
Burgess, R. and R. Pande, 2005. Can Rural Banks Reduce Poverty? Evidence from the
Indian Social Banking Experiment, American Economic Review 95, 780-795.
Cameron, E., 1953. The Credit Mobilier and the Economic Development of Europe,
Journal of Political Economy 61, 461-488.
Capaul, M., 2003. Corporate Governance in Latin America, mimeo, World Bank.
Caprio, G. and P. Honohan, 2001. Finance for Growth: Policy Choices in a Volatile
World, World Bank, Oxford University Press: New York.
Caskey, J. P., C. Ruíz Durán, and T. M. Solo, 2004. The Unbanked in Mexico and the
United States, presented at the International Conference on Access to Finance, Brussels,
28-29 October.
CGAP, 2003a. Microfinance Means Financial Services for the Poor, Donor Brief No. 11.
CGAP, 2003b. Scoring: The Next Breakthrough in Microcredit? Occasional Paper No. 7.
CGAP, 2004. Financial Institutions with a “Double Bottom Line:” Implications for the
Future of Microfinance, Occasional Paper No. 8.
68
CGPA, 2005a. Mexico Country-Level Savings Assessment.
CGAP, 2006. Using Technology to Build Inclusive Financial Systems, Focus Note No.
32.
Cho, Y. J., 1997. Credit Policies and the Industrialization of Korea, in K. B. Staking,
(ed.), Policy-Based Finance and Market Alternatives: East Asian Lessons for Latin
America and the Caribbean, Inter-American Development Bank: Washington, DC.
Claessens, S., 2005. Universal Access to Financial Services: A Review of the Issues and
Public Policy Objectives, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3589.
Clarke, G., R. Cull, and M. Shirley, 2004. Empirical Studies of Bank Privatization: Some
Lessons, presented at the World Bank, International Monetary Fund, and Brookings
Institution Conference The Role of State-Owned Financial Institutions: Policy and
Practice, Washington, DC.
Coase, R. H., 1960. The Problem of Social Cost, Journal of Law and Economics 3, 1-44.
Coutinho, L., 2006. Networking: The Case of Bansefi, mimeo, World Bank.
Daley-Harris, S. 2003. State of the Microcredit Summit Campaign Report 2003, mimeo.
Davis, H. A., 2005. The Definition of Structured Finance: Results form a Survey, Journal
of Structured Finance 11, 5-10.
De la Torre, A., J. C. Gozzi, and S. Schmukler, 2005. Stock Market Development under
Globalization: Whither the Gains from Reforms? mimeo, World Bank.
De Marzo, P. M., 2004. The Pooling and Tranching of Securities: A Model of Informed
Intermediation, Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming.
69
Djankov, S., C. McLiesh, and A. Shleifer, 2006. Private Credit in 129 Countries, Journal
of Financial Economics, forthcoming.
Duffie, D. and N. Garleanu, 2001. Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations,
Financial Analysts' Journal Jan.-Feb., 41-59.
Durlauf, S., P. A. Johnson, and J. Temple, 2005. Growth Econometrics, in P. Aghion and
S. Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier: Amsterdam.
Easterly, W., 1993. How Much do Distortions Affect Growth? Journal of Monetary
Economics 32, 187-212.
Easterly, W., 2001. The Lost Decade: Developing Countries’ Stagnation in Spite of
Policy Reform 1980–1990, Journal of Economic Growth 6, 135–57.
Easterly, W., 2005. National Policies and Economic Growth: A Reappraisal, in P. Aghion
and S. Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier: Amsterdam.
Easterly, W. and R. Levine, 2003. Tropics, Germs, and Crops: How Endowments
Influence Economic Development, Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 3-40.
Fernandez-Arias, E. and P. Montiel, 2001. Reform and Growth in Latin America: All
Pain and No Gain? IMF Staff Papers 48, 522-546.
Fleisig, H. W., 1996. Secured Transactions: The Power of Collateral, Finance &
Development 33, 44-46.
Francisco, M. and A. Kumar, 2004. Enterprise Size, Financing Patterns and Credit
Constraints in Brazil: Analysis of Data from the Investment Climate Assessment Survey,
World Bank Working Paper 49.
Galindo, A. and A. Micco, 2004. Do State Owned Banks Promote Growth? Cross-
country Evidence for Manufacturing Industries, Economics Letters 84, 371-376.
Galindo, A., A. Micco, and G. Ordoñez, 2002. Financial Liberalization and Growth,
presented in Financial Globalization: A Blessing or a Curse? World Bank Conference,
May.
Gelb, A. H., 1989. Financial Policies, Growth, and Efficiency, World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper Series 202.
70
Gershenkron, A., 1952. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective, in F. Hoselitz
(ed.) The Progress of Underdeveloped Areas, University of Chicago Press: Cambridge,
MA.
Ghatak, M. and T. Guinnane, 1999. The Economics of Lending with Joint Liability:
Theory and Practice, Journal of Development Economics 60, 195-228.
Goldsmith, R., 1969. Financial Structure and Development, Yale University Press: New
Haven.
Graham Bannock and Partners Ltd., 1997. Credit Guarantee Schemes For Small Business
Lending – A Global Perspective, Volume I – Main Report.
Green, A., 2003. Credit Guarantee Schemes for Small Enterprises: An Effective
Instrument to Promote Private Sector-Led Growth? United Nations Industrial
Development Organization, SME Technical Working Paper No. 10.
Greif , A., 1993. Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The
Maghribi Traders' Coalition, American Economic Review 83, 525-48.
Hall, R. E. and C. Jones, 1999. Why do Some Countries Produce so Much More Output
per Worker than Others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 83-116.
Haber, S. and N. Maurer, 2004. Related Lending and Economic Performance: Evidence
from Mexico, mimeo, Standford University.
Hanson, J. A., 2003. Banking in Developing Countries in the 1990s, World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper 3168.
Hardy, D., P. Holden, and V. Prokopenko, 2002. Microfinance Institutions and Public
Policy, IMF Working Paper 02/159.
Herrero Calvo, A. and P. Pombo Gonzalez, 2001. Los Sistemas de Garantia para la Micro
y la PYME en una Economia Globalizada.
Hirschman, A. O., 1958. The Strategy of Economic Development, Yale University Press:
New Haven.
71
Hoff, K. and J. E. Stiglitz, 2001. Modern Economic Theory and Development, in G.
Meier and J. E. Stiglitz (eds.), The Future of Development Economics in Perspective,
Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Honohan, P., 2004. Financial Sector Policy and the Poor: Selected Findings and Issues,
World Bank Working Paper No. 43.
Inter-American Development Bank, 2004. Unlocking Credit: The Quest for Deep and
Stable Bank Lending, Report on Economic and Social Progress in Latin America.
Jansson, T., 2002. Financing Microfinance: Exploring the Funding Side of Microfinance
Institutions, Inter-American Development Bank Sustainable Development Department
Technical Paper 118.
Japelli, T. and M. Pagano, 2002. Information Sharing, Lending and Defaults: Cross-
country Evidence, Journal of Banking and Finance 26, 2017-2045.
Kaminsky, G. and S. Schmukler, 2003. Short-run Pain, Long-run Gain: The Effects of
Financial Liberalization, NBER Working Paper No. 9787.
Karolyi, G. A., 2004. The Role of American Depositary Receipts in the Development of
Emerging Equity Markets, Review of Economics and Statistics 86, 670-690.
Klapper, L., 2005. The Role of Factoring for Financing Small and Medium Enterprises,
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3593.
Krebsbach, K., 2003. Doing Good By Doing Well, U.S. Banker 47-48, August.
Krueger, A., 1974. The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society, American
Economic Review 64, 291-303.
72
Krueger, A., 2004. Meant Well, Tried Little, Failed Much: Policy Reforms in Emerging
Market Economies, remarks at the Roundtable Lecture at the Economic Honors Society,
New York University, New York, March 23.
Kumar, A., 2005. Access to Financial Services in Brazil: A Study, World Bank:
Washington, DC.
Levine, R., 1998. The Legal Environment, Banks, and Long-run Economic Growth,
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30, 596-620.
Levine, R., 2005. Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence, in P. Aghion and S.
Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier: Amsterdam.
Levine, R. and S. Schmukler, 2006a. Migration, Spillovers, and Trade Diversion: The
Impact of Internationalization on Domestic Stock Market Activity, Journal of Banking
and Finance, forthcoming.
Levitsky, J., 1997a. SME Guarantee Schemes: A Summary, The Financier - Analyses of
Capital and Money Market Transaction 4, 5-11.
Levitsky, J., 1997b. Best Practice in Credit Guarantee Schemes, The Financier - Analyses
of Capital and Money Market Transaction 4, 86-94.
Littlefield E. and R. Rosenberg, 2004. Microfinance and the Poor: Breaking Down the
Walls between Microfinance and Formal Finance, Finance & Development 41, 38-40.
Loayza N., P. Fajnzylber, and C. Calderón, 2005. Economic Growth in Latin America
and the Caribbean. Stylized Facts, Explanations, and Forecasts, mimeo, World Bank.
73
Lombardo, D. and M. Pagano, 2002. Law and Equity Markets: A Simple Model, in J.
McCahery, P. Moerland, T. Raaijmakers, and L. Renneboog (eds.), Corporate
Governance Regimes: Convergence and Diversity, Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Love, I. and N. Mylenko, 2003. Credit Reporting and Financing Constraints, World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper 3142.
McKinnon, R. I., 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development, The Brookings
Institution: Washington, DC.
Meddin, L., 2004. Structured Finance in the Emerging Markets, in Global Securitisation
Review 2004 / 2005, Euromoney.
Megginson, W. L., 2005. The Economics of Bank Privatization, Journal of Banking and
Finance 29, 1931-1980.
Micco, A. and U. Panizza, 2004. Bank Ownership and Lending Behavior, mimeo, Inter-
American Development Bank.
Micco A. and U. Panizza, 2005. Public Banks in Latin America, background paper
prepared for the conference on Public Banks in Latin America: Myth and Reality Inter-
American Development Bank February 25, 2005.
Miller, 2003. Credit Reporting Systems and the International Economy, MIT Press:
Cambridge MA.
Mitchell, J., 2004. Financial Intermediation Theory and the Sources of Value in
Structured Finance Markets, National Bank of Belgium Working Paper.
Moel, A., 2001. The Role of American Depositary Receipts in the Development of
Emerging Markets, Economia 2, 209-273.
Morduch, J., 1999. The Microfinance Promise, Journal of Economic Literature 37, 1569-
1614.
Murphy, K., Shleifer A. and Vishny R., 1989. Industrialization and the Big Push, Journal
of Political Economy 97, 1003-1026.
Naranjo M., 2005. NAFIN’S Reverse Factoring Program, mimeo, World Bank.
74
Oldfield, G., 2000. Making Markets for Structured Mortgage Derivatives, Journal of
Financial Economics 57, 445-471.
Pagano, M. and P. Volpin, 2001. The Political Economy of Finance, Oxford Review of
Economic Policy 17, 502-519.
Peachey, S. and A. Roe, 2004. Access to Finance, A Study for the World Savings Banks
Institute, Oxford Policy Management, October.
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, 2001. Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth,
Oxford Review of Economic Policy 17, 467-482.
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, 2003a. Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists, Crown
Business Division of Random House: New York.
Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, 2003b. The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial
Development in the 20th Century, Journal of Financial Economics 69, 5-50.
Riding, A. L., 1997. Review of Costs and Benefits of Loan Guarantee Programs by R. C
Vogel and D. W. Adams, The Financier - Analyses of Capital and Money Market
Transactions 4, 107-111.
Rodrik, A., 2002, After Neo-Liberalism, What? The Economic Times, November 19th.
Rodrik, D., 2005. Why We Learn Nothing from Regressing Economic Growth on
Policies, mimeo, Harvard University.
Rodrik, D., A. Subramanian, and F. Trebbi, 2004. Institutions Rule: The Primacy of
Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development, Journal of
Economic Growth, forthcoming.
Roe, M., 1994. Strong Managers and Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American
Corporate Finance, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Rostow, W. W., 1962. The Process of Economic Growth, 2nd ed., Norton: New York.
75
Roubini, N. and X. Sala-i-Martin, 1992. Financial Repression and Economic Growth,
Journal of Development Economics 39, 5-30.
Srinivasan, T. N., 1985, Neoclassical Political Economy, the State and Economic
Development, Asian Development Review 3, 38-58.
Srivastava, P. and P. Basu, 2004. Scaling-up Access to Finance for India’s Rural Poor,
World Bank Working Paper 30829.
Stigler, G. J., 1971. The Theory of Economic Regulation, Bell Journal of Economics 2, 3-
21.
Stiglitz, J. E., 1994. The Role of the State in Financial Markets, in Proceedings of the
World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1993, world Bank:
Washington, DC.
Taber L., 2005. Integrating the Poor into the Mainstream Financial System: The
BANSEFI and SAGARPA Programs in Mexico, in Scaling up Poverty Reduction. Case
Studies in Microfinance, CGAP/World Bank: Washington DC.
Tejerina, L., 2004. Enterpreneurship and Financial Constraints: The Case of Nicaragua,
presented at the Inter-American Development Bank Conference on Financial Products
76
and Poverty Reduction in Latin America and the Caribbean, Washington D.C.,
September 30 to October 1.
Temple, J., 1999. The New Growth Evidence, Journal of Economic Literature 37, 112-
156.
Tullock G., 1967. The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies and Theft, Western
Economic Journal 5, 224-232.
Vittas, D., 1997. Policy-Based Finance: Application of East Asian Lesson to the
America, in K. B. Staking (ed.), Policy-Based Finance and Market Alternatives: East
Asian Lessons for Latin America and the Caribbean, Inter-American Development Bank:
Washington, DC.
Vittas D. and Y. J. Cho, 1996. Credit Policies: Lessons from Japan and Korea, World
Bank Research Observer 11, 277-298.
Vogel, R. C. and D. W. Adams, 1997. Costs and Benefits of Loan Guarantee Programs,
The Financier - Analyses of Capital and Money Market Transactions 4, 22-29.
Williamson, J., 1990. What Washington Means by Policy Reform, in J. Williamson (ed.),
Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? Washington, D.C.: Institute for
International Economics.
Williamson, J. and M. Mahar. 1998. A Review of Financial Liberalization, South Asia
Discussion Paper, Report No. IDP-171, World Bank.
World Bank, 1983. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington, DC.
World Bank, 1989. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington, DC.
World Bank, 1990a. Colombia Industrial Competition and Performance, Report No.
7921-Co.
World Bank, 1990b. Colombia Industrial Restructuring and Development project, Staff
Appraisal Report, October.
77
World Bank, 1993. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy, World
Bank: Washington, DC.
World Bank, 1997. The Long March: A Reform Agenda for Latin America and the
Caribbean in the Next Decade, World Bank: Washington, DC.
World Bank, 1999. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington, DC.
World Bank, 2001. Mexico Rural Finance: Savings Mobilization Potential and Deposit
Instruments in Marginal Areas, Report No. 21286-ME.
World Bank, 2002. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington, DC.
World Bank, 2003a, Colombia Rural Finance: Access Issues, Challenges and
Opportunities, Report 27269-CO, November.
World Bank, 2003b, Broadening Access to Financial Services among the Urban Poor:
Mexico City’s Unbanked, Draft Final Report, July.
World Bank, 2004a. Whither Latin American Capital Markets? Latin America and
Caribbean World Bank Regional Study, World Bank: Washington, DC.
World Bank, 2004b. Mexico - Second Savings and Rural Finance (BANSEFI) Project:
Project Appraisal Document, Report 28929-ME.
World Bank, 2005a. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington DC.
World Bank, 2005b. Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform,
World Bank: Washington DC.
Zagha, R., 2004. Results from the Exercise on the Lessons of the 1990s, in Searching for
Alternatives – Beyond the Washington Consensus, International Policy Dialogue: Berlin.
Zingales, L., 2004. The Costs and Benefits of Financial Market Regulation, European
Corporate Governance Institute Law Working Paper 21/2004.
78