[go: up one dir, main page]

0% found this document useful (0 votes)
2 views82 pages

6243197

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1/ 82

CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.

uk
Provided by Research Papers in Economics WPS4326
Public Disclosure Authorized

P olicy R esearch W orking P aper 4326


Public Disclosure Authorized

Innovative Experiences in Access to Finance:


Market Friendly Roles for the Visible Hand?

Augusto de la Torre
Juan Carlos Gozzi
Public Disclosure Authorized

Sergio L. Schmukler
Public Disclosure Authorized

The World Bank


Latin America and the Caribbean Region
Financial and Private Sector Development Unit
and
Development Research Group
Macroeconomic and Growth Team
August 2007
Policy Research Working Paper 4326

Abstract
Interest in access to finance has increased significantly a limited role for the public sector in financial markets,
in recent years, as growing evidence suggests that lack but contends that there might be room for well-designed,
of access to credit prevents lower-income households restricted interventions in collaboration with the private
and small firms from financing high return investment sector to foster financial development and broaden
projects, having an adverse effect on growth and poverty access. The authors illustrate this view with several recent
alleviation. This study describes some recent innovative experiences in Latin America and then discuss some open
experiences to broaden access to credit. These experiences policy questions about the role of the public and private
are consistent with an emerging new view that recognizes sectors in driving these financial innovations.

This paper—a product of the Office of the Chief Economist, Latin America and the Caribbean Region, the Development
Research Group, and the Financial and Private Sector Development Vice Presidency—is part of a larger, Bank-wide effort
to enhance the understanding of analytical and policy issues in access to financial services. Policy Research Working Papers
are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at adelatorre@worldbank.org,
juan_carlos_gozi_valdez@brown.edu, and sschmukler@worldbank.org.

The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development
issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the
names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those
of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and
its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.

Produced by the Research Support Team


Innovative Experiences in Access to Finance:
Market Friendly Roles for the Visible Hand?

Augusto de la Torre

Juan Carlos Gozzi

and

Sergio L. Schmukler*

JEL classification codes: G18, H11, O16

Keywords: access to finance; financial development; development banks; public banks;


Latin America

*
Authors are with the World Bank. Gozzi is also with Brown University. We would like to thank all the
people that helped us with our interviews and, in particular, Remigio Alvarez Prieto, Carlos Budar, Javier
Gavito, Timoteo Harris, Miguel Hernández, Francisco Meré, and Jaime Pizarro. We are grateful to Aquiles
Almansi, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, Patrick Honohan, and Marilou Uy (the study’s peer reviewers), who
provided detailed and very useful comments. We also received useful comments and suggestions from Stijn
Claessens, Carlos Cuevas, Giovanni Majnoni, Martin Naranjo, Guillermo Perry, Luis Serven, and Jacob
Yaron. We would also like to thank Leonor Coutinho for helping us in the initial stages of this project and
José Azar and Francisco Ceballos for excellent research assistance. The findings, interpretations and
conclusions expressed in this study are entirely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the
views of the World Bank. E-mail addresses: adelatorre@worldbank.org,
juan_carlos_gozi_valdez@brown.edu, and sschmukler@worldbank.org.
Innovative Experiences in Access to Finance:
Market Friendly Roles for the Visible Hand?

Contents

1. Introduction 1

2. Conceptual Issues in Access to Finance 6


Problem of Access vs. Lack of Access 6
Institutions and Access to Finance 9

3. The Role of the Public Sector in Broadening Access 11


The Interventionist View 13
The Laissez-Faire View 18
The Pro-Market Activism View 24

4. Recent Pro-Market Interventions in Latin America 27


Public Provision of Market Infrastructure 27
Structured Finance 30
Credit Guarantee Systems 32
Transaction Cost Subsidies 35
Public Lending 36

5. Final Remarks 37

Appendices
An Overview of Microfinance 41
BANSEFI’s Experience 43
NAFIN’s Reverse Factoring Program 50
FIRA’s Structured Finance Transactions 56

References 66
1. Introduction

Academic and policy interest in financial development has risen in step with the
accumulation of evidence supporting the view that a sound financial system is not just
correlated with a healthy economy, but actually causes economic growth. 1 By and large,
the empirical work behind this evidence has used financial sector depth, typically
expressed as the ratio of financial assets to GDP, as the “independent variable,” thereby
implicitly assuming that depth is a good proxy for financial development. 2 This may be a
justifiable assumption when it comes to empirical work, given the arguably strong
correlation between financial depth and financial development, and considering data
constraints. But it is clear that the intricate web of institutional and market interactions
that are at the heart of financial development can hardly be reduced to a single dimension.
It is financial development in all of its dimensions—and not just financial depth—which
lubricates and boosts the process of growth. It is not surprising, therefore, that the
discussion of finance and growth has naturally widened to consider other dimensions of
finance that appear crucial to economic and social development. These include stability,
diversity, and—the focus of this study—access to finance. Of these dimensions, access to
finance is, so to speak, the “new kid in the block.” 3

Although a relatively new field, the study of financial development from the
perspective of the breadth of access to financial services has mushroomed. 4 There are a
number of factors that have contributed to this. First, there is some empirical evidence,
albeit still limited, that the expansion of access may reduce poverty. Burgess and Pande
(2005), for instance, find that a 1 percent increase in the number of rural banked locations
in India reduces rural poverty by 0.34 percent (see also Department for International
Development, 2004, and references therein). 5

1
The literature on the finance-growth nexus is vast. Reviews of such literature can be found in a variety of
forms that can suit all sorts of different tastes. A comprehensive review is found in Levine (2005). Rajan
and Zingales (2001; 2003a), by contrast, provide shorter reviews in less technical language. Caprio and
Honohan (2001) offer an excellent rendition that emphasizes the World Bank contributions to the empirical
literature.
2
A notable exception is Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2005), who collect several indicators of
banking sector outreach and find that outreach is associated with lower firm-level financial constraints,
even after controlling for financial sector depth.
3
The study of financial stability is arguably a more mature endeavor that includes such well-researched
topics as regulation and supervision, early warning systems, crisis prevention, crisis management and
resolution, and monetary and financial sector linkages. The study of financial system diversity is arguably
also a relatively more mature subject, inasmuch as financial sub-sectors (e.g., banking, capital markets,
insurance, and pensions) are the object of specialized disciplines.
4
A large number of recent studies have focused on quantifying the lack of access of households and firms
and trying to determine its causes. In the case of developing countries, these studies include: Kumar (2005)
for Brazil; World Bank (2003a) for Colombia; Srivastava and Basu (2004) for India; Atieno (1999) for
Kenya; Aliou and Zeller (2001) for Malawi; Caskey et al. (2004) and World Bank (2003b) for Mexico;
Beegle, Dehejia, and Gatti (2003) and Satta (2002) for Tanzania. Halac and Schmukler (2004) present data
for various Latin American countries. In addition, Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Maksimovic (2002),
Francisco and Kumar (2004), IADB (2002), Tejerina (2004), and Schulhofer-Wohl (2004) analyze
measures of access to finance for small firms.
5
A broader group of studies has shown a link between financial market depth and poverty reduction, but
does not identify whether this is caused by a simultaneous expansion in the breadth of access, or simply by

1
Second, the interest in access also comes from the fact that arguments about the
channels through which financial development may lead to growth often include access-
related stories. Most prominent in this regard is the Schumpeterian argument,
compellingly restated by Rajan and Zingales (2003a), that financial development causes
growth because it fuels the process of “creative destruction,” and it does so by moving
resources to efficient uses and, in particular, to the hands of efficient newcomers. What is
relevant in this perspective is the access dimension of financial development—it is
through broader access to finance that talented newcomers are empowered and freed from
the disadvantages that would otherwise arise from their lack of inherited wealth and
absence of connections to the network of well-off incumbents. In other words, financial
development can stimulate the process of creative destruction—and thus the growth
process—by expanding economic opportunities and by leveling the playing field, that is,
by giving the outsiders and the poor a chance. It is on the strength of this type of
reasoning that Rajan and Zingales (2003a) confidently say that “healthy and competitive
financial markets are an extraordinarily effective tool in spreading opportunity and
fighting poverty.”

A third reason for the increasing interest on the study of access is the sheer lack of
access to financial services in emerging economies, particularly when compared to the
extent of access in developed countries. Recent World Bank country-specific reports
suggest that more than 70 percent of the Latin American population lacks access to such
basic financial services as a checking or savings account. 6 In industrial countries this
statistic is typically below 20 percent. 7 By implication, the Latin Americans that have
access to the more sophisticated financial services—long-term credit, mutual funds,
insurance products, etc.—are truly few and far between. 8 The differences in access across
countries are also illustrated by studies showing that firms in developing countries,
especially SMEs (small and medium enterprises), use formal sources of finance much
less than similar firms in industrial countries (see, for example, Beck, Demirguc-Kunt,
and Maksimovic, 2002).

In light of the increasing awareness of the importance of access, not only among
policymakers but also academics, this study aims at filling in one of the many gaps in this
still emerging literature, by addressing specific issues related to access to finance. In
particular, this study has two objectives. The first one is to discuss some conceptual
issues in access to finance. The second one is to describe some recent experiences to
broaden access to credit. These experiences seem to be driven by an emerging new view
on the role of the public sector in financial development, which tends to favor restricted

an increase in income levels that favors lower income sectors. Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2004),
for example, find that in countries with higher financial sector depth the income of the poorest 20 percent
of the population grows faster than average GDP per capita and income inequality falls at a higher rate.
6
See relevant references in footnote 3.
7
Household surveys that compile data on access to financial services across countries are surveyed in
Peachey and Roe (2004) and Claessens (2005). The percentage of households without a checking account
is estimated to be about 30 percent in Italy, 12 percent in the U.K., nine percent in the U.S., eight percent in
Spain, and less than two percent in Scandinavian countries (Peachey and Roe, 2004).
8
One exception among credit services, however, appears to be consumer credit (including the micro
variety), the access to which is broadening at a fast pace.

2
government interventions in collaboration with the private sector in non-traditional ways.
We illustrate this new view with several recent initiatives in Latin America and discuss
some open policy questions about the role of the public and private sectors in light of
these experiences.

Among the wide set of products covered under the “financial services” label—
including savings, payments, insurance, and credit products—we focus our analysis on
credit services. We believe that, regarding issues of access, these services are the most
interesting and challenging from an analytical point of view and from policymakers’
perspective, as the provision of credit entails many complexities that lead providers to
exclude very diverse groups of borrowers.

We start by noting that the observation that a certain share of the population does
not use financial services, which we identify as lack of access, does not necessarily mean
that there is a problem of access. This distinction has often been ignored or understated in
the recent literature, even though the failure to recognize it can lead to the wrong policy
advice. Lack of access is simply the fact that financial services are not being used. To
conclude that this observation entails a problem is not easy, as there is no clear definition
of what such a problem is. To conduct our study, we adopt a working definition of a
problem of access to credit. In our definition, a problem of access to credit exists when a
project that would be internally financed if resources were available, does not get external
financing. This happens because there is a wedge between the expected internal rate of
return of the project and the rate of return that external investors require to finance it.
This wedge is mainly introduced by two well-known constraints that hamper the ability
to write and enforce financial contracts, namely, principal-agent problems and
transaction costs.

The institutional framework of the economy affects the ability of agents to deal
with these problems and therefore has a significant impact on financial development and
access to finance. In environments with weak institutions, agency problems tend to be
mitigated through arrangements that rely on personalized relationships, group
monitoring, and fixed collateral. These instruments work, by definition, within a
circumscribed network of participants, excluding creditworthy borrowers that lack
collateral and/or connections. In contrast, a strong institutional environment enables the
expansion of arm’s-length financing by using impersonal contracts that rely on rules of
general application, effectively freeing borrowers from the tyranny of collateral and
personalized connections.

Given the major potential benefits of access-enhancing financial development, a


relevant question is whether government intervention to foster financial development and
broaden access is necessary and, if so, what form should this intervention take. While
most economists would agree that the government can play a significant role in fostering
financial development, there is less consensus regarding the specific nature of its
intervention. Opinions on this issue tend to be polarized in two highly contrasting but
well-established views: the interventionist and the laissez-faire views. The interventionist
view argues that an active government involvement in mobilizing and allocating financial
resources, including through government ownership of financial institutions, is needed to

3
broaden access to credit, as private markets fail to expand access. In contrast, the laissez-
faire view contends that governments can do more harm than good by intervening
directly in the financial system and argues that government efforts should instead focus
on improving the enabling environment.

A third view is emerging in the middle ground, favoring direct government


interventions in non-traditional ways. This view, which we denominate pro-market
activism, seems to be behind some recent experiences of public sector intervention. In a
sense, this third view is closer to the laissez-faire view, to the extent that it recognizes a
limited role for the government in financial markets and acknowledges that institutional
efficiency is the economy’s first best. However, it contends that there might be room for
well-designed, restricted government interventions to address specific market failures and
help smooth the transition towards a developed financial system or even speed it up.

The main message of pro-market activism is that there is a role for the visible
hand of the government in promoting access in the short run, while the fruits of ongoing
institutional reform are still unripe. However, the government must be highly selective in
its interventions, always trying to ensure that they promote the development of deep
domestic financial markets, rather than replace them. Careful analyses to identify market
failures and their causes should precede any intervention. And even if a market failure is
identified, government intervention can only be justified if it can solve the failure in a
cost-effective manner. There must also be mechanisms in place to prevent political
capture that may undermine the temporary nature of the interventions or their
compatibility with the long-run objective of institutional reform and financial market
development.

We illustrate the pro-market activism view with a number of recent experiences in


Latin America. This exercise shows that there are now several institutions in the region
that seem to be moving in the direction of pro-market interventions. We do not attempt to
undertake a comprehensive assessment of these interventions or to claim that they have
been successful. Rather, we use them to illustrate how pro-market activism has worked in
practice. Although all the experiences we described were driven by the public sector, in
many cases they could have been implemented by the private sector. In fact an open
question is whether direct government intervention is necessary or if, given the right
incentives, the private sector would take the initiative. The analysis of these experiences
shows that the pro-market activism view favors the use of a wide range of instruments. In
some countries, the government has provided infrastructure to help private financial
intermediaries achieve economies of scale and reduce the costs of providing financial
services. This is, for instance, the case the electronic market for factoring services created
by the Mexican development bank NAFIN and the electronic platform implemented by
BANSEFI, another Mexican financial institution, to help semi-formal and informal
financial intermediaries reduce their operating costs by centralizing back-office
operations. Alternatively, in Brazil, the government has amplified the phenomenon of
corresponding banking by making non-financial public infrastructure with a large
geographical coverage, like the post office, available for the distribution of financial
services. In other cases, the public sector has acted as an arranger in structured finance
schemes, coordinating stakeholders, providing guarantees, and fostering financial

4
innovation, as illustrated by the structured finance products created by FIRA, a Mexican
development financial institution, to provide financing to the agricultural sector. In other
cases the instruments used have been similar to those promoted by proponents of the
interventionist view (i.e., public credit, subsidies, and guarantees). However, pro-market
interventions tend to differ from previous ones in important aspects of their design—
especially regarding sustainability, time limits, governance, and transparency—and even
in terms of their objectives, as they seek to complement and promote private financial
intermediation, rather than replace it. This is the case of BancoEstado’s intervention in
the microfinance market in Chile, which was designed to promote financial innovation
and foster the participation of formal private financial institutions in this market. Other
pro-market interventions using traditional government instruments include the FOGAPE
guarantee system in Chile and the SIEBAN subsidy designed by FIRA to cover the initial
costs of serving small borrowers.

We conclude with some open questions raised by these experiences that are key to
understanding whether the pro-market activism view can constitute a viable alternative to
broaden access to finance in developing countries. First, a relevant question is whether
idiosyncratic experiences can lead to more general policy guidelines. The experiences we
describe may be the result of a specific environment that favors government innovation
and reduces the risk of political capture and may also be inherently related to certain
characteristics of the development-oriented financial institutions that have implemented
them. This raises the question of to what extent these experiences can be replicated in
other countries. Second, the analysis of the experiences suggests that it might be
necessary to rethink some institutional features of development-oriented financial
institutions to ensure that interventions succeed in fostering private financial
intermediation and broadening access. Some features that may be helpful in this regard
include: separating subsidies from funding and functioning more as development
agencies—with an initial endowment from the government but no annual budget
allocations—than financial intermediaries; redefining their mandates in dynamic terms,
so that institutions move on to new interventions once the market they were promoting
becomes self-sustainable; and modifying the way in which their performance is
evaluated, away from criteria based on the volume of guarantees or loans provides and
towards indicators based in the amount of financial intermediation promoted. Third, the
pro-market view poses certain risks. Pro-market interventions may reduce incentives for
institutional reform and detract resources away from efforts to achieve institutional
efficiency, which is the economy’s first best. Pro-market interventions may also lead to
inefficient equilibriums due to the existence of path dependence in financial
development. Furthermore, even if interventions are designed to be time-bound and
government support is restricted to the provision of seed capital, the creation of vested
interest entailed in any government intervention raises significant political economy
issues, as the government may face pressure to provide additional financial support in the
future. Finding adequate instruments to effectively minimize these risks is one of the
most important factors for the success of pro-market interventions. Fourth, an open
question is whether pro-market interventions are just short-term solutions to broaden
access while institutions are taking time to build, or if there is role for these interventions
even in countries with a good enabling environment. Finally, further research is needed to

5
understand the adequate roles for the public and private sectors in fostering financial
innovation and broadening access.

The rest of the study is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses conceptual


issues of access to finance, including the definition of a problem of access and the
relation between access and the institutional framework. Section 3 describes the different
views on the role of the public sector in financial markets. Section 4 illustrates the pro-
market activism view with a number of recent experiences in Latin America. Section 5
concludes with some final remarks.

2. Conceptual Issues in Access to Finance

2.1 Problem of Access vs. Lack of Access

Let us start by noting that the phenomenon that a certain proportion of the
population does not use financial services, which here we identify as lack of access, does
not necessarily mean that there is a problem of access. A lack of access and a problem of
access are two very different things. This distinction, unfortunately, has often been
ignored or understated in most of the recent literature, even though the failure to
recognize it can lead to the wrong policy advice. As defined above, a lack of access is
simply the fact that financial services are not being used. To conclude that this
observation entails a problem is not easy, not least because that would require a clear
definition of what such problem is. Additionally, even if we agreed on a definition, it is
difficult to identify a problem of access in practice and isolate it from the mere lack of
access. In other words, data might reveal an equilibrium outcome of lack of access, but
this may reflect either supply or demand factors. For example, households and firms may
be observed not to use credit simply because they may not need to borrow (either because
they lack viable investment projects or because they find it beneficial to use internal
funds to finance their investments). To complicate matters, the problem in some cases
may be not the lack of access to credit but rather the imprudent access to it. Many
financial crises have in fact originated in exuberant lending that did not internalize
appropriately the risks involved. Hence, that some borrowers are observed to be excluded
from credit may actually be a good thing, as their projects may not generate, under most
states of the world, the returns needed to pay back the debt. Finally, what may appear to
be a problem of access to credit for the disenfranchised poor may be mainly a problem of
poverty. In such a case, the policy solution would not be to artificially increase the flow
of credit to those segments of the population but rather to seek other means of reducing
poverty.

One important obstacle in trying to define problems of access to financial services


is that “financial services” is a label that applies to a very wide set of extremely
heterogeneous products, including savings, payments, insurance, and credit products.
These different classes of products have very different costs, risks, and production
functions, and it is not feasible to work on a definition of access that groups them all
together. In this study, however, we will consciously choose to narrow down our analysis

6
to problems of access to credit services only. We believe that, in what regards problems
of access to financial services, this particular class of products is the most interesting and
challenging from an analytical point of view and from policymakers’ perspective.
Products belonging to other categories, like savings and payment services, are just some
of the many services that the poor cannot afford to pay. On the other hand, the provision
of credit services entails many more complexities that sometimes lead providers to
exclude very diverse groups of borrowers.

To be able to conduct our study, we adopt a working definition of a problem of


access to credit. In our definition, a problem of access to credit exists when a project that
would be internally financed if resources were available, does not get external financing
(from outside financiers). This happens because there is a wedge between the expected
internal rate of return of the project (that is generated by the project’s fundamentals) and
the rate of return that external investors require to finance it. This wedge is mainly
introduced by two well-known constraints that hamper the ability to write and enforce
financial contracts, namely, principal-agent problems and transaction costs. 9

Note that our definition abstracts from any factors that may affect the level of
interest rates, and thus the opportunity cost of funds. For example, a lower interest rate
stemming from a reduction in macroeconomic volatility will reduce the opportunity cost
of funds, increasing the number of viable projects (i.e., those that would be internally
financed if resources were available) and the amount of financial contracting. However,
this will not necessarily reduce the wedge between the internal rate of return and that
required by external investors. Although in this example there would be an increase in the
observed use of financial services and arguably major welfare gains, it would not entail a
mitigation of the problem of access according to our definition.10 In effect, our definition
does not focus on the number of projects that are viable or on the number of projects that
are observed to receive external financing, per se. An increase in those numbers would of
course be highly desirable and beneficial to society, but it is outside the scope of our
definition. For us, as the share of viable projects that are able to obtain external finance
increases, the problem of access is reduced.

The two fundamental elements that introduce the access wedge—principal-agent


problems and transaction costs—while conceptually distinct, are tightly intertwined in
practice. Let us now turn to a brief discussion of each of them.

Consider principal-agent problems first. The classic principal-agent problems are


adverse selection and moral hazard. 11 The adverse selection problem arises because high-

9
See Lombardo and Pagano (2002) for a simple model showing the impact of principal-agent problems on
the equilibrium rate of return.
10
Note that our working definition also allows us to abstract from the level of competition in the financial
sector. The market structure of this sector may affect the cost of financing faced by borrowers, but even in
an monopolistic environment, in the absence of transaction costs and principal-agents problems, all projects
that would be internally financed (if the resources were available) should get external finance. The level of
competition in the financial sector, however, will affect how the profits are divided among borrowers and
creditors.
11
The canonical analysis of principal-agent problems in finance is due to Stiglitz and Weiss (1981).

7
risk borrowers (not just those that may be unable to repay their debt under a relevant
range of states of the world, but also those that might be unwilling to do so) are the ones
that are more willing to look for external finance. A financer may be willing to provide
financing to some projects/debtors by increasing the risk premium charged, but this
approach can backfire at some point due to the adverse selection problem. This is because
as the risk premium required by lenders rises, so does the riskiness of the pool of
interested borrowers. High-risk borrowers are “adversely selected” by higher risk
premiums. In effect, the higher the interest rate, the lower its usefulness and reliability for
creditors as a device for sorting out the good projects/borrowers from the bad ones. The
situation is one where the debtor may know ex-ante whether her project is good or bad,
and may have incentives to window-dress the bad ones, but the creditor cannot screen the
projects adequately because she cannot extract or verify this information. Faced with the
risk of adverse selection, lenders will try to use non-price criteria to screen
debtors/projects and ration and apportion credit, rather than further increasing the risk
premium.

The moral hazard problem, by contrast, concerns the situation after the agent
(e.g., the debtor) has received the resources (e.g., the loan) from the principal (e.g., the
lender). The problem here is that an agent may have informational advantages and
associated incentives to use the resources in ways that are inconsistent with the
principal’s interests. Acting on such incentives, the agent may divert resources to riskier
activities, strip and loot assets, or simply run away with the money, and the creditor may
not have an effective way to monitor and prevent such behavior. Note, however, that the
moral hazard problem can arise even when the agent does not have informational
advantages over the principal—i.e., when information is symmetrically shared—if the
principal faces high costs of enforcing the contract subscribed with the agent. Faced with
the moral hazard risk, a principal (e.g., a financer) would try to find ways to align the
incentives of the agent with its own. If unable to do so, principals may just not provide
funding—i.e., curtail access.

Consider, next, transaction costs. Even assuming that there are no principal-agent
problems, a problem of access to finance may still exist where the transaction costs
involved in the provision of finance exceed the expected risk-adjusted returns. Such a
scenario may arise due to the inability of financial intermediaries to reduce costs by
capturing economies of scale and scope. The result would affect disproportionately such
outsiders as poor households and small enterprises, as providing finance to them could be
rendered unprofitable by high costs per transaction. Cost barriers could also stem from
deficiencies in institutions and market infrastructure that make it expensive to gather
information on debtors/projects, value assets appropriately, and monitor and enforce
contracts.

Problems of asymmetric information and transactions costs, furthermore, can


generate first-mover dilemmas and coordination problems that make the expansion of
access to certain groups of the population increasingly difficult. As an example, when an
investor decides to start lending to a risky group of borrowers, such as small farmers, it
will have to bare all the costs in case of default, while facing fierce competition in case of
success, because its best borrowers, who now have a good credit history, will try to

8
obtain better lending terms from new creditors. Similarly, once a new lending technology
is introduced and proves to be successful, it can be easily adopted by others, who will not
share the research costs. Due to these dilemmas, research and investment in these areas
will be below the social optimum, unless a coordinating device is introduced to distribute
costs and benefits in an efficient way.

2.2 Institutions and Access to Finance

The institutional framework of the economy affects information flows, transaction


costs, and contract enforcement. Therefore, institutions can be expected to have a
significant impact on financial development and access to external finance. A relatively
recent and growing empirical literature has provided significant evidence in this regard,
finding that countries with legal systems that enforce property rights, support private
contractual arrangements, and protect the rights of creditors and shareholders have more
developed financial systems (see Beck and Levine, 2005 for a review of this literature).

In environments with weak public institutions, contract writing and enforcement


are difficult and publicly available information scarce. As a result, agency problems tend
to be mitigated through arrangements between private parties that rely heavily on
personalized relationships, fixed (preferably real estate) collateral, and group
monitoring. 12 Relationship finance mitigates agency problems thorough contractual
arrangements between private parties that raise the reputation costs of non-compliance
and hence foster loyalty. In these arrangements, to use North’s (1990, p. 55) words,
“parties … have a great deal of knowledge of each other and are involved in repeated
dealings … [so that] it simply pays to live up to agreements.” This is why, for all of its
potential drawbacks, related lending can be seen as way to cope with a deficient
informational and contractual environment. 13 Collateral is another way of mitigating
agency problems at all stages of financial development—by posting it, the agent puts part

12
The threat of violence and the resort to physical intimidation and punishment are also commonly
observed devices—especially used by loan sharks—to deal with agency problems in financially
underdeveloped markets.
13
Rajan and Zingales (2003a), for instance, argue (p. 34) that “insider-lending practices [are] a solution to
primitive informational and contractual infrastructure,” and note that “historical studies indicate that
lending to related parties reflects financial underdevelopment (…) rather than some cultural propensity
towards being devious.” There is in effect a great deal of fascinating literature on how agency problems
have been dealt with through relationship-based arrangements in earlier stages of financial development.
For example, Greif (1993) provides an illuminating analysis of how the Maghribi traders were able to
monitor agents involved in distant trading by forming a community of merchants who were mutually bound
by a set of rules (the Merchant’s Law). Haber and Maurer (2004) analyze the rapid expansion in bank
lending to the textile industry in Mexico during 1876-1911 which was mostly accounted for by lending to
insiders. They show that due to certain rules of the game (which, inter alia, required lenders to have
substantial own resources at risk, enabled minority shareholders to monitor controlling shareholders, and
boosted reputation effects), such lending to insiders did not degenerate into looting or the misallocation of
credit. La Porta et al. (2003), in contrast, illustrate the perverse incentives of related lending by showing
that, in the Mexico of more recent times, related borrowers have been 33 percent more likely to default on
their debts than unrelated ones, and that recovery rates have been 30 percent lower for related loans than for
unrelated ones.

9
of its own resources at risk, which aligns its incentives better with those of the
principal. 14 In a context where collateral repossession is unduly cumbersome, opacity is
high, accounting rules are unreliable, and asset markets are illiquid, financers will only
accept fixed collateral, preferably real estate. Finally, in the case of group monitoring—a
device extensively used in the context of microfinance—the agency problems are
mitigated because the group is collectively liable for the failure to pay of one member,
which encourages group members to police each other and to exclude the risky ones from
participating (Morduch, 1999). Relationship finance, fixed collateral, and group
monitoring do enable the broadening of access, but only up to a point, as they work, by
definition, within a circumscribed network of participants, excluding viable
projects/creditworthy borrowers that lack fixed collateral and/or connections.

In countries with a strong institutional framework, in contrast, the ability to solve


agency problems and reduce transaction costs is facilitated by the forces of competition
working in the context of a high quality contractual environment and efficient market
infrastructures, fostering the incorporation of advances in information technology and
financial engineering into financial contracts. This enables the expansion of arm’s-length
financing; contracts that are impersonal in nature and that, therefore, rely more on
transparency (e.g., broadly disclosed information and sound accounting) and enforcement
rules of general application (i.e., not circumscribed to the participants of a particular
contractual arrangement). Arm’s-length financing, which frees borrowers from the
tyranny of collateral and personalized connections, requires the prompt and unbiased
enforcement of private contracts by a third party (generally courts). Furthermore, in a
high quality contractual environment financial contracts are designed much less to cope
with or bypass bad public institutions (as is often the case in underdeveloped financial
systems) and much more to take advantage of the opportunities opened by good
institutions. Financial development, thus, engenders a robust process of chipping down of
the barriers to access.

Institutional development can also broaden access through the reduction of


transaction costs. For instance, sound frameworks for collateral repossession and
corporate bankruptcy will reduce the costs of recovering value in the event of default.
Similarly, reliable disclosure and accounting standards will reduce the costs of evaluating
projects. Technological innovation also plays a crucial role in cost reductions, even where
the contractual environment is still deficient. A case in point is the fast expansion of
consumer and micro lending in emerging markets over the last years, which has been
propelled by major costs reductions resulting from the intensive use of e-technology,
scoring methods, and credit information systems. 15

The view that financial development is closely related to institutional


development implies that, as any process of institutional evolution, financial development

14
See Rodriguez-Meza (2004) for a discussion of the role of collateral. IADB (2004) discusses the issue of
over reliance on collateral in Latin America.
15
Credit scoring is an automated statistical technique used to assess the credit risk of loan applicants. It
involves analyzing a large sample of past borrowers to identify the characteristics that predict the likelihood
of default. Scoring systems usually generate a single quantitative measure (the credit score) to evaluate the
credit application.

10
is characterized by “path dependence” (North, 1990). Path dependence reflects the fact
that institutional arrangements are self-reinforcing (although not always efficient) due to
substantial increasing returns—the large set up costs of new institutions, the subsequent
lowering of uncertainty and transaction and information costs, and the associated
spillovers and externalities for contracting. An important corollary of path dependence is
that an isolated legal or regulatory feature that may be functional under a given
institutional matrix and at a given stage of financial development may produce
unintended effects when transplanted to another institutional milieu. 16

3. The Role of the Public Sector in Broadening Access

Given the major potential benefits of access-enhancing financial development, a


relevant question, especially in countries with underdeveloped financial systems, is
whether government intervention to foster financial development and broaden access is
necessary and, if so, what form should this intervention take.

Standard arguments for government intervention in the financial sector stress that
financial markets are different from other markets because they rely heavily on
information and produce externalities that cannot be easily internalized by market
participants. 17,18 When information is asymmetric between lenders and borrowers and is
costly to obtain, or when the social benefit of a project is higher than the private benefit,
the market may fail to provide adequate financing.

Financial markets rely heavily on the production and processing of information,


which is fundamentally a public-good, in the sense that it is non-rival in consumption (the
consumption of the good by one individual does not detract from that of another
individual) and non-excludable (it is very costly to exclude anyone from enjoying the
good). As theory demonstrates, such goods are undersupplied in a competitive
equilibrium. For example, investors may not find it optimal to screen and finance certain
borrowers because, once these borrowers obtain a good credit history, they can get credit

16
Empirical studies suggest that legal traditions help explain cross-country differences in investor
protection laws, contracting environment, and financial development (see, for example, Beck, Demirguc-
Kunt, and Levine, 2003; Levine, 1998, 1999; and La Porta et al., 1997, 1998), with countries of English
legal origin presenting better creditor and shareholder rights protection and more developed financial
markets. This evidence suggests the existence of a high level of path dependence in financial development.
However, other researchers reject the view that legal origin is a central determinant of investor protection
and stress the role of politics in determining regulations and contract enforcement (see, for example,
Pagano and Volpin, 2001; Rajan and Zingales, 2003b; and Roe, 1994).
17
Stiglitz (1994) discusses the main arguments for public intervention in the financial sector. Besley (1994)
presents a critical review of the arguments for government intervention in financial markets, with a focus
on rural credit. Also, see Zingales (2004) for a critique of the traditional rationale for government
intervention based on Coase’s (1960) arguments and their application to financial regulation.
18
Another common argument for government intervention in financial markets is related to the need to
maintain the safety and soundness of the financial system, given the large costs and externalities generated
by financial crises. This argument, however, has been invoked to justify the need for government regulation
and supervision, rather than direct public involvement in financial markets.

11
from other investors, who will not bare the initial screening costs. 19 The failure to
appropriate the returns of information causes financial intermediaries to under invest in
information acquisition. The sub-optimal stock of information gathered by the financial
sector leads to a sub-optimal level of investment: viable projects will be underfinanced
(or not financed at all) due to the lack of adequate information. Similar effects are present
when lenders invest in new credit technologies. While they will bare all the costs in case
of failure, it is often difficult to prevent other investors from adopting the new technology
once it has proven successful, reducing incentives for innovation.

Another reason for competitive markets to produce inefficient equilibrium


outcomes is when the social rate of return of an investment differs from the private rate of
return. Private financiers focus on the expected returns that they receive and therefore
have no incentives to finance socially profitable but financially unattractive investments.
Private banks, for instance, may not find it profitable to open branches in rural and
isolated areas, because they fail to internalize the social benefits that may be accrued by
the positive effects on growth and poverty reduction in these areas. Similarly, private
creditors may find it unattractive to finance infant industries or industries that are not
particularly profitable but are considered of national interest, such as airlines or oil
refineries.

Finally, some financial instruments may need to achieve a certain scale in order to
be profitable. This is the argument behind the protection of infant industries. The failure
to coordinate efforts may lead to a prisoner’s dilemma type of game in which gains only
materialize if all investors invest in one project simultaneously, and the one that invests
alone incurs a large loss. In this type of game, without a coordination mechanism, no
investment will take place in equilibrium.

While most economists would agree that some type of government intervention to
foster financial development is warranted, there is less consensus regarding the specific
nature of this intervention. Answers to this question tend to be polarized in two highly
contrasting but well-established views: the interventionist and the laissez-faire views.
The interventionist view argues that an active public sector involvement in mobilizing
and allocating financial resources, including government ownership of banks, is needed
to broaden access to credit, as private markets fail to expand access. In contrast, the
laissez-faire view contends that governments can do more harm than good by intervening
directly in the financial system and argues that government efforts should instead focus
on improving the enabling environment, which will help to reduce agency problems and
transaction costs and mitigate problems of access.

A third view is emerging in the middle ground, favoring direct government


interventions in non-traditional ways. This third view is in a sense closer to the laissez-
faire view, to the extent that it recognizes a limited role for the government in financial
markets and acknowledges that institutional efficiency is the economy’s first best, but, as
it will be explained below, it does not exclude the possibility that in the short run, while

19
Additionally, since the likelihood of default increases with the amount borrowed, further borrowing by
the debtor may have a negative impact on the first creditor (Arnott and Stiglitz, 1991).

12
institutions are taking time to build and consolidate, some government actions undertaken
in collaboration with market participants may be warranted. This is the view of pro-
market activism. We now turn to a more detailed characterization of each view.

3.1 The Interventionist View

The interventionist view is a very old view, which was popularized by the import
substitution policies of the 1950s and 1960s. This view regards the problems of access to
finance as resulting from widespread market failures that cannot be overcome in
underdeveloped economies by leaving markets forces alone. 20 For the proponents of this
view, it is less important to gain an adequate understanding of why private markets fail
than to recognize that they do fail, and badly. The key contention, therefore, is that to
expand access to finance beyond the narrow circle of privileged borrowers—mainly large
enterprises and well-off households—the active intervention of the government is
required. The government is thus called upon to have an intense, hands-on involvement
in mobilizing and allocating financial resources.

The interventionist view was closely related to the predominating thinking at the
time about the role of the government in the development process. The early development
literature drew attention to the constraints imposed by limited capital accumulation and
argued that markets tended to work inadequately in developing countries (see, for
example, Gerschenkron, 1962; Hirschman, 1958; Rosenstein-Rodan, 1943; and Rostow,
1962). 21 Consistent with these view, the growth strategies of most developing countries
in the 1950s and 1960s focused on accelerating the rate of capital accumulation and
technological adoption through direct government intervention. The role of the
government was to take the “commanding heights” of the economy and guide resource
allocation to those areas believed to be most conductive to long-term growth. This led to
import substitution policies, state ownership of firms, subsidization of infant industries,
central planning, and a wide range government interventions and price controls.
Confidence in government intervention was, at least partially, based on its perceived
success in expanding production during World War II and its role in the reconstruction of
Europe and Japan. Moreover, memories of the Great Depression made policymakers
skeptical about the functioning of markets.

The main instrument to broaden access to finance promoted by proponents of the


interventionist view was the direct provision of funds through public, development-
oriented banks. As a result, public banks mushroomed throughout the world: by the
1970s, the state owned on average 40 percent of the assets of the largest banks in
developed countries and about 65 percent in developing countries. Among developing
countries there were large regional differences, with South Asia and Latin America
presenting the highest share public bank ownership, reaching close to 90 percent of the
20
Gerschenkron (1962) was one of the first authors to argue that the private sector alone is not able to
overcome the problems of access to finance in a weak institutional environment.
21
The arguments made by these early authors have been formalized in several theoretical papers (see, for
example, Hoff and Stiglitz, 2001 and Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny, 1989).

13
assets of the ten largest banks in the former and around 65 percent in the latter (banks
were fully government owned in transition economies). Public banks became key policy
vehicles, used by governments to support the pursuit of their social and developmental
agenda through the selective allocation of (often subsidized) credit. Consistently with the
market failure rationale, public banks tended to focus on areas where private markets are
typically missing, such as long-term finance, lending to SMEs, housing finance, and
agricultural credit.

Theoretically, in underdeveloped economies, public banks may have advantages


over private banks in dealing with principal-agent problems and transactions costs—as
they might, for instance, be better able to access information and exploit economies of
scale. The government could increase the number of viable projects that get financed
through several means: (i) using privileged information or compelling the disclosure of
information to lower the costs of screening and monitoring; (ii) forcing participation in
insurance schemes to increase the expected return on the loan; and (iii) internalizing
potential externalities and redistributing costs through taxes or government borrowing
(Stiglitz, 1994).

Governments can cross-check information with income tax systems and other
official records, or compel the disclosure of information that is not available to private
investors. This gives publicly owned banks an advantage in selecting and monitoring
borrowers, reducing the fixed costs of providing loans, and therefore reducing the break-
even rate of return of external finance.

The government can also help to solve the problems generated by externalities.
As mentioned above, if the social rate of return of a project is higher than its private rate
of return, private creditors may not be willing to finance it, even if it would be beneficial
for society as a whole to do so. This happens because it is difficult for the private sector
to internalize the social benefits that may be generated by the project. This instead can be
achieved by the government, through the tax system (intra-generational risk sharing) or
through government debt (inter-generational risk sharing).

In addition, government ownership of banks may increase public trust in the


banking system, leading to more savings and deeper financial markets. 22 Also, if
government-owned banks are more trusted by depositors than private banks, they will
have an advantage in attracting deposits and will face lower funding costs (see Adrianova
et al., 2002 for a discussion of the case of Russia).

Apart from the direct provision of credit through public banks, another
widespread tool for broadening access in developing countries was the imposition of
lending requirements, which obligated private banks to allocate a certain share of their
loans (or even absolute amounts) to specific sectors or regions. In Brazil, for example,

22
Note that the government could also increase trust in the banking sector through adequate regulation and
supervision of private banks, as well as through the creation of deposit insurance systems. Which type of
intervention will have a larger impact in terms of increasing public trust in the financial system depends on
the public’s perception of the government’s ability to provide incentives and monitor private banks relative
to its ability to monitor its own agents.

14
commercial banks were required to allocate between 20 and 60 percent (depending on
bank size) of their sight deposits to agriculture. In India, 50 percent of bank deposits had
to be invested in government bonds at below market rates and most of the remaining
funds had to be directed to priority sectors like agriculture and small enterprises, with
only about 20 percent of bank resources being freely allocated. In Thailand, bank
branches established outside Bangkok after 1975 were subject to “local lending
requirements,” mandating them to lend at least 60 percent of their deposit resources
locally (Booth et al., 2001). Many countries also established refinance schemes, which
allowed commercial banks to discount loans to selected sectors at preferential rates with
the Central Bank. The rationale for these interventions is similar to that for the creation of
public banks discussed above: private banks cannot internalize the positive externalities
generated by some investments, and therefore, without government intervention, may fail
to allocate enough funds to those projects with the highest social returns.

Another commonly used tool was the regulation of interest rates. Governments
often established preferential rates for commercial lending to priority sectors, which were
significantly lower than those on regular loans. In Colombia, for example, interest rates
on directed credit were, on average, about 12 percentage points lower than those on non-
preferential credit over the period 1983-1987 (World Bank, 1990a). In the case of
Turkey, this differential reached 36 percentage points between 1980 and 1982 (World
Bank, 1989). A variation of this tool was the establishment of interest rate ceilings on
deposits and/or loans, which could apply across the board or vary by sector or type of
loan. Interest rate controls were expected to result in lower costs of financing and greater
access to credit. 23

The extensive regulation of the banking sector resulted in a pervasive influence of


the government on credit allocation in many developing countries. In Colombia, for
example, directed credit accounted on average for 62 percent of total credit provided by
commercial banks and financial corporations to industry and mining between 1984 and
1987 (World Bank, 1990b). In the case of Korea, the ratio of directed credit to total credit
reached 60 percent at the end of the 1970s (Booth et al., 2001). In Brazil, government
credit programs represented more than 70 percent of credit outstanding to the public and
private sectors in 1987 (World Bank, 1989).

Despite the theoretical advantages of government-owned banks in broadening


access to credit, the general experience with public banking in developing countries has
not been successful. Most empirical studies suggest that public banks tend to do more
harm than good (see Barth, Caprio, and Levine, 2001; Caprio and Honohan, 2001; IADB,
2004; and La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer, 2002). In particular, these studies—
typically based on cross-country regressions—find that greater government participation
in bank ownership is associated with lower levels of financial development, less credit to
the private sector, wider intermediation spreads, greater credit concentration, slower

23
Broadening access to credit was not the only reason for the imposition of interest rate controls and
directed lending requirements. Strict control and regulation of the banking system was also supposed to
give monetary authorities a better control over the money supply and provided the government with easily
accessible resources to finance public expenditures (see Roubini and Sala-i-Martin, 1992).

15
economic growth, and recurrent fiscal drains. 24,25 The perceived failure of public banking
in developing countries contrasts with evidence suggesting that development banks
played an important role in the rapid industrialization of Continental Europe and Japan
(Cameron, 1953, 1961; Gershenkron, 1952). 26

While cross-country studies tend to find a negative or, at best, neutral impact of
government bank ownership, it is necessary to consider that public banks are highly
heterogeneous, both across and within countries. Detailed case studies highlight some
success stories, such as the Village Bank system of Bank Rayat in Indonesia
(Charitonenko, Benjamin, and Yaron, 1998) or the Bank for Agriculture and Agricultural
Cooperatives in Thailand (Townsend and Yaron, 2001). 27

The prevalence, on average, of a negative impact of public banks in cross-country


empirical studies can be explained by a variety of reasons. For starters, public banks in
developing countries have frequently failed at reaching their targeted clientele, typically
by wide margins, and even where they have done so, it has been at the expense of unduly
high subsidy costs. Also, major incentive and governance problems in the operation of
public banks have tended to surface, leading to such recurrent problems as poor loan
origination and even poorer loan collection (thereby fostering a non-payment culture),
wasteful administrative expenditures, overstaffing, plain corruption, political
manipulation of lending with “clientelistic” motives, and capture by powerful special
interests. All these factors have typically resulted in large losses and the need for
recurrent recapitalizations, at very high fiscal costs. For example, in 2001 the Brazilian
government absorbed the non-performing loan portfolios of two public banks (Banco do
Brasil and Caixa Economica Federal) at a net cost of about 6 percent of GDP (Micco and
Panizza, 2005). In the case of Turkey, the cost of recapitalizing the two largest public
banks (Ziraat Bank and Halk Bank) in 2001 amounted to 15.5 percent of GDP (Fouad et

24
IADB (2004) revises the empirical evidence on the impact of public banks and finds that, while the
results that government-owned banks have a negative impact are not as strong as previously thought, there
is no indication that government ownership has a positive effect. It concludes that public banks, at best, do
not play much of a role in financial development.
25
The interpretation of these findings in terms of causality is rather difficult, as the association between
government participation in the banking system and poor financial development and macroeconomic
performance could stem either from the need for more government intervention in countries with severe
market imperfections that prevent financial development, or from a negative impact of public intervention
on financial markets. Galindo and Micco (2004) try to address the problem of causality by using the
methodology devised by Rajan and Zingales (1998) and find that government-owned banks do not promote
the growth of those industries that rely more on external finance, nor do they promote the growth of
industries that, due to reduced collateral, face more financial constraints. They conclude that what matters
for growth is the development of private financial institutions.
26
Armendariz de Aghion (1999a) compares the successful development banking experience of Credit
Nationale in France with the relatively unsuccessful more recent experience of Nacional Financiera in
Mexico. She argues that the requirement to engage in co-financing arrangements with private financial
intermediaries in the case of Credite Nationale and the type of government involvement (subsidized credit
and loan guarantees in the case of France, direct ownership in Mexico) are among the factors that explain
the contrasting results.
27
Following Yaron (1992), these papers use a comprehensive framework to evaluate the performance of
development banks and their lending programs, mainly in terms of the outreach to their targeted clientele
and the degree to which their operations are dependent on subsidies.

16
al., 2005). In Mexico, the government had to recapitalize Banrural, a development bank
providing financing to the rural sector, with about 1.1 billion U.S. dollars in 1999, even after
having significantly downscaled its operations in previous years (Brizzi, 2001). 28

Moreover, it has been extremely difficult for public banks to break free from the
inherent contradiction between their social policy mandates, on the one hand, and
pressures to avoid losses, on the other. Public banks are charged with social policy
mandates which, by definition, expose them to high-risk clientele and limit their capacity
to diversify risks across economic and geographic sectors or across segments of
population with different income levels. With subsidies typically hidden in below market
interest rates, these institutions tend to incur low profits or losses—often magnified by
weak risk management systems, wasteful administrative expenses, and vulnerability to
political interference—and hence require repeated recapitalizations. To minimize
operational losses and the associated fiscal costs, these banks are often placed under the
same regulatory and supervisory standards as private commercial banks. This leads them
to enter into less risky and more lucrative lines of business, in competition with private
banks, reducing losses. However, this tends to be unsustainable as their activities become
increasingly inconsistent with their social policy mandate, prompting political pressures
to re-orient their activities towards meeting their mandate, which leads to a new cycle of
losses and recapitalizations. 29

The experience with directed credit programs has also been unsuccessful in most
cases (World Bank, 1989, 2005a). Although some East Asian countries like Japan, Korea,
and Taiwan seem to have achieved some success with directed lending to manufacturing,
in most developing countries the results have been poor. 30 Directed credit programs often
failed to reach their intended beneficiaries. Within priority sectors, larger and more
influential borrowers were favored. Lenders misclassified loans to provide credit to other
sectors and borrowers diverted credit to other uses. One extreme example is the case of
Korea, where an active market developed for borrowers with access to preferential
lending to on-lend funds to firms without it. Directed credit programs were often used not
to correct market failures, but to provide funds to politically-connected sectors and firms.
Once directed credit programs were established, they created a strong constituency of
beneficiaries, making it very difficult for governments to reduce their support to these
programs, regardless of how inefficient or costly they were. The cost of subsidies on
directed credit programs has often been substantial: in Brazil, for example, this cost was

28
Banrural is currently being liquidated. The World Bank has provided support of 505 million U.S. dollars
to the Mexican government to replace Banrural with a non-bank financial institution, Financiera Rural. The
total cost of government intervention in the rural financial system in Mexico, mostly through different
development banks, during the 1983-1992 period has been estimated at approximately 28.5 billion U.S.
dollars, 80 percent of which is associated with interest rate subsidies. The annual average of these costs
represents about 13 percent of agricultural GDP (Brizzi, 2001).
29
This phenomenon is what de la Torre (2002) calls the “Sisyphus syndrome” of public banks.
30
See World Bank (1993) for a description of the experience of East Asian countries with credit controls.
Also, Vittas and Cho (1996) try to extract the main lessons from the experience of these countries with
directed credit programs. They conclude that these programs should be small, narrowly focused, and of
limited duration. Several authors (see, for example, Cho, 1997; Santomero, 1997; Vittas, 1997; and World
Bank, 1993) point out that the relative success of directed credit programs in East Asian countries was
achieved at the expense of a slower development of more complete financial markets.

17
estimated at between 7 and 8 percent of GDP in 1987. In Korea, the subsidy provided by
directed credit was approximately 1 percent of GDP during the 1980s (Booth at al.,
2001). Directed lending requirements in many cases left little power or responsibility on
credit allocation to private banks, resulting in low investments in credit assessment and
monitoring. Also, extensive refinance schemes at low interest rates reduced the incentives
for financial institutions to mobilize resources on their own, leading to a lower level of
financial intermediation.

Furthermore, direct government intervention in the operation of financial markets,


through directed lending programs, interest rate controls, entry restrictions, and high
reserve requirements, has been found to have significant costs in terms of economic
efficiency and growth and to stifle, rather than promote, financial development. These
policies were initially challenged by Goldsmith (1969) and later by McKinnon (1973)
and Shaw (1973), who coined the term “financial repression” to describe them.
Goldsmith (1969) argues that the main impact of financial repression is to reduce the
marginal productivity of capital. Since interest rate controls keep rates below their
equilibrium level, high quality projects with higher returns do not get financed.
McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973) focused on two other channels. First, financial
repression reduces the efficiency of the banking sector in allocating savings, as bankers
do not ration credit according to price criteria. Second, by maintaining interest rates
below their market equilibrium, financial repression reduces the savings level. These two
channels have a negative impact on growth, as too little will be saved and those savings
will not be allocated to the projects with the highest marginal productivity. 31 Financial
development is also likely to suffer under these conditions, as the low return on financial
assets encourages savers to keep their savings outside the financial system.

3.2 The Laissez-Faire View

Over the last decades, mostly as a reaction to the mentioned problems of public
banking and direct government intervention in the financial sector, a second, entirely
opposite view has gained ground: the laissez-faire view. This view also stems from an
increasing awareness of the role played by institutions and market infrastructures in
financial development. The laissez-faire view contends that, due to incentive issues,
bureaucrats will never be good bankers and that governments can do more harm than
good by intervening directly in credit allocation and pricing. According to this view,
although there may be market failures in the financial industry, these are not as extensive

31
A number of cross-country studies have attempted to measure the impact of financial repression on
growth. Most of these papers use real interest rates (or variables based on threshold values of real interest
rates) to measure financial repression, as controls on lending and deposit rates resulted in low or negative
real interest rates in many developing countries (Agarwala, 1983; Gelb, 1989). These studies tend to find a
negative relation between financial repression and economic growth (see, for example, Easterly, 1993;
Lanyi and Saracoglu, 1983; Roubini and Sala-i-Martin, 1992; and World Bank, 1989). Galindo, Micco, and
Ordoñez (2002) measure the extent of financial liberalization using indices based on financial system
regulations and find that financial liberalization, mainly in the domestic financial sector, increases the
relative growth rate of those industries that rely more on external finance.

18
as assumed by proponents of the interventionist view and private parties by themselves,
given well-defined property rights and good contractual institutions, may be able to
address most of these problems. Additionally, the costs of government failures are likely
to exceed those of market failures, rendering direct interventions, at best, ineffective and
in many cases, counterproductive. Therefore, this view recommends that governments
exit from bank ownership and lift restrictions on the allocation of credit and the
determination of interest rates. Instead, the argument goes, government efforts should be
deployed towards improving the enabling environment—e.g., providing a stable
macroeconomic framework, enhancing creditor and shareholder rights and their
enforceability, upgrading prudential regulation, modernizing accounting practices, and
promoting the expansion of reliable debtor information systems (Caprio and Honohan,
2001; Klapper and Zaidi, 2005; Rajan and Zingales, 2001; World Bank, 2005a).

The laissez-faire view is consistent with the general shift on thinking about the
role of the government in the development process over the last decades. The experiences
of developing countries in the 1970s and 1980s showed that widespread government
intervention in the economy, through trade restrictions, state ownership of firms, financial
repression, price controls, and foreign exchange rationing, resulted in the waste of large
resources and impeded, rather than promoted, growth. Confidence in the ability of the
government to foster economic development diminished dramatically, as growing
evidence showed that government failure was widespread in developing countries and in
many cases outweighed market failure (see, for example, Krueger, 1990; Srinivasan,
1985; and World Bank, 1983). 32 This led economists and policymakers to conclude that
constraining the role of the public sector in the economy and eliminating the distortions
associated with protectionism, subsidies, and public ownership was essential to fostering
growth. 33 Much of this vision was reflected in the so-called “Washington Consensus” and
guided most of the reform programs during 1990s. 34 Governments focused on creating a
stable macroeconomic environment by reducing fiscal deficits and improving monetary
policies. In line with the objective of reducing the role of the state in the economy,
countries privatized government-owned enterprises, deregulated domestic industries,
eliminated quantitative restrictions and licensing requirements, and dismantled
agricultural marketing boards and other state monopolies. Many countries also reduced
tariffs and other restrictions on imports and liberalized regulations on foreign investment.
In recent years, the focus of the reforms has turned away from macroeconomic
stabilization and liberalization and shifted towards improving the institutional
environment (World Bank, 1999, 2002), consistent with the growing empirical evidence

32
The theoretical literature also started to focus on the causes of government failure, such as rent-seeking
and capture by special interests (see, for example, Buchanan, 1962; Krueger, 1974; Stigler, 1971; and
Tullock, 1967)
33
The view that better policies would lead to higher growth was also motivated by endogenous growth
theories developed by Lucas and Romer in the mid-1980s which imply that government policies can
influence not just the income level, but also countries’ steady-state growth rates. This literature provided
the foundation to empirical work based on cross-country regressions to analyze the effects of policies on
growth, which was started by Barro (1991). Durlauf, Johnson, and Temple (2005), Easterly (2005), and
Temple (1999) provide critical surveys of this literature. See also Rodrik (2005).
34
The term “Washington Consensus” was coined by Williamson (1990). See World Bank (2005b) for a
review of the reforms during the 1990s and a discussion of their policy lessons.

19
on the impact of institutions of economic development (see, for example, Acemoglu,
Johnson, and Robinson, 2001; Easterly and Levine, 2003; Hall and Jones, 1999; and
Rodrik, Subramanian, and Trebbi, 2004).

The failure of the financial repression policies led many countries to liberalize
their financial systems, reducing direct government intervention in the allocation and
pricing of credit. Financial liberalization was carried out both on the domestic and
external fronts. Regarding the domestic financial system, liberalization policies included
the elimination or downscaling of directed lending programs, the reduction of reserve
requirements, and the deregulation of interest rates. On the external front, many countries
lifted restrictions on foreign borrowing by financial institutions and corporations and
dismantled controls on foreign exchange and capital transactions. Despite stops, gaps,
and some reversals, the process of financial liberalization has advanced through much of
the world over the last decades. 35 Countries in all income groups have liberalized,
although developed countries were among the first to start this process and have
remained more liberalized than lower-income economies throughout. In developing
countries, the pace and timing of financial liberalization has differed across regions. In
Latin America, Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay liberalized their financial systems in the
late 1970s, but these reforms were reversed in the aftermath of the 1982 debt crisis, and
financial systems remained repressed during most of the 1980s. Latin American countries
carried out substantial financial liberalizations in the late 1980s and early 1990s. In the
case of East Asia, the liberalization process was more gradual. A number of countries
started slowly rationalizing their directed credit programs and liberalizing their interest
rates during the 1980s and the process in many cases stretched for over a decade.

The financial liberalization process was accompanied by a significant


privatization of government-owned banks, driven by fiscal considerations and the
changing view about the role of the state in the economy.36 From 1985 to 2000 more than
50 countries carried out bank privatizations, totaling 270 transactions and raising over
119 billion U.S. dollars (Boehmer, Nash, and Netter, 2005). Although the process started
in higher-income countries, developing countries quickly followed suit. The privatization
process intensified in the second half of the 1990s, with more than 60 percent of the
transactions taking place after 1994. Although this privatization wave resulted in a
significant reduction in government bank ownership, the presence of the public sector in
the banking system remains widespread, especially in developing countries. In 2003, the
government held controlling stakes in banks representing about 7 percent of banking
sector assets in developed countries and about 19 percent in developing countries (Clarke
et al., 2004). Furthermore, in 21 of the 73 developing countries for which information is
available, the public sector controls more than 30 percent of total banking system assets,
compared to only three developed countries where this is the case.

The laissez-faire view led to a barrage of reforms aimed at creating the proper
institutions and infrastructure for financial markets to flourish. Governments tried to
35
See Williamson and Mahar (1998) for an overview of the financial liberalization process around the
world. Kaminsky and Schmukler (2003) construct indices of financial liberalization for a large number of
developing and developed countries.
36
See Megginson (2005) for a review of the empirical literature on bank privatization.

20
mitigate principal-agent problems in credit markets by reforming bankruptcy laws and
enacting new legislation regarding creditor rights. Many countries also tried to improve
information sharing among lenders by fostering the development of credit bureaus. Credit
bureaus make borrowers’ loan payment history available to different lenders, facilitating
information exchanges and reducing screening costs. Credit bureaus also increase
incentives for repayment, since borrowers know that their reputations will be shared
among different creditors. 37 Governments tried to create a supportive environment for
private credit bureaus by enacting credit reporting laws that allow the sharing of
information among creditors and in many cases created public credit registries. Miller
(2003) reports that 15 countries, including nine Latin American countries, have
established public credit registries since 1989 and that several developing countries in
other regions are actively considering similar initiatives. Private credit bureaus have also
experienced a significant growth over the last decades, with approximately half of the
private credit reporting firms around the world covered by Miller (2003) starting their
operations after 1989. In some countries, governments also modified collateral laws and
created registries for moveable property in order to allow these assets to be used as
collateral, which was expected to benefit smaller firms that are less likely to own fixed
assets. 38

Enticed by their potential benefits, governments also implemented several reforms


aimed at fostering securities market development. 39 In particular, governments created
domestic securities and exchange commissions, developed the regulatory and supervisory
framework, and took important strides towards establishing and improving the basic
infrastructure for securities market operations. The latter included reforms related to
centralized exchanges, securities clearance and settlement systems, custody
arrangements, and trading platforms. Moreover, many countries tried to improve
corporate governance practices by introducing new standards in a number of different
areas, including voting ratings, tender procedures, and the structure of the board of
directors. 40 Some countries also improved accounting and disclosure standards and
enacted new insider trading regulations. 41

37
McIntosh and Wydick (2004) show that the total effect of credit bureaus can be decomposed in two
separate effects (a screening effect and an incentive effect) and that credit bureaus can improve access to
financing for the poorest borrowers. Empirically, Japelli and Pagano (2002) find that the presence of credit
bureaus, irrespective of whether they are public or private, is associated with deeper credit markets and
lower credit risk. Love and Mylenko (2003) find that the existence of private credit bureaus is associated
with lower financing constraints, while public credit registries do not seem to have a significant effect.
38
In most developing countries, legal impediments restrict the use of movable property as collateral, as
there is little or no information on whether other creditors have claims on the same asset and the
repossession process is usually cumbersome (often exceeding the economic life of the movable good). In
contrast, lending secured by movable property is widespread in developed countries, reaching almost 40
percent of total credit in the U.S. (Fleising, 1996).
39
See World Bank (2004a) for a description of the evolution of securities markets and related reforms over
the last decades, with a focus on Latin America.
40
See Capaul (2003) for an overview of corporate governance reforms in Latin America.
41
Bhattacharya and Daouk (2002) find that 39 developing countries have established insider trading
regulations since 1990.

21
Despite the intense reform effort, access to finance does not seem to have
increased significantly in most developing countries since the early 1990s. 42 While many
countries experienced a strong growth in deposits, this growth did not translate into an
increase of similar magnitude in credit to the private sector, as most of the additional
loanable funds were absorbed by higher holdings of public sector debt (Hanson, 2003). 43
Similarly, the performance of domestic securities markets in many emerging economies
has been disappointing (World Bank, 2004a). Although some countries experienced
growth of their domestic securities markets, this growth in most cases was not as
significant as that witnessed by industrialized nations. Other countries experienced an
actual deterioration of their securities markets. 44

The general perception of lack of results from the reform process contrasts with
empirical evidence suggesting that reforms did in fact have a positive impact on financial
development. For instance, Djankov, McLiesh, and Shleifer (2006) find that
improvements in creditor rights and the introduction of credit bureaus are associated with
increases in credit to the private sector. Similarly, de la Torre, Gozzi, and Schmukler
(2005) find that capital market-related reforms tend to be followed by significant
increases in stock market capitalization, trading, and capital raising. The contrast between
this evidence and the general perception may be explained by excessively high
expectations at the beginning of the reform process. 45 The gap between expectations and
outcomes may also be ascribed to a combination of insufficient reform implementation
with impatience. 46 In effect, despite what many claim, key reforms were in some cases
not even initiated, while other reforms were often implemented in an incomplete or
inconsistent fashion. In many cases, only laws were approved, but they were not duly
implemented, nor were they adequately enforced. Moreover, policymakers have been too
impatient, often expecting results to materialize sooner than warranted. While the

42
From a more general perspective, Easterly (2001) points out that despite significant policy reforms,
developing countries have on average stagnated over the last two decades. He argues that worldwide
factors may have contributed to this stagnation and says that this evidence deals a significant blow to the
optimism surrounding the “Washington Consensus.”
43
The increase in public sector debt holdings was driven by several factors, including central banks’
growing use of bonds as monetary policy instruments, post-crisis bank restructurings in several countries,
and increasing fiscal deficits. In countries where banking crises where not massive and government deficits
were limited, credit to the private sector grew reasonably well (Hanson, 2003).
44
Stock markets in many developing countries have seen listings and liquidity decrease, as a growing
number of firms have cross-listed and raised capital in international financial centers, such as New York
and London. Karolyi (2004) and Moel (2001) offer evidence on how the use of American Depositary
Receipts (ADRs) can affect stock markets in emerging economies. Levine and Schmukler (2006a,b)
analyze the impact of migration to international markets on domestic market trading and liquidity.
45
Loayza, Fajnzylber, and Calderon (2005) analyze whether the growth outcome of the reforms of the
1990s in Latin America can be interpreted as a disappointment. They estimate the expected impact of the
reforms on economic growth using cross-country regressions and then compare the predicted growth rate of
Latin American countries on the basis of the reforms with their observed growth during the 1990s. They
find that most Latin American countries experienced growth rates consistent with the extent of the reforms
and thus conclude that reforms had the predicted impact. However, the estimated pay-offs of the reforms in
many cases are quite small, suggesting that initial expectations may have been overly optimistic.
46
Renditions of this view, in the more general context of assessing the impact of reforms on economic
development, can be found in Fernandez Arias and Montiel (2001), Krueger (2004), Singh et al. (2005),
and World Bank (1997).

22
expectation of a rapid payoff may be justified with respect to some first-generation
reforms, more complex second-generation reforms have long gestation periods. 47

Proponents of the laissez-faire view also point out that, even in environments
where there are institutional deficiencies that negatively affect financial contracting, there
has been some progress in expanding access. One example of this is the strong growth of
microfinance in developing countries. Microfinance consists in the provision of financial
services to low-income individuals and informal firms. 48 Microfinance institutions have
developed several mechanisms to deal with principal-agent problems and help reduce the
transaction costs of serving small borrowers (see Appendix 1 for a general overview of
microfinance). Unsecured consumer credit, including credit card lending, has also
experienced significant growth in many developing countries in recent years (see, for
example, BIS, 2005a and The Economist, 2006), fostered by advances in information
systems and scoring methods. 49

Although the arguments of the laissez-faire view are quite compelling and have
attained widespread support, the associated policy prescription is not free of problems.
Improving the enabling environment is easier said than done. Even if we knew exactly
what needs to be done, and in what sequence, there is no denying that the actual reform
implementation would be full of glitches and affected by the two-steps-forward-one-step-
backward phenomenon. But the reality is that we do not know with precision all that
needs to be done, as there is no ex-ante formula to achieve access-enhancing financial
development. Financial development is not amenable to one-size-fits-all or a “template”
approach, not least because of its evolutionary, path-dependent nature, as noted above. A
good enabling environment is in effect the historical result of a complicated and rather
delicate combination of mutually reinforcing institutional innovations and market
dynamics—which cannot be transplanted at will from one country to another. Hence,
financial reforms that are partial, inadequately complemented, or wrongly sequenced may
lead to dysfunctional yet self-reinforcing institutional hybrids, which may be
subsequently hard to dislodge. Learning and re-learning will be needed along the way,
including through the cleansing aspects of financial crises and the pressures of
competition, in order to re-route the process of financial development.

Given these characteristics of the institutional reform process, considerable time


will elapse before most emerging economies can develop an adequate enabling

47
In general terms, first-generation reforms concern those taken as part of the initial wave of efforts to
regain macroeconomic stability while de-regulating the economy. In the financial sector, first-generation
reforms focused mainly on liberalizing the domestic financial market and on allowing freer cross-border
capital mobility. Second-generation reforms concern the subsequent wave of reforms that are, by and large,
much more intensive in institution building. In the financial sector, these entail, for instance, strengthening
prudential oversight and transparency, improving creditor rights systems, enhancing corporate governance
practices and minority shareholder protection, modernizing market infrastructures, etc.
48
As CGAP (2003a) emphasizes, while microfinance originally focused on working-capital loans to micro-
entrepreneurs, it has now expanded to include all sorts of financial services provided to low-income
individuals, including savings, credit, insurance, and money transfer services. See also Honohan (2004).
49
This rapid expansion may create some risks in the absence of prudent credit policies, as illustrated by the
case of Korea where a credit card lending boom, partially fuelled by tax incentives, led to significant losses
(see BIS, 2005a and The Economist, 2003).

23
environment and see any results in terms of broader access to credit. Even innovative
solutions like microfinance that, at least partially, help to overcome institutional
deficiencies are unlikely to broaden access significantly in the short term. 50 It seems
rather naive to expect governments to remain completely disengaged from any direct
intervention geared at broadening access during the long transition to a developed
financial system. For one, governments are likely to face increasing political pressures to
do something. As mentioned above, there is a growing disillusionment with the reform
process of the 1990s as reforms have failed to meet the (possibly excessive) initial
expectations. While it can be questioned whether this disillusionment is warranted or not,
reform fatigue is in any case likely to boost pressures for government intervention.
Second, in many countries governments are still so engaged in the financial system that a
quick withdrawal may not be possible. Existing public financial institutions have
institutional incentives to continue intervening in financial markets and in many cases
closing them or significantly downscaling their operations may not be politically feasible
or even desirable, given existing linkages among markets and institutional arrangements.
Finally, one could reasonably argue that certain government interventions may help to
smooth the transition towards a developed financial system or even speed it up, without
distracting from the long-run policy objective of institutional reform.

If one thinks in terms of non-conflicting long- and short-run policy objectives, it


is possible to rationalize some recent experiences of government intervention into a third,
middle ground view, which we denominate pro-market activism. We now turn to the
characterization of this view.

3.3 The Pro-Market Activism View

The pro-market activism view is an emerging new view that rationalizes a series
of recent government interventions. Given that this view is quite recent and just emerging
it is difficult to accurately characterize it. It may be easier to understand it by contrasting
it with the two well-established views described above. In contrast with the
interventionist view, the pro-market activism view does not assume that market failures
are widespread and that therefore direct government intervention in the allocation and
pricing of credit is necessary. Much to the contrary, this view argues that markets can and
do broaden access to finance and therefore the adequate role of the government is to
promote the development of deep and efficient financial markets, not to replace them.
This view recognizes that direct government interventions may be warranted in some
cases, but argues that careful analyses to identify market failures and specify their causes
should precede interventions. The observation that a certain group lacks access to credit
does not constitute by itself an indication of a market failure and therefore cannot justify
interventions in credit markets. Interventions should be directed at solving market failures
underlying problems of access, not at increasing the use of financial services per se. And
50
Despite its strong growth over the last years, microfinance penetration is still quite low in most countries.
For instance, Daley-Harris (2003) reports that the ratio of borrowing clients of microfinance institutions to
the total population exceeds two percent in only eight countries and in most developing countries this ratio
is below one percent.

24
even if a market failure is identified, public sector interventions can only be justified if
they can solve this failure in a cost-effective manner. According to the pro-market
activism view, government interventions should be designed to complement or facilitate
the development of financial markets through the adequate choice of instruments
(subsidies, funding, etc.) and institutions (private financial intermediaries, NGOs, public
banks). This view is well aware of the risks of government lending, and therefore favors a
wide range of instruments beyond lending. If subsidies are deemed necessary to solve a
specific market failure, they should be restricted to seed capital to launch a project or be
limited by sunset clauses and in all cases must be transparently budgeted to avoid the
price distortions that have characterized past government interventions in financial
markets.

In a sense, the pro-market activism view is closer to the laissez-faire view, as it


contends that the governments’ main focus should be to forge ahead with the task of
improving the enabling environment for financial markets. However, in contrast with that
view, it recognizes that there might be room for well-designed, restricted government
interventions to address specific market failures and help smooth the transition towards a
developed financial system or even speed it up. According to this view, it seems
unrealistic and possibly unwarranted in good logic for governments to solely focus on the
enabling environment and to remain completely disengaged from any direct intervention
to broaden access during the long transition to a developed financial system.

Thus, the main message of pro-market activism is that there is indeed a market
friendly role for the visible hand of the government to promote access in the short run,
while the fruits of ongoing institutional reform are still unripe. The important qualifier is,
however, that the government needs to be highly selective in its interventions, always
trying to ensure that they work with the market, never against it. Interventions should be
relatively small and temporary, being terminated when the underlying causes of the
problem of access have been removed. There must also be mechanisms in place to
prevent political capture that may undermine the temporary nature of the interventions or
their compatibility with the long-run objective of institutional reform and financial
market development. Pro-market activism, moreover, favors a policy strategy that
explicitly creates room for a process of discovery and learning-by-doing as the
interventions are implemented, and may be useful to give the authorities a first hand
understanding of what legislation or enforcement mechanisms are missing for certain
innovations to take off. For pro-market activism, the ultimate goal is to foster the
broadening of access in ways that simultaneously create financial markets where they are
missing or enhance the functioning of the existing ones.

The pro-market activism view seems to be part of an emerging new way of


thinking about development policies, based on the experience of the last decades. While
still very far from providing a coherent clearly articulated thinking on development
policies, this view tends to argue that, although a good enabling environment is a
necessary condition for sustainable long-term growth, it may not be enough to initiate the
development process and selective limited government interventions to address market
failures may be required. This view is presented, for instance, by Rodrik (2002) who
argues that “[t]he record suggests that an adequate growth programme needs to be

25
anchored in two strategies: an investment strategy designed to kick-start growth, and an
institution building strategy (…)” Similarly, Zagha (2004) argues that reviewing the
experience of the 1990s “confirms the importance for growth of fundamental principles:
macro-stability, market forces in the allocation of resources, and openness” and also
shows that “selective government interventions can contribute to growth when they
address market failures, when and where they are carried out effectively, and are subject
to institutional checks.” As mentioned above, this emerging view is still far from
providing clear guidelines on development policies. It is a more nuanced view that calls
for policy diversity, selective and modest reforms, and experimentation. In fact, its main
characteristic seems to be the recognition of the need to avoid one-size-fits all strategies
and to follow a more targeted approach taking into account country specificities. World
Bank (2005b), for instance, argues that “there is no unique set of rules (…) [W]e need to
get away from formulae and the search for elusive ‘best practices’ (…)” While a more
nuanced approach to development policies may be necessary, this view runs the risk of
degenerating into an “anything-goes” approach. The main challenge for this emerging
view is translating its recommendations into specific operational guidelines for promoting
development, without degenerating into a rigid blueprint.

The pro-market activism view, if warranted, must however recognize itself as a


solution for the short run. It must understand the idiosyncrasies of institutional
arrangements and market conditions in each country, and the specific ways in which
access problems arise in that context, not only because well-designed and efficient
institutions are the first-best solutions, but because guaranteeing that the eventual
interventions under pro-market activism do not conflict with the long-run objective of
institutional reform will crucially hinge on the quality and extent of such understanding.

For all of its potential appeal, pro-market activism raises many questions. Are
there actually cases where government interventions do not displace financial market
activity, but rather crowd it in? Can direct interventions indeed be designed so as to
ensure that at least no harm is done? If a given government intervention is efficient, in
the sense that it leads to greater, mutually beneficial financial contracting, why don’t
private financial intermediaries take the initiative? Is direct government intervention
necessary or, given the right incentives, private financial intermediaries would take the
initiative? While it is very difficult to provide a definite answer to these questions, we
will try to address them in the next section by analyzing how pro-market activism has
worked in a number of recent experiences in Latin America. It is necessary to stress that
we do not attempt to make a comprehensive assessment of these interventions or to claim
that they have been successful. Rather, we use them to illustrate how pro-market activism
has worked in practice and understand to what extent actual experiences have conformed
to the stylized description of this view presented so far. This analysis will also help us to
identify potential implementation problems, as well as pitfalls that must be avoided in the
design of pro-market interventions.

26
4. Recent Pro-Market Interventions in Latin America

This section describes a number of recent experiences from Latin America that
illustrate the approach of the pro-market activism view to government interventions. To
guide the discussion, we group these experiences in terms of the type of instrument used
in each case. However, most interventions are not as clear-cut in practice, as they tend to
combine several instruments. This bundling of different instruments is in most cases the
result of institutional design and incentives. An open question is whether these
components can be effectively unbundled. The classification by type of instrument is
used mainly for presentational purposes, to help depict the nature of the intervention
under analysis and highlight the relevant policy issues. Two additional caveats are
necessary before turning to the description of these experiences. In the first place, some
of the instruments used in these interventions are similar to those promoted by
proponents of the interventionist view (i.e., public lending, subsidies, and credit
guarantees). However, pro-market interventions tend to differ from previous ones in
important aspects of their design—especially regarding sustainability, time limits,
governance, and transparency—and even in terms of their objectives, as they seek to
complement and promote private financial intermediation, rather than replace it. Second,
we focus on extracting the main policy lessons from these interventions, rather than on
describing them in detail. Detailed descriptions of each experience are available in a
number of appendices and several papers.

4.1 Public Provision of Market Infrastructure

A traditional argument for government intervention in the banking sector is that


private banks may not find it profitable to open branches in rural and isolated areas, and
thus government intervention is necessary to provide financial services to residents of
those areas. Underlying this argument is the idea that access to financial services
generates positive externalities in terms of growth and/or poverty reduction (Burgess and
Pande, 2005). This led to the creation of public banks to serve rural areas and in many
cases also resulted in the establishment of regulations requiring banks to open branches in
certain regions. In India, for instance, the government imposed the so-called 1:4 license
rule in 1977. This rule stated that banks could open one branch in an already banked
location only if they opened four in unbanked locations.

An innovative approach to increase the availability of financial services in remote


areas has been adopted by the Brazilian government through the use of correspondent
banking arrangements (see Kumar et al., 2006). Correspondent banking refers to
arrangements whereby banks outsource services typically undertaken at branches, like
receiving loan applications, making deposits and withdrawals, and paying invoices, to
non-financial institutions with a significant network of outlets, such as convenience stores
and supermarkets. This process significantly reduces the cost of providing financial
services, enabling banks to reach areas where it might not be profitable to open branches.
One could question whether direct government intervention is needed to promote this

27
kind of arrangements, as they can (and do) take place among private parties. 51 However,
in many developing countries some of the largest networks of non-financial outlets are
owned or regulated by the public sector. Therefore, in order to achieve a wide geographic
coverage it is necessary for the government to allow financial institutions to use some of
these networks to distribute their services. In the case of Brazil, lottery houses have been
used by the federal savings bank Caixa Economica Federal (CEF) to distribute financial
services. The right to provide banking services through the post office was granted to
Banco Bradesco, the largest private bank in Brazil, through a public bidding process. The
use of correspondents significantly reduces the cost of servicing remote locations.
According to Kumar et al. (2006), initial investments for a correspondent outpost in
Brazil can be as low as 0.5 percent of those for a traditional bank branch, and operating
costs are negligible if existing employees and communication networks are used. This
has resulted in a significant geographic expansion in access to financial services. While in
2001 29 percent of the municipalities in Brazil had no bank services (branches or bank
service outposts), by 2004 all municipalities had access to these services, with 31 percent
of them being served exclusively by bank correspondents.

Another example of a government intervention designed to help reduce the costs


of providing financial services in unbanked areas for private financial intermediaries is
the Mexican development bank BANSEFI (Banco de Ahorro Nacional y Servicios
Financieros, National Savings and Financial Services Bank). 52,53 BANSEFI has the
mandate of spearheading the development of semi-formal and informal financial
institutions (called popular savings and credit institutions), including a variety of credit
unions, savings and credit associations, cooperatives, and NGOS that serve regions where
the presence of commercial banks is minimal or non-existent. 54 To this end, BANSEFI
performs two tasks. First, it administers a one-off government investment subsidy
(mostly financed by the World Bank) to help popular savings and credit institutions meet
the criteria of sustainability, prudent risk taking, and adequate risk pricing necessary to
become formal regulated financial intermediaries. BANSEFI provides these institutions
with technical assistance and training to upgrade their governance, transparency, and
management capacity to standards required for licensing. BANSEFI’s second task, which
we view as the most innovative component of its operations, is to provide centralized
back-office services like electronic transfers, liquidity management, clearing house

51
Even if direct government intervention is not necessary to promote correspondent banking, regulatory
changes in several areas, including the use of electronic payment systems, account opening requirements,
and agency relationships, may be required (CGAP, 2006). In the case of Brazil, for example, a number of
Central Bank resolutions between 1999 and 2000 were key in the development of correspondent banking,
by allowing correspondents to provide banking services, clarifying existing rules, and eliminating certain
restrictions (Kumar et al., 2006).
52
BANSEFI was established in 2001 to replace PANHAL (Patronato Nacional del Ahorro), a government-
owned narrow bank that focused exclusively on mobilizing savings by capturing deposits, mostly among
small rural clients, and investing these funds in government debt securities.
53
See Appendix 2, Coutinho (2006), and Taber (2005) for more detailed descriptions of BANSEFI’s
operations.
54
BANSEFI has a second, separate mandate to promote savings by acting as a narrow bank, which it
inherited from its predecessor, PANHAL. This second mandate may place it in competition with some of
the popular savings and credit institutions it is supposed to support, generating some conflicts of interest
(see CGAP, 2005a).

28
services, debit and credit card services, and foreign exchange and derivatives transactions
to the popular savings and credit institutions to allow them to capture economies of scale
and scope that they may not be able to achieve individually. In the case of liquidity
services, for instance, BANSEFI can consolidate the liquidity of all the participant
institutions and invest it on their behalf in the commercial banking system, securing a
higher rate of return than what the institutions could negotiate individually. BANSEFI is
developing a technological platform to allow the sector to operate effectively as a
network and to help institutions minimize operation and supervision costs. These
centralized services are offered at fee and can be voluntarily contracted by the
institutions. BANSEFI has also created a commercial alliance among several popular
savings and credit institutions (L@Red de la Gente, The People’s Network) to share
branches and facilitate the distribution of financial products. 55 This network uses a
common technological platform to distribute financial products, helping to generate
homogenous products that are offered under an umbrella trademark, significantly
reducing distribution and marketing costs. L@Red de la Gente is also used to distribute
several government programs and operates with traditional money transfer companies
that use its network to distribute remittances. This increases the revenues of member
institutions through distribution fees and helps to attract new customers and bring them
into the financial system.

The BANSEFI-led program has made substantial progress in meeting its


objectives, although there have been some delays in the process of upgrading and
converting the popular savings and credit institutions into regulated entities. As
mentioned above, government funding of BANSEFI was limited to the provision of seed
money to finance technical assistance to the popular savings and credit institutions and
build the technological platform to provide them with centralized services. BANSEFI
was established with a clear sunset clause, which states that it will be, at least partially,
sold to the popular savings and credit institutions once these institutions become formal
regulated entities. The result of this sale will be a clear indicator of whether BANSEFI
has actually added value by providing centralized services. The terms and procedures for
this sale are currently under analysis (BANSEFI, 2006) and many sector representatives
have expressed interest in taking part (CGAP, 2005a). See Appendix 2 for more details
on BANSEFI’s experience.

Another example of electronic infrastructure provided by the public sector to


reduce operational costs for financial intermediaries is the on-line market for factoring
services developed by the Mexican development bank NAFIN (Nacional Financiera).56
In many countries, small businesses find it difficult to finance their production cycle,
since they lack access to bank credit and most buyers usually take between 30 and 90
days to pay. After delivery, sellers issue an invoice, recorded as an account receivable by
the seller and an account payable by the buyer. Factoring is a type of financing in which
firms sell their accounts receivable at a discount (equal to interest plus service fees) to a
financial firm (called the factor) and receive immediate cash. Factoring is an asset sale,

55
This network is currently integrated by 68 institutions with a total of 1,170 branches, including 548
branches that BANSEFI inherited from PANHAL.
56
See Appendix 3, Naranjo (2005), and Klapper (2005) for detailed descriptions of this program.

29
not a loan. There is no debt repayment and no additional liabilities on the supplier’s
balance sheet. An alternative to ordinary factoring is reverse factoring. In this case, the
factor only purchases accounts receivable issued by certain buyers. Reverse factoring
reduces information problems, as the factor only needs to assess the credit worthiness of
a specific group of large firms. A significant advantage of factoring, especially in
developing countries, is that it does not require good collateral laws, just the legal ability
to sell, or assign, accounts receivables.

NAFIN, a Mexican development bank, created an online system, called Cadenas


Productivas (Productive Chains), to provide reverse factoring services to SMEs. This
program works by creating chains between “big buyers” and their suppliers. The buyers
that participate in the program, large credit-worthy firms, must invite suppliers to join
their chain. This reduces principal-agent problems by effectively outsourcing screening to
the buyers, who have an informational advantage relative to financial intermediaries. All
transactions are carried out on an electronic platform, reducing transaction costs,
increasing speed, and improving security. Once a supplier delivers goods to the buyer and
issues an invoice, the buyer posts an online “negotiable document” equal to the amount
that will be factored on its NAFIN webpage. Participant financial institutions that are
willing to factor this particular receivable post their interest rate quotes for this
transaction. Finally, the supplier can access this information and choose the best quote.
Once the factor is chosen, the discounted amount is transferred to the supplier’s bank
account. The factor is paid directly by the buyer when the invoice is due.

NAFIN was responsible for the development, production, and marketing costs
related to the electronic platform. It operates the system and also handles all the legal
work. NAFIN requires all participating financial institutions to use its second-tier funding
to provide credit through the system. 57 In fact, NAFIN does not charge a fee for the
factoring services, but rather covers its costs with the interest it charges on its loans.
NAFIN’s factoring program has been very successful, extending over nine billion U.S.
dollars in financing since its inception in September 2001 and brokering more than 1.2
million transactions, 98 percent by SMEs. More than half of NAFIN’s second-tier
lending in 2004 corresponded to the financing of factoring transactions originated from
this program. NAFIN has entered into agreements with development banks in several
Latin American countries, including Colombia, El Salvador, and Venezuela, to
implement similar programs and development banks in other countries in the region are
considering replicating this program. See Appendix 3 for more details on NAFIN’s
reverse factoring program.

4.2 Structured Finance

Structured finance can be defined as a form of financial intermediation based


upon securitization technology. 58 In its simplest form, it is a process where assets are
pooled and transferred to a third party (commonly referred to as special purpose vehicle
57
As discussed in Appendix 3, this seems to be the result of institutional incentives as NAFIN is a second-
tier bank that is evaluated on the basis of its volume of loan disbursements.
58
Accurately defining structured finance is quite difficult, as even among market participants there is no
agreement on exactly what it encompasses. See Davis (2005) for a survey of alternative definitions.

30
or SPV), which in turn issues securities backed by this asset pool. Typically, several
classes of securities (called tranches) with distinct risk-return profiles are issued. 59
Innovations abound in this market and several types of assets have been included in the
collateral pool, ranging from cash instruments (e.g., mortgages, loans, bonds, credit card
receivables) to synthetic exposures (e.g., credit default swaps). The structured finance
market in developed countries has experienced significant growth over the last years (see
BIS, 2005b). In the case of developing countries, although the volume of transactions
has also increased significantly, structured finance markets are still small and
underdeveloped. 60

Structured finance transactions involve a number of different participants. These


typically include: the originator, who originates the underlying assets in the course of its
regular business activities or purchases them in the market; the arranger, who sets up the
structure and markets the securities; the servicer, who collects payments and tracks the
performance of the asset pool; the trustee, who oversees cash distributions to investors
and monitors compliance with deal documentation; and, in some deals, financial
guarantors, who provide guarantees for certain tranches.

FIRA (Fideicomisos Instituidos en Relación con la Agricultura, Agricultural


Related Trust Funds), a Mexican development-oriented financial institution that provides
second-tier funding to the agricultural sector, has recently promoted several structured
finance transactions. 61 One of these transactions was designed to provide working capital
financing to shrimp producers in collaboration with a large shrimp distributor called
Ocean Garden. 62 The general structure can be summarized as follows. Shrimp producers
sign supply contracts with Ocean Garden to deliver a certain amount of shrimp at a future
date. Ocean Garden pays them a portion of these contracts in advance to provide them
with working capital financing and subsequently transfers these credit rights to an SPV,
which sells participations to investors. Ocean Garden not only acts as originator but also
as servicer, being responsible for transferring payments to the trust fund once the
producers deliver their production. To help align the incentives of the different industry
participants and reduce adverse selection problems, shrimp producers, shrimp feed
suppliers, and Ocean Garden provide liquid guarantees to cover the first credit losses.
Shrimp producers and feed suppliers provide guarantees that cover the credit losses of
each individual working capital loan up to 24 percent, whereas Ocean Garden provides a
general guarantee that covers up to 25 percent of the total asset pool. Once these
guarantees are exhausted, investors start facing credit losses. 63 FIRA not only acts as an

59
Some authors (see, for example, Alles, 2001, and BIS, 2005b) differentiate between securitization (which
only involves the pooling and transfer of assets to a third party and subsequent issuance of securities) and
structured financing (which also involves the creation of different classes of securities). In keeping with
common usage, we use the term structured finance to refer to both types of instruments.
60
See Meddin (2004) for an overview of structured finance in emerging markets and the role it may play in
fostering capital market development.
61
See Appendix 4 for a more detailed description of FIRA’s structured finance operations.
62
Ocean Garden is one of the main exporters of Mexican shrimp to the U.S. It handles approximately one
quarter of Mexico’s shrimp production and has annual sales of about 250 million U.S. dollars. The firm
was owned by the Mexican government and was recently privatized.
63
This happens when credit losses exceed approximately 32 percent of the total asset pool, see Appendix 4
for details.

31
arranger in this transaction, but also as a financial guarantor providing guarantees to
partially cover credit losses once the liquid guarantees from industry participants are
exhausted. FIRA charges a fee for its services as arranger and also for the provision of
the guarantees. FIRA requires all investors participating in this scheme, which are
financial institutions, to use its second tier lending to purchase the securities issued by the
SPV.

This structured finance transaction helps to solve principal-agent problems by


outsourcing the screening of small producers to a large commercial firm that has an
informational advantage relative to financial intermediaries. A significant problem in this
type of transaction is that the originator may have incentives to include lower quality
assets in the pool. Anticipating this possibility, investors who have less information about
the quality of the assets may not be willing to invest or may ask for a premium to
compensate them. In this particular transaction, the adverse selection problem is
ameliorated by the fact that, since Ocean Garden signs supply agreements with the
producers, it depends on the fulfillment of these agreements for its future sales and
therefore has incentives to adequately screen and monitor producers. The adverse
selection problem is further reduced by the fact that Ocean Garden provides guarantees to
cover the initial credit losses. The pooling of working capital loans to several producers
reduces transaction costs and also helps financial institutions to diversify their risk
exposure, as they do not face the idiosyncratic risk of an individual producer.
Also, financial institutions do not face Ocean Garden’s credit risk, as the supply contracts
are removed from its balance sheet and their ownership is transferred to the SPV. This
means that if Ocean Garden files for bankruptcy, the assets in the pool do not come under
court jurisdiction. FIRA has been successful in using similar structured finance
transactions to improve access to credit in several sectors (including wheat, corn, and
sorghum production) by using large commercial firms as originators and the loans
provided through this type of transactions now account for 5 percent of its total portfolio.
See Appendix 4 for more details on FIRA’s experience with structured finance.

4.3 Credit Guarantee Systems

Credit guarantee systems are mechanisms in which a third party, the guarantor,
pledges to guarantee loans to a particular group of borrowers. Credit guarantee systems
reduce the lender’s expected credit losses—even if the probability of default remains
unchanged—acting as a form of insurance against default. Public credit guarantee
systems are widespread: according to a survey conducted by Graham Bannock and
Partners, in 1995 there were at least 85 countries with some type of government credit
guarantee program. 64 The largest and more established guarantee schemes are mostly in
developed countries, including Canada, Japan, the U.S., and several European countries.
The general experience with credit guarantee systems, especially in developing countries,
has been poor to mixed, at best: most systems have depleted their reserves due to high

64
Graham Bannock and Partners (1997) find that in 14 countries there is no public credit guarantee system
and in another 76 countries it is not possible to tell whether operating guarantee schemes exist. See also
Herrero Calvo and Pombo Gonzalez (2001) for an overview of public credit guarantee systems around the
world.

32
credit losses and bad investment decisions and in many cases they have been designed to
channel funds to certain sectors without due regard to loss rates.

There is significant debate in the literature regarding the role fulfilled by credit
guarantees and the need for this type of government intervention (see for example, Green,
2003; Holden, 1997; Levitsky, 1997a; Rodriguez Meza, 2004; and Vogel and Adams,
1997). The most frequent cited justification for credit guarantee schemes is as a substitute
for collateral where the collateral market operates imperfectly due to cumbersome and
costly repossession processes, political difficulties in the realization of assets pledged by
certain sectors, or uncertainty about the value of collateral, which lead to excessive
collateral requirements. 65 However, one could reasonably argue that imperfections in the
legal system should be addressed through improvements in collateral laws and
enforcement mechanisms, rather than through direct government intervention (Holden,
1997; Vogel and Adams, 1997). Nevertheless, both strategies are not necessarily
exclusive, at least in the short-term (Graham Bannock and Partners, 1997), and therefore
collateral guarantee systems could help to reduce problems of access to finance while
institutional reform is taking time to mature. 66 An alternative argument contends that
credit guarantee systems work as subsidies to cover the costs of learning how to provide
loans to a new group of borrowers by financial intermediaries. However, as Vogel and
Adams (1997) point out, there is no evidence of public programs that have been able to
eliminate guarantees after a certain period. Critics of public credit guarantee systems also
argue that these schemes cannot decrease asymmetric information problems in credit
markets, and are even likely to increase them. Public guarantee systems may increase
moral hazard for both borrowers and lenders: borrowers that know that their loans are
guaranteed by the government may not feel obligated to repay them and lenders may
have fewer incentives for screening and monitoring borrowers, as guarantees cover their
credit losses. An open question therefore is whether credit guarantee systems can be
designed in a market-friendly way, minimizing their unintended consequences while at
the same time promoting private financial market activity. 67

FOGAPE (Fondo de Garantia para Pequeños Empresarios), a state fund designed


to provide partial credit guarantees to loans issued by commercial banks to small firms in
Chile, has been considered a success story in terms of fostering market activity while
minimizing the problems that have characterized previous guarantee schemes
(Benavente, Galetovic, and Sanhueza, 2006 and Bennett, Billington, and Doran, 2005).
FOGAPE was created in 1980 but remained relatively inactive until 1999, when the
Chilean government decided to reformulate the program. The fund is administered by

65
Public credit guarantee systems have also been justified in terms of market failures, although the nature
of these failures is usually not identified (Vogel and Adams, 1997). And even if a market failure is
identified, it is not clear whether credit guarantee schemes are the best form of addressing it. One possible
market failure could be the absence of credit insurance markets (Rodriguez Meza, 2004).
66
Benavente, Galetovic, and Sanhueza (2006) develop a theoretical model showing that under certain
conditions, credit guarantee systems can improve access to credit for borrowers with viable projects that
would otherwise be excluded due to lack of collateral, without increasing moral hazard.
67
See Levitsky (1997b) for a review of best practices in operating guarantee schemes. Bennett, Billington,
and Doran (2005) analyze some recent successful experiences of credit guarantee systems in developing
countries.

33
Banco Estado, a public commercial bank, which charges a fee for its services. FOGAPE
functions as a classical guarantee fund, sharing the risk of default on eligible loans and
charging a guarantee premium. The commercial relationship is between FOGAPE and the
banks. Banks select those loans that the wish guaranteed and FOGAPE only checks
whether they meet eligibility criteria. 68 According to Benavente, Galetovic, and Sanhueza
(2006), several features of FOGAPE’s operations have been key in reducing moral
hazard problems. First, commercial banks share part of the risk of default, as guarantees
only cover between 70 and 80 percent of credit losses. Second, and more important, to
allocate the available guarantees Banco Estado conducts auctions four to six times per
year among participating banks. Each bank has to submit a bid indicating the amount of
guarantee it wants to receive and the maximum coverage rate as a percentage of lending.
The bids are selected by the lowest coverage required until the total amount auctioned has
been assigned; therefore the biding process determines how the risks are shared among
FOGAPE and financial intermediaries. 69 Banks with high default rates on previously
guaranteed loans can be permanently or temporarily excluded from participating in the
bidding process (this has already happened in one case). This helps to reduce moral
hazard, as banks that reduce screening and monitoring today lose profitable opportunities
in the future. Also, the use of a bidding process increases competition among financial
institutions. The risk share taken by commercial banks has increased from 21 percent in
2001 to 29 percent in 2003 (Bennett, Billington, and Doran, 2005). Third, the amount of
FOGAPE guarantees each bank can obtain is limited: no bank can be awarded more than
two thirds of the total rights auctioned. This also helps to reduce moral hazard, as the
amount that can be gained by reducing screening and monitoring today is reduced.
Following the bidding process, banks have three months to grant the corresponding loans.

FOGAPE used to charge a fixed commission of 1 percent of the credit guaranteed,


but since June 2004 has increased it to a range between 1 and 2 percent, depending on the
claims performance of each bank. Default rates on loans guaranteed by FOGAPE have
been relatively low, standing at 1.05 percent in the second semester of 2005, suggesting
that the provision of its guarantees has not resulted in lower screening and monitoring by
banks. 70 FOGAPE is designed to be a sustainable fund, in the sense that fees and other
income, such as returns on investment, should cover all administrative costs and claims.
Government support should be restricted to the provision of start-up capital. Benavente,
Galetovic, and Sanhueza (2006) show that fees charged have been roughly equal to
guarantees paid and that the fund seems to be operating on a break-even basis with
revenues typically matching expenses. However, it is still an open question whether
FOGAPE can be sustainable in the long-run, as there is little evidence than credit
guarantee systems can achieve sustainability, even in developed countries. 71

68
The main eligibility criteria are related to borrower and loan size. Also, total exposure of the guarantee
fund to each borrower through loans from all banks is limited to UF 5,000 (approximately 120,000 U.S.
dollars).
69
FOGAPE establishes maximum guarantee coverages of 80 and 70 percent for long- and short-term loans,
respectively.
70
In comparison, default rates for the banking system as a whole stood at 1.01 percent.
71
Graham Bannock and Partners (1997) claim that in practice no government credit guarantee scheme has
been found to be able to cover administrative costs and default claims with fees collected. There is some

34
4.4 Transaction Cost Subsidies

Access to credit by small borrowers, especially in developing countries, has


usually been hindered by many difficulties, including lack of usable collateral, no credit
histories, and no reliable records. Also, small borrowers usually seek to borrow small
amounts, making the transaction costs of lending per unit too high. In developing
countries these problems are compounded by deficiencies in institutions and market
infrastructure that make it more expensive to gather information, value assets
appropriately, and monitor and enforce contracts. As a result, small borrowers are usually
excluded from the formal financial system. To address this problem, governments in most
countries have provided loans to small producers, either through public banks or by using
directed credit programs, at subsidized rates. As described above, interest rates subsidies
have resulted in significant fiscal costs and have failed to improve access to finance.
These subsidies just aim at increasing credit use, but do not address any of the underlying
causes of access problems. Theory advocates that subsidies, if granted, should be targeted
directly at the source of the distortion; otherwise, they create additional distortions that
may lead to a worse outcome in equilibrium. In fact, interest rate subsidies have led to
significant price distortions in financial markets associated with pervasive general-
equilibrium implications.

An open question is whether subsidies can help to solve problems of access in a


market-friendly way, that is, by fostering private financial intermediation without
increasing distortions. In Mexico, the development agency FIRA has introduced a
program called SIEBAN (Sistema de Estímulos a la Banca) to provide subsidies to cover
the administrative and screening costs of serving small borrowers. This subsidy covers
low-income rural producers that access credit from commercial banks, credit unions, or
financial firms for the first time. The subsidy is a fixed amount that varies with the size of
the loan, representing a maximum of 16.7 percent of the amount borrowed in the case of
smaller loans, consistent with the idea of covering costs that tend to be relatively fixed.
SIEBAN subsidies are portable by borrower (i.e., they can be used to obtain credit from
different financial institutions), fostering competition. Financial institutions are required
to provide borrower information to the credit bureau in order to help them establish credit
histories. The subsidy decreases over time and has a duration of three years. The
temporary nature of the subsidy is based on the fact that once borrowers have been able
to establish credit histories screening costs for financial institutions should be
significantly lower, eliminating the need for subsidization.

The provision of a subsidy like SIEBAN could be justified on the basis of one of
the arguments mentioned above for the creation of public credit guarantee systems, that
is, subsidizing the costs for financial institutions of learning how to provide loans to a
new group, in this case low-income rural borrowers. However, SIEBAN has several
design features that address the limitations of credit guarantees in achieving this
objective. First, as Vogel and Adams (1997) point out, there is no evidence of public

debate on this issue as Riding (1997), for instance, argues that the Canadian Small Business Loan Act , the
Small Business Administration in the U.S., and the Loan Guarantee Scheme in the U.K. operate, in some
cases, on a break-even basis.

35
guarantee programs that have been able to eliminate guarantees after a certain period. In
contrast, SIEBAN is designed to be temporary: after three years borrowers no longer
receive any subsidy. Second, SIEBAN does not generate moral hazard. As discussed
above, credit guarantee systems reduce incentives for financial institutions to screen and
monitor borrowers, as the guarantee covers part of their credit losses. In the case of
SIEBAN, there is no risk shifting to the public sector Financial intermediaries only
receive a (relatively small) fixed initial subsidy and have incentives to adequately assess
borrowers’ credit quality, since they face all the costs in case of default. Another
important feature of SIEBAN is that it requires financial intermediaries to register
borrowers in the credit bureau, consistent with the idea of reducing the information
asymmetries that typically characterize small borrowers. An open question, however, is
how effective SIEBAN has actually been in improving access to credit and whether small
borrowers continue to receive credit once the subsidy ends. Also, the program is provided
by FIRA, which finances it with the profits from other operations. To increase
transparency, subsidies should be explicitly budgeted and separate from the provision of
financial services.

4.5 Public Lending

As described above, the general experience with the provision of credit by public
banks has been negative, resulting in high subsidies, recurring fiscal drains, and retarding,
rather than fostering, financial market development. Major incentive and governance
problems in the operation of public banks have tended to surface, leading to poor loan
origination and even poorer loan collection, wasteful administrative expenditures,
overstaffing, plain corruption, and political manipulation of lending. An open question is
whether there is any role for the provision of public credit in fostering financial
development and if this type of intervention can be designed in a way that ensures that at
least no harm is done.

Yaron, Benjamin, and Charitonenko (1998) argue that some experiences from
Asia, such as the Village Bank program of the Bank Rayat Indonesia, show that public
institutions can provide credit to rural producers in an efficient, market-friendly way and
that subsidies are not necessary for the provision of financial services to these producers.
They highlight the role of several mechanisms in increasing efficiency, such as shifting
from disbursing credit to motivating loan recovery, establishing a hard budget constraint,
increasing management autonomy, introducing innovative systems for both clients and
employees to encourage repayment, and increasing staff accountability.

The microfinance lending operation implemented by Banco Estado, a public


commercial bank from Chile, has also been considered a successful experience of
provision of credit by a public financial institution (Benavente, 2006). Banco Estado
decided to start lending to micro entrepreneurs in 1996 in order to foster the development
of the Chilean microfinance market. At the time, no commercial bank was participating
in this market and Banco Estado wanted to generate a demonstration effect. As discussed
above, financial innovation in many cases can be hampered by the fact that once a new
lending technology is introduced and proves to be successful, others can easily adopt it.
Therefore, there is little incentive for lenders to invest in new credit technologies. In this

36
situation, as Besley (1994) argues, there might be a role for the government to subsidize
innovation. A key factor for the success of Banco Estado’s microfinance program has
been the implementation of a new organizational structure tailored to meet the needs of
micro entrepreneurs. Banco Estado also established new incentive systems for
employees. An important change in this respect has been the increase in the fixed portion
of the remuneration of account executives, in order to reduce incentives to focus solely
on loan disbursement. Banco Estado’s microfinance operations are managed by a
separate business unit with its own profit and loss statement. The program was designed
to be self-sustainable, without providing any subsidies. In fact, this program achieved
break-even by the third year of operations and has remained profitable since then.

Banco Estado’s microfinance program seems to have been successful in terms of


fostering innovation, as three commercial banks have now entered the microfinance
market. The program has also had a positive impact on the micro entrepreneurs that have
access its funds, helping their firms to expand, increasing formality, and improving
business practices (Benavente, 2006).

5. Final Remarks

One of the objectives of this study was to once more call the attention of
policymakers, development institutions, and academics alike to the fact that there are
many problems of access to credit in developing countries, generated by the difficulties
of solving principal-agent problems and reducing transaction costs in weak institutional
environments. As a result, the penetration of formal credit in most developing countries is
low and banks are disengaged from many economic activities.

Given the major potential benefits of access-enhancing financial development, a


relevant question is whether government intervention to foster financial development and
broaden access is necessary and, if so, what form should this intervention take. As we
discuss, answers to this question tend to be polarized in two highly contrasting but well-
established views: the interventionist and the laissez-faire views. We describe a number
of recent experiences in Latin America that illustrate an emerging third view in this
regard, which we denominate pro-market activism. This exercise shows that there are
now several institutions in this region that seem to be moving in the direction of pro-
market interventions, but little is still known about their activities. It is difficult yet to
evaluate the results of these interventions. We do not attempt to undertake a
comprehensive assessment of these interventions or to claim that they have been
successful. Rather, we use them to illustrate how pro-market activism has worked in
practice. The analysis of these experiences raises a number of questions that deserve
further study and that are key to understanding whether the pro-market activism view can
constitute a viable alternative to broaden access to finance in developing countries.

First, an open question is whether idiosyncratic experiences can lead to more


general policy guidelines. We believe that the experiences analyzed show that the
government can play a role in broadening access to finance through restricted self-

37
sustainable interventions that aim to foster market activity, not replace it. However, one
could reasonably question to what extent these experiences are the consequence of a
specific institutional environment that favors government innovation and reduces the risk
of political capture. Also, these interventions may be a result of certain characteristics of
the public financial institutions that have implemented them, such as their management
quality. A better understanding of these issues is key to determining to what extent these
experiences can be replicated in other countries. As we have emphasized throughout this
study, financial development is intrinsically linked to the institutional environment and
therefore, government interventions that work under a given institutional matrix and at a
given stage of financial development may produce unintended effects when transplanted
to another institutional milieu. This suggests that interventions should be modified to take
into account the idiosyncrasies of the institutional arrangements and market conditions in
each country. A related question is whether, even if experiences can be replicated with
some adjustments to local conditions, the government should try to create organizational
capabilities to implement pro-market interventions where these capabilities do not exist.

Second, the analysis of the experiences suggests that it might be necessary to


rethink some institutional features of development-oriented financial institutions to
ensure that pro-market interventions succeed in fostering private financial intermediation
and broadening access. In the first place, the move to pro-market interventions may
require public financial institutions to separate subsidies from financing and to start
functioning more as development agencies than financial intermediaries. Restricting
government financial support to the provision of an initial endowment may help to reduce
the distortions created by interventions, by forcing development institutions to provide
their services at market prices—or at least at cost—in order to remain sustainable. Also,
limiting the ability of these institutions to assume financial liabilities, including by taking
deposits, may limit the potential fiscal costs of their interventions. Second, the mandate
of institutions implementing pro-market interventions may need to be redefined in
dynamic terms, not statically. This would provide incentives for these institutions to
move on to new activities once the market they were promoting becomes self-sustainable.
However, this might not be easily achieved, as public institutions may try to protect their
franchise value by continuing to operate profitable and successful programs, even when
public intervention is no longer necessary. This problem could be ameliorated by
establishing separate business units, with their own profit and loss statements, to
implement new interventions and by creating clear sunset clauses when launching a new
program. Third, the management of these institutions should be devoid from political
influence. The negative experiences with public banks in developing countries illustrate
the high costs of political interference. Guaranteeing that public financial institutions are
managed in an independent and professional manner seems to be a key factor for the
success of pro-market interventions. Finally, the advent of a new approach to government
intervention in financial markets may require new ways of evaluating the performance of
development-oriented financial institutions. Most of the programs analyzed were
implemented by first or second-tier public (development) banks that are evaluated on the
basis of traditional performance indicators, such as the volume of loan disbursements or
the amount of guarantees provided. These evaluation criteria generate incentives that
could be inconsistent with the implementation of interventions that foster private market
development. Evaluations based on credit growth, for instance, force development

38
institutions to combine more innovative market friendly interventions with the provision
of loans, even if liquidity is not a constraint for private financial intermediaries. The
bundling of more innovative instruments with traditional ones— such as second-tier
lending, guarantees, and subsidies—motivated by the use of traditional performance
indicators, makes it very difficult to analyze the individual merits of each instrument.
Bundling also carries the risk of distorting prices and incentives. Fostering the
proliferation of new market friendly instruments may require basing the evaluation of
development-oriented financial institutions on a new set of indicators, including measures
of the increase in financial activity generated by their interventions and indicators of their
impact on economic activity and the socio-economic environment of the targeted
population. These new indicators may be more difficult to design and estimate than
traditional ones, and it may take time and a process of trial and error to find the correct
indicators to evaluate each type of intervention.

Third, further research is needed to understand how to minimize the unintended


consequences of pro-market interventions. First, the focus on short term-interventions
may distract governments from the hard work of improving the enabling environment for
financial markets, which is the first best according to the pro-market activism view.
Institutional reforms may take a long time to yield visible results in terms of access and
the possibility of obtaining some short-term results through pro-market interventions may
reduce government incentives to forge ahead with reform efforts and may even divert
resources away from those efforts. Although the pro-market activism view argues that
institutional efficiency is the economy’s first best and considers direct government
interventions as a complement, not a substitute, for institutional reform, it is not clear that
the actual implementation of its proposals will not result in the diversion of government
efforts away from achieving the economy’s first best. Second, given the existence of path
dependence in the evolution of financial markets, the implementation of second-best
solutions like those proposed by the pro-market activism view may lead to inefficient
equilibriums. Direct government interventions, even if designed in a market friendly way,
may lead to dysfunctional yet self-reinforcing institutional hybrids, which may be
subsequently very hard to dislodge. Finally, the creation of vested interests entailed in
any direct government intervention raises tricky political economy issues. Even if
interventions are designed to be time-bound and financial support is restricted to the
provision of seed capital, the government may face pressures to provide additional funds
in the future or might be tempted to prop up programs or institutions with more favorable
access to subsidies or public funds. This is one of the main challenges faced by pro-
market interventions. A number of instruments can be used to mitigate this risk. For
example, the government could create sunset clauses by law with clear indicators of when
the public sector should end its participation, or even fixed time limits, which raise the
institutional costs of extending or propping up interventions. Of course, these types of
clauses also reduce flexibility, but this may be a small cost to pay to avoid the recurrent
fiscal drains that have characterized past public interventions in financial markets. The
participation of multilateral organizations may also help to ameliorate political risks.
However, in those cases where institutional incentives cannot be designed to effectively
reduce this risk, the government should refrain from intervening.

39
Fourth, an open question is whether there is a need for pro-market interventions in
the long run. As discussed throughout this study, the economy’s first best is achieving a
good enabling environment that allows financial markets to flourish. In this context, pro-
market interventions are seen as short-term solutions to broaden access while institutional
reforms are taking time to mature and may even help to speed up the process. However, it
is not clear whether once a good enabling environment is achieved there is a need for
direct government interventions. If there are long-term market failures that even in a good
contractual environment cannot be dealt with by private parties, there could be a role for
pro-market interventions in the long run. The widespread intervention of the public sector
in financial markets in developed countries suggests that this could be the case. However,
one could question to what extent the persistence of these interventions is the result of
political capture and self-reinforcing institutional arrangements that make it very difficult
to dismantle them, even if they are no longer useful for fostering financial market
development. Further research is needed to clarify this issue.

Finally, the experiences of pro-market intervention described raise the question of


why, if a certain activity is profitable, the private sector does not take the initiative. As
discussed, in some cases innovation in financial markets may be hindered by the fact that
once a new lending technology is introduced and proves to be successful, others can
easily adopt it. Therefore, there is little incentive to invest in new credit technologies and
there might be a role for the government to subsidize innovation. However, even if some
type of government support is necessary, it is not clear that this should result in a direct
intervention by a public institution, as the government could subsidize innovation by
private financial intermediaries. This also suggests that the government should exit the
operation of innovative programs once the market they were promoting becomes self-
sustainable. An open question in this regard is whether direct government intervention is
necessary at all or if, given the right incentives, the private sector would take the
initiative. Further research is necessary to answer these questions, but they suggest that
there is an important role for collaboration between the private and public sectors in
fostering financial development and broadening access.

40
Appendix 1

An Overview of Microfinance

Microfinance consists in the provision of financial services to low-income


individuals and informal businesses. As CGAP (2003a) emphasizes, while microfinance
originally focused on providing working-capital loans to micro-entrepreneurs through the
use of collateral substitutes, it has now expanded to include all sorts of financial services,
including credit, insurance, savings, and money transfer services.

Access to credit by low-income borrowers, especially in developing countries, has


usually been hindered by many difficulties, including lack of usable collateral, no credit
histories, and no reliable records. Also, low-income borrowers usually seek to borrow
small amounts, making the cost of lending per-unit too high. To overcome these
obstacles, microfinance institutions developed a series of innovative lending techniques.
A much studied mechanism (see, for example, Armendariz de Aghion, 1999b; Besley and
Coate, 1995; Ghatak and Guinnane, 1999; and Morduch, 1999) is group lending, in
which lenders group themselves to apply for loans. Loans are made to individual
members of the group, but the group as a whole is held jointly liable for repayment. This
reduces screening and monitoring costs for the creditor, as risky borrowers are excluded
from the group and group members have strong incentives to monitor each borrower,
with social sanctions among members replacing (weak) legal sanctions. Microfinance
institutions also try to ameliorate the problems caused by asymmetric information
through the use of dynamic incentives such as progressive lending, which involves
increasing loan disbursements gradually over time, so that failure to repay an earlier loan
causes borrowers to lose access to larger loans in the future. Another mechanism is the
use of frequent repayment schedules, to help establish the creditworthiness of the
borrower and reduce the possibilities for diversion. Technological advances, especially
those related to scoring methods, and the availability of debtor information have also
played an important role in the expansion of the microfinance industry by significantly
reducing screening costs. 72

As microfinance has evolved, there has been an increasing flexibility in the use of
techniques, with business models and lending technologies now differing widely across
countries and even across microfinance institutions within a given country. This is partly
the result of the still experimental nature of microfinance and also reflects the need to
adapt to local conditions. As the practices of microfinance institutions have changed,
their lending techniques have become increasingly similar to those of mainstream
financial institutions (Honohan, 2004).

Microfinance was initially developed and is today still primarily deployed by


nongovernmental organizations (NGOs), with most of the funding coming from
multilateral development agencies and, to a lesser extent, private charities and local

72
See, for example, Hardy, Holden, and Prokopenko (2002) for a description of how the availability of
debtor information systems combined with scoring technologies has allowed Banco del Trabajo in Peru to
become a commercially-viable microfinance institution. CGAP (2003b) presents an overview of how
scoring works and its application to microfinance.

41
governments (Hardy, Holden, and Prokopenko, 2002). However, there has been an
increasing trend towards microfinance operations becoming self-sustainable and
commercially viable. Between 1992 and March 2003, 39 NGOs in 15 countries have
transformed into full-fledged banks, while another 200 have become supervised non-bank
financial institutions, either permanently or as an interim step towards becoming a bank
(Krebsbach, 2003). Some of these microfinance institutions have even been able to
successfully issue bonds in local capital markets (Jansson, 2002). Also, several
commercial banks have started to enter the microfinance market, either by providing
financial services directly to low-income customers or acting through existing
microfinance institutions (see, for example, CGAP, 2005b; Littlefield and Rosenborg,
2004; and The Economist, 2005). These trends have been particularly pronounced in
Latin America, where by 2001 commercial banks provided around 29 percent of
financing to micro enterprises, while NGOs that became licensed financial institutions,
together with other non-bank licensed financial intermediaries, provided an additional 45
percent (CGAP, 2001). 73

Despite its strong growth over the last years, microfinance penetration is still
quite low in most countries. For instance, Daley-Harris (2003) reports that the ratio of
borrowing clients of microfinance institutions to the total population exceeds 2 percent in
only eight countries and in most countries (35 out of a total of 55 developing countries
covered by the study) this ratio is below 1 percent. CGAP (2004) analyzes the penetration
of all institutions that focus on expanding financial services to the poor, including not
only microfinance institutions, but also postal savings banks, financial cooperatives, rural
banks, and development banks. Its results indicate that the number of savings and loan
accounts in these institutions as a percentage of the total population reaches 4 percent in
Africa, 5 percent in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, and 3 percent in Latin America.
Coverage is much higher in East and South Asia, reaching 17 percent of the population.

73
In 2001 the microfinance industry in Latin America served approximately 1.5 to two million clients and
had a total loan portfolio of about 1.5 billion U.S. dollars. There were 97 specialized regulated financial
institutions operating in this segment, most of which were created through the transformation of NGOs,
with a combined portfolio of 914 million U.S. dollars (Jansson, 2002).

42
Appendix 2

BANSEFI’s Experience

1. Introduction

Access to financial services in Mexico is very limited. World Bank (2003b), for
instance, estimates that three quarters of the adult population of Mexico City has no bank
account or any dealings with a financial institution. In the case of rural areas, access to
financial services is even more reduced, with only 6 percent of households using formal
financial savings instruments and less than 3 percent having access to credit from a
financial institution (World Bank, 2001). Bank density rates are low, with a country-wide
average of one branch per 12,000 people. Around 74 percent of municipalities,
representing 22 percent of the population, have no bank branch (World Bank, 2004b).

Lower income households, especially in rural areas, rely on a wide variety of


loosely regulated or unregulated financial institutions (called popular savings and credit
institutions)—including credit unions, savings and credit associations, cooperatives, and
NGOS—for the provision of financial services. As of June 2001, this sector was
comprised of about 618 institutions serving approximately 2.3 million people (around 7
percent of the economically active population) with total assets of more than 1.4 billion
U.S. dollars (about 1 percent of banking sector assets).74 The lack of effective regulation
and supervision has meant that these institutions and their depositors are exposed to
significant risks, constraining the sector’s development. Also, most of these institutions
are small, community-based organizations, with limited product offering, no links to the
national payment system, and low efficiency levels.

The Mexican government tried to increase access to financial services in rural


areas by providing these services through several development-oriented financial
institutions and trust funds. These interventions created large fiscal outlays and failed to
achieve a significant increase in access to finance. The total cost of government
intervention in the rural financial system in Mexico during the 1983-1992 period has
been estimated at approximately 28.5 billion U.S. dollars, 80 percent of which is
associated with interest rate subsidies. The annual average of these costs represents about
13 percent of agricultural GDP (Brizzi, 2001). The government started to reform rural
credit policies in the early 1990s to increase the efficiency of public rural finance
institutions and reduce their fiscal costs. It made transfers to these institutions more
transparent, reorganized inefficient entities, and reduced subsidies.

Between 1996 and 1999 the Mexican government tried to encourage commercial
banks to extend their presence in rural areas by subsidizing the costs of opening and
operating new branches. However, this project failed to induce a significant expansion of
branch networks, partly as a result of the consequences of the 1994-1995 financial crisis,
but also due to the availability of alternative profitable opportunities for commercial
banks. Also, opening new branches in rural areas represented a significant investment in

74
See Table 2.1.

43
new infrastructure and staff for commercial banks and required them to develop
knowledge on rural economic activities.

The failure of these attempts to increase access to financial services in rural areas
led the Mexican government to focus on strengthening popular savings and credit
institutions in order to help them increase their outreach. Since these intermediaries were
already working in rural areas and had knowledge of rural economic activities, the
incremental cost of extending client outreach for them was expected to be smaller than
for commercial banks. To this end, the government developed a new regulatory and
supervisory framework for popular savings and credit institutions. The decision to create
a new legal framework was also motivated by the failure of several of these institutions
due to fraudulent activities in the late 1990s (Taber, 2005).

The new legal framework, enacted through the Ley de Ahorro y Credito Popular
(Savings and Popular Credit Act), became effective in June 2001. This law provides for
the gradual incorporation of popular savings and credit institutions into the new legal
framework over a four-year period. Under this law, two types of popular savings and
credit institutions will be authorized to mobilize deposits from the public: Sociedades
Cooperativas de Ahorro y Credito (Savings and Credit Cooperatives) and Sociedades
Financieras Populares (Popular Financial Associations). The main difference between
the two is that the former are non-profits owned by their members, while the later are
partial for-profits owned by shareholders. The scope of financial intermediation activities
allowed, as well as the regulatory and supervisory standards applied, depends on several
characteristics of institutions, including asset size, number of clients, number of branches,
geographic location, and technical and operational capabilities, with four distinct
categories. The CNBV (Comisión Nacional Bancaria y de Valores, National Banking and
Securities Commission) is responsible for regulating and supervising the sector and
licensing the different popular savings and credit institutions. The new legal framework
establishes an auxiliary supervision scheme, with federations (voluntary groupings of
popular savings and credit institutions) enforcing secondary regulations and carrying out
some supervision and oversight tasks. 75 To be licensed by the CNBV an institution must
first receive a favorable rating from the supervision committee of its federation.
Federations are grouped in confederations, which are responsible for operating a deposit
insurance fund. This fund will be created using an initial government contribution and
will subsequently be strengthened with contributions from popular savings and credit
institutions. Both federations and confederations are licensed by the CNBV.

2. BANSEFI’s Role

As part of its strategy of fostering the development of the popular savings and
credit sector, in April 2001 the government created BANSEFI (Banco de Ahorro
Nacional y Servicios Financieros, National Savings and Financial Services Bank), a
development bank with the objective of providing support to this sector. BANSEFI was
created out of PANHAL (Patronato Nacional del Ahorro), a government-owned narrow

75
This system of auxiliary supervision is based on the models of financial cooperative supervision
employed in Germany and Canada.

44
bank that focused exclusively on mobilizing savings by capturing deposits, mostly among
small-scale rural clients, and investing these funds in government debt securities.
BANSEFI has two main mandates: first, promoting savings by acting as a narrow bank (a
function it inherited from PANHAL) and second spearheading the development of the
popular savings and credit sector.

To accomplish this second mandate, BANSEFI performs two tasks. First, it


administers and coordinates a one-off government subsidy for about 45 million U.S.
dollars (mostly financed by the World Bank) to strengthen and support popular savings
and credit institutions in their transition process towards licensing under the new legal
framework. BANSEFI provides institutions and federations with technical assistance and
training to help them improve their governance, transparency, and management
capabilities to standards required for licensing. BANSEFI also helps to coordinate the
evaluation of the popular savings and credit institutions and the development of action
plans to strengthen those institutions that do not yet meet the operational and financial
standards of the new legal framework. Supervisory committees were created in each
federation to assess, with the support of international institutions specialized in this
sector, the financial condition of each institution and its operational capabilities.

BANSEFI’s second task, which we view as the most innovative component, is to


provide centralized back-office services like electronic transfers, liquidity management,
clearing house services, debit and credit card services, and foreign exchange and
derivatives transactions to the popular savings and credit institutions to allow them to
capture economies of scale and scope that they may not be able to achieve individually.
In the case of liquidity services, for instance, BANSEFI can consolidate the liquidity of
all the participant institutions and invest it on their behalf in the commercial banking
system, securing a higher rate of return than what the institutions could negotiate
individually. BANSEFI is developing a technological platform, financed with a one-off
subsidy of about 90 million U.S. dollars, to allow the sector to operate effectively as a
network and to help institutions minimize operation and supervision costs. These
centralized services are offered at fee and can be voluntarily and modularly contracted by
the institutions.

BANSEFI has also created a commercial alliance among several popular savings
and credit institutions (L@Red de la Gente, The People’s Network) to share branches and
facilitate the distribution of financial products. 76 This network uses a common
technological platform to distribute financial products, helping to generate homogenous
products that are offered under an umbrella trademark, significantly reducing distribution
and marketing costs. L@Red de la Gente is also used to distribute several government
programs and operates with traditional money transfer companies that use its network to
distribute remittances. 77 This provides additional revenues to member institutions
through distribution fees and helps to attract new customers and increase financial
76
This network is currently integrated by 68 institutions with a total of 1,170 branches, including 548
branches that BANSEFI inherited from PANHAL.
77
Remittances are a major source of income in Mexico. In 2004 Mexicans received 16.6 billion U.S.
dollars in remittances and estimates for 2005 are around 20 billion. About 75 percent of the 25 million
emigrants living abroad have no access to financial services (BANSEFI, 2006).

45
services penetration. The distribution of government programs is linked to the opening of
savings accounts for beneficiaries, helping to introduce them into the financial system. At
the end of 2003, for instance, more than 80 percent of the beneficiaries of the
Oportunidades government program who received their benefits through L@ Red kept
positive balances in their accounts.78 There is no exclusivity agreement or legislation
restricting competition for the distribution of government programs and therefore L@Red
de la Gente must provide its distribution services on a competitive basis.

The BANSEFI-led program has made substantial progress in meeting its


objectives, although there have been some delays in the process of upgrading and
converting the popular savings and credit institutions into regulated entities. In April
2005 the deadline to comply with the new regulatory standards for those institutions that
meet minimum ratings was extended to December 2008. As of December 2005, three
popular savings and credit institutions and 12 federations had been authorized by the
CNBV. Out of 406 institutions participating in the technical assistance program, 360 have
already been classified, with about 6 percent meeting the requirements to apply for
licensing and another 48 percent having to implement a stabilization plan before become
eligible for authorization (see Table 2.2). The remaining institutions will have to undergo
major reorganization processes or will be liquidated. The technological platform is in the
implementation stage with four institutions currently participating and an additional 83
intending to start roll-out.

3. Policy Discussion

A salient characteristic of BANSEFI’s activities is that, in line with our stylized


description of the pro-market activism view, they are designed to promote the
development of private financial intermediaries, not replacing them. However, one could
reasonably question whether providing support to popular savings and credit institutions
is warranted and whether other policy options would not yield similar or even better
results. If increasing access to financial services in rural areas is considered beneficial
due to the associated externalities, the government could subsidize the opening of
commercial bank branches in those areas, rather than supporting informal institutions. As
mentioned above, the Mexican government tried to encourage commercial banks to
extend their presence in rural areas between 1996 and 1999 by subsidizing the costs of
opening and operating new branches. However, this project failed to induce a significant
expansion of branch networks. The failure of this effort led the Mexican government to
try to foster the development of those intermediaries that are already working in rural
areas and have knowledge of rural economic activities. The need to transform the popular
savings and credit institutions into regulated institutions was reinforced by the failure of
several of these institutions due to fraudulent activities in the late 1990s. BANSEFI
explicitly recognizes that the government could focus on improving the enabling
environment, so that popular savings and credit institutions would resolve their
deficiencies over time, until becoming fully integrated with the formal financial system.

78
The Oportunidades program provides cash transfers for health and education expenses to lower-income
families.

46
However, it argues that this would take a long time and therefore some type of
government intervention is necessary to speed-up the process (see BANSEFI, 2003).

Another relevant question about BANSEFI’s activities is why government


intervention is needed to provide centralized services and help popular savings and credit
institutions achieve economies of scale. In principle, if there are significant benefits of
scale, these institutions should grow and capture these economies of scale by themselves.
Alternatively, they could contract a private provider of back-office services. Most
popular savings and credit institutions are rather small (only two institutions have more
than 50 branches) because the type of credit they provide requires detailed knowledge of
local borrowers and business conditions, constraining their geographic expansion. Most
of these small institutions may also lack adequate capital and human resources to use new
information and communication technologies to expand their operations and achieve
economies of scale. Regarding the private provision of centralized services, most of the
costs of back-office operations are fixed and therefore the adoption of a similar provider
by many institutions may be necessary to achieve economies of scale and make this kind
of service profitable. The failure to coordinate efforts among different institutions may
prevent the development of a private provider. Also, while commercial banks could use
their existing back-office operations to provide services to popular savings and credit
institutions, this may be prohibited by regulations and many institutions may be unwilling
to share data with banks that could potentially become their competitors.

BANSEFI has some institutional features that differentiate it from more


traditional interventions. BANSEFI was financed by a one-off subsidy from the
government (mostly financed by the World Bank). Therefore, government funding was
limited to providing seed money to upgrade the popular savings and credit institutions
and build the technological platform to provide them with centralized services. The lack
of annual budget allocations forces BANSEFI to provide its services at market prices—or
at least at cost—in order to remain sustainable, reducing distortions. Of course, the
creation of vested interests entailed in this type of intervention raises tricky political
economy issues, as the government may face pressures to provide additional funds to
BANSEFI in the future or to use it to channel funds to the private sector through the
popular savings and credit institutions. 79 We believe that these are important risks that
must be considered when designing any intervention. In the case of BANSEFI these risks
may have been mitigated by the participation of multilateral organizations and the
creation of a clear sunset clause, establishing that BANSEFI would be, at least partially,
sold to the popular savings and credit institutions once these institutions become formal
regulated entities. The result of this sale will be a clear indicator of whether BANSEFI
has actually added value by providing centralized services. The terms and procedures for

79
Although the law authorizes BANSEFI to lend to the popular savings and credit institutions and their
clients, it has concentrated on providing fee-based services and does not take any credit risk exposure, as
this could threaten its sustainability. Also, providing credit to the public would place BANSEFI in direct
competition with private institutions, which runs contrary to its objective of fostering financial market
development. While the fact that BANSEFI has avoided providing credit is commendable, one could
reasonably argue that the best option to reduce political risk would be to explicitly prohibit BANSEFI from
extending credit.

47
this sale are currently under analysis (BANSEFI, 2006) and many sector representatives
have expressed interest in taking part (CGAP, 2005a).

On aspect of BANSEFI’s experience that raises some questions is the fact that, as
described above, it performs two tasks in relation to popular savings and credit
institutions: giving them technical support to help them become formal financial
institutions and providing them with centralized services to help them achieve economies
of scale and scope. An open question is whether having a single institution fulfill both
tasks may not generate some incentive problems. For instance, since BANSEFI provides
popular savings and credit institutions with technical support and training, they might feel
pressured to use its centralized services, even if these services do not add much value or
are not competitively priced. Of course, constructing a technological platform to help
informal institutions to reduce their costs may not make much sense if these institutions
are not sustainable and lack adequate capabilities. Therefore, upgrading informal
institutions may be a pre-condition to the provision of centralized services, and both
functions may complement each other, to the extent that sustainable institutions may be
better able to take advantage of the cost reductions generated by the centralized provision
of back-office services, and lower costs may increase sustainability. However, while
admitting that both tasks are necessary, one could reasonably question whether they
should be performed by the same institution. In the case of BANSEFI, this problem may
be compounded by the fact that it has second separate mandate. As mentioned above,
BANSEFI inherited a wide network of branches from PANHAL that capture deposits and
invest them in government securities. The participation of BANSEFI in the retail savings
sector may place it in competition with popular savings and credit institutions. In fact,
according to CGAP (2005a), some of the largest institutions have opted not to use
BANSEFI’s centralized services because they see it as a potential competitor. In contrast
with this perception, BANSEFI does not believe it competes with popular savings and
credit institutions, as it does not provide credit services and many of its branches are
located in areas where they are not present.

48
Table 2.1: Overview of Popular Savings and Credit Institutions
(June 2001)

Legally
Number of Authorized to
Number of Clients Receive
Type of Institution Instituions (Thousands) Deposits? Regulated?
Credit unions 32 19 Yes Yes
Savings and Loans Associations 11 675 Yes Yes
Cooperatives 157 1,081 Yes No
Social Credit Institutions 210 190 No No
Populer Credit Institutions 208 344 No No

Total 618 2,309

Source: BANSEFI

Table 2.2: Evaluation of Popular Savings and Credit Institutions


(November 2005)

Global Rating by Technical Number of Share of


Asisstance Experts Instituions Instituions
A 20 6%
B 172 48%
C 110 31%
D 58 16%

Total 360

Rating Categories
Category A: Institutions that meet the requirements to apply for authorization.
Category B: Institutions that require an improvement program to be authorized.
Category C: Institutions that are in need of overhaul and that require financial support to
strengthen their capital. This includes institutions that will require a merger, spin off, or
major reorganization process.
Category D: Institutions that are incapable of meeting the minimum requirements for
operating pursuant to the Savings and Popular Credit Act. These institutions shall be
liquidated or dissolved.

49
Appendix 3

NAFIN’s Reverse Factoring Program

1. Factoring

In many countries, small businesses find it difficult to finance their production cycle,
since they lack access to bank credit and most buyers usually take between 30 and 90
days to pay. After delivery, sellers issue an invoice, recorded as an account receivable by
the seller and an account payable by the buyer. Factoring is a type of financing in which
firms sell their accounts receivable at a discount (equal to interest plus service fees) to a
financial firm (called the factor) and receive immediate cash. Factoring is an asset sale,
not a loan. There is no debt repayment and no additional liabilities on the supplier’s
balance sheet. Most factoring is done “without recourse,” meaning that the factor
assumes the default risk, as it does not have recourse against the supplier if the buyer
defaults. Thus, the credit risk that the factor faces is that of the buyer.

An alternative to ordinary factoring is reverse factoring. In this case, the factor


only purchases accounts receivable issued by certain buyers. Reverse factoring may have
significant advantages in providing financing to SMEs in developing countries. Ordinary
factoring requires information on all of the borrowers’ customers, which may be difficult
to obtain in countries without good credit information systems. Also, fraud (false
receivables, non-existing customers, etc.) is a significant problem in ordinary factoring,
especially in countries that lack credit bureaus and electronic registries and have weak
legal environments. Reverse factoring reduces these problems, as the factor only needs to
assess the credit worthiness of a specific group of large firms. Another advantage of
factoring in developing countries is that it does not require good bankruptcy systems, just
the legal ability to sell, or assign, accounts receivables. Since factoring involves the
purchase of accounts receivable by the factor, not the provision of a loan, the receivables
become the property of the factor and are not affected by the bankruptcy of the
supplier. 80

Factoring has experienced significant growth in both developed and developing


countries in recent years. In 2004, total worldwide factoring volume reached 860.2 billion
euros (about 1.1 trillion U.S. dollars), after an impressive growth of 88 percent since
1998. Factoring volume, both in absolute terms and as a percentage of GDP, is higher in
Western European countries, with the U.K. and Italy having the largest markets.
Factoring is still relatively underdeveloped in most developing countries, but transaction
volume in those countries has more than doubled over the last seven years. 81

80
Despite this advantage, creditor rights and contract enforcement are not irrelevant for factoring
transactions, as they affect the factor’s ability to collect payment from the buyer. Also, in emerging
economies there may be additional legal, tax, and regulatory issues that limit the ability to conduct
factoring transactions (see Klapper, 2005 for a discussion).
81
See Bakker, Klapper, and Udell (2004) for an overview of worldwide factoring markets, with a focus on
Eastern European countries. Klapper (2005) analyzes the determinants of factoring market development.

50
2. Description of NAFIN’s Reverse Factoring Program

Nacional Financiera (NAFIN) is a Mexican development bank created in 1934 to


provide commercial financing. NAFIN is mostly a second-tier bank: about 90 percent of
its lending is done through banks and only 10 percent is made directly to borrowers.
NAFIN launched an online system, called Cadenas Productivas (Productive Chains), to
provide reverse factoring services to SMEs in 2001. This program works by creating
chains between “big buyers” and their suppliers. The buyers that participate in the
program, large credit-worthy firms, must invite suppliers to join their chain. All
transactions are carried out on an electronic platform. NAFIN maintains an internet site
with a dedicated page for each buyer. Once a supplier delivers goods to the buyer and
issues an invoice, the buyer posts an online negotiable document equal to the amount that
will be factored (usually 100 percent of the value of the receivable) on its NAFIN
webpage. Participant financial institutions that are willing to factor this particular
receivable post their interest rate quotes for this transaction. Finally, the supplier can
access this information and choose the best quote. Once the factor is chosen, the
discounted amount is transferred to the supplier’s bank account. The factor is paid
directly by the buyer when the invoice is due (see figure 3.1).

This program has several advantages in terms of dealing with principal-agent


problems and transaction costs. First, buyers must invite their suppliers to join their chain
and participate in the program. This effectively outsources screening to the buyers, who
have an informational advantage relative to financial institutions. Buyers generally
require suppliers to have a relationship of a minimum length and a good performance
record before inviting them to participate in the program. Banks are not required to invest
significant resources in the screening process since they only need to collect credit
information and estimate the credit risk of buyers, which are large credit-worthy firms
that in many cases already have an ongoing business relationship with them. Second, the
system increases information availability and prevents fraud. Banks can access
information on the performance of the suppliers, which helps to establish credit histories
and may provide cross-selling opportunities. Also, since the buyer (not the supplier)
enters the receivables into the system, the supplier cannot submit bogus receivables,
preventing fraud. Third, the use of an electronic platform significantly reduces
transaction costs. The electronic platform allows NAFIN to capture economies of scale,
since most of the costs of the system are fixed and electronic access enables a large
number of firms and financial institutions to participate. The platform also increases the
speed of transactions: all transactions are completed within three hours and the money is
credited to the suppliers’ account by the close of business, providing them with
immediate liquidity. Furthermore, the system increases competition among financial
intermediaries, as once a transaction is posted online all participating financial
institutions can bid to factor it by posting an online quote. The use of an electronic
platform allows all banks to participate, giving national reach to smaller regional banks.

NAFIN was responsible for the development, production, and marketing costs
related to the electronic platform. It operates the system and also handles all the legal
work, such as document transfers, preparing and signing documents, etc. NAFIN requires
all participating financial institutions to use its second-tier funding to provide credit

51
through the system. In fact, NAFIN does not charge a fee for the factoring services, but
rather covers its costs with the interest it charges on its loans. Banks are allowed to
charge a maximum interest rate of 7 percentage points above the rate at which they get
funding from NAFIN. This limit seems to be non-binding, as banks charge on average
five additional percentage points (which is about 8 percentage points below commercial
lending rates).

NAFIN’s factoring program has been very successful. As of mid-2004, the


program encompassed 190 large buyers (45 percent of which were private) and more than
150,000 suppliers (about 70,000 of these were SMEs). About 20 domestic lenders
participated in the program, including banks and independent financial companies.
NAFIN has extended over nine billion U.S. dollars in financing since the program’s
inception and has brokered more than 1.2 million transactions, 98 percent by SMEs.
According to Klapper (2005), many of the suppliers had no access to external financing
before participating in the program and most depended on credit from their own suppliers
and internal funds to finance their activities. More than half of NAFIN’s second-tier
lending in 2004 corresponded to the financing of factoring transactions originated from
this program. NAFIN has started to offer other credit products, like contract financing,
using the same electronic platform and has created a similar system to provide factoring
services to exporting firms. NAFIN has also entered into agreements with development
banks in several Latin American countries, including Colombia, El Salvador, and
Venezuela, to create similar programs and development banks in other countries in the
region are considering replicating NAFIN’s model.

Several factors have contributed to the success of NAFIN’s program (see Naranjo,
2005). A key element was the consistency between strategy and resource deployment.
The creation of the Cadenas Productivas program required NAFIN to change from a
model where its focus was affecting the supply of credit through second-tier lending to a
model where it had to affect the demand for funds by promoting financial intermediation.
The promotion of the factoring program had to be made mostly at the firm level and
required different human and technical resources than acting as a second-tier bank,
namely a new and larger retail sales staff and promotional resources. Deploying the
required resources to establish the productive chains was one of the main drivers of the
success of NAFIN’s program. Second, the use of a non-lending contract like factoring
helped to overcome institutional deficiencies and reduce principal-agent problems,
fostering financial intermediation. Finally, the success of the program depended on the
availability of technology to implement the electronic platform which significantly
reduces transaction costs. The use of this electronic system was facilitated by the
existence of adequate legislation regulating electronic transactions.

3. Policy Discussion

In line with the stylized description of pro-market interventions presented in this


study, NAFIN’s program is designed to foster financial market activity, not replace it.
However, one could question whether this is actually the case, since, in principle, the
services offered by NAFIN’s online system could be provided by a private firm and
therefore this program could be displacing private sector activity. At the time of the

52
program’s introduction, some financial firms were providing factoring services in
Mexico, but none had developed a system integrating a large number of firms and
financial intermediaries. A possible explanation for this lack of private sector initiative is
that financial innovation in many cases can be hampered by the fact that once a new
lending technology is introduced and proves to be successful, others can easily adopt it.
Therefore, there is little incentive for lenders to invest in new credit technologies. In this
situation, as Besley (1994) argues, there might be a role for the government to subsidize
innovation. Furthermore, the system created by NAFIN may present significant network
effects, since the value for firms of participating increases with the number of financial
institutions that take part, and vice versa. This type of network effects may give rise to a
“chicken and egg” problem: to attract buyers and suppliers, the program needs a large
base of registered financial intermediaries, but these will be willing to register only if
they expect many firms to participate. Also, note that financial intermediaries are most
likely to have the know-how to create a program of this type, but they may not be willing
to allow their competitors to participate, reducing the incentives for buyers and suppliers
to take part. Without a coordination mechanism, no innovation may take place in this
situation. As mentioned above, a key factor in the success of NAFIN’s program has been
the development of a large retail sales staff and promotional resources to reach firms and
establish the productive chains, which requires different human and technical resources
than financial intermediation.

There are several characteristics of NAFIN’s Cadenas Productivas program that may
hold important lessons for the design of pro-market interventions. First, the program is
designed to foster competition among financial institutions and increase information
availability. Once a transaction is posted online, all participating banks can bid to factor it
by posting an online quote. The system also increases transparency, as all banks can
access historical information on the performance of suppliers which helps them to
establish a credit history. NAFIN’s experience suggests that in order to foster competition
through this type of intervention, it is necessary to facilitate the participation of all
financial intermediaries and to avoid giving preferential access or other advantages to
larger banks or public institutions.

Second, as mentioned above, NAFIN requires all financial institutions that participate
in the Cadenas Productivas program to use its funds for lending through the system and
does not charge any fees for the use of the electronic platform, covering its costs with the
interest it charges on its loans. This reduces transparency and makes it difficult to
evaluate whether the program’s services are adequately priced. Also, there is no reason
for NAFIN to provide funds to the participating financial institutions. The requirement to
use loans from NAFIN seems to be the result of institutional incentives: since NAFIN is a
second-tier development bank, its performance is evaluated in terms of the volume of
loan disbursements. In fact, as Naranjo (2005) highlights, the creation of the factoring
program seems to have been driven, at least partially, by the loss of NAFIN’s traditional
cost advantage in lending to the financial sector and the resulting need to increase
demand for its loans through other means. As the financial system recovered from the
1994-1995 financial crisis and overall macroeconomic conditions improved, the spread
between bank rates and the Mexican sovereign rates decreased significantly and
NAFIN’s financing became relative expensive. It was no longer possible for NAFIN to

53
promote credit to SMEs using second-tier lending. Therefore, it tried to increase its loan
volume by fostering financial intermediation through the reverse factoring program.
NAFIN’s experience suggests that in order to foster pro-market interventions and avoid
distortions, it may be necessary to develop new ways of evaluating the performance of
public institutions that go beyond the volume of credit provided and rather focus on the
amount of financial intermediation promoted.

Finally, one could reasonably question whether continued government operation of


the program is necessary. While there might be arguments for subsidizing the initial costs
of developing and promoting the program and operating it in its initial stages, there is no
a priori justification for government participation once it becomes fully functional.
Development institutions should move on to new activities once the market they were
promoting becomes self-sustainable. For instance, NAFIN could sell the Cadenas
Productivas program to a private firm. However, institutional incentives may make this
quite difficult. When a program is successful and profitable, the public institution that
manages it does not have incentives to divest it. Also, the program may become an
important part its activities. In the case of NAFIN, for instance, more than half of its
second-tier lending in 2004 corresponded to the financing of factoring transactions
originated from the Cadenas Productivas program. Transferring it to a private operator
would mean losing a significant part of its franchise value. Also, note that in order to
transfer the program to a private firm it must be separate from other activities and have a
clear market-based pricing, which is not the case of NAFIN. All these arguments suggest
that when designing a program of this type it is necessary to create clear sunset clauses,
establishing when public participation in the program will be terminated and under what
conditions its operation will be transferred to the private sector. This may require
defining the mandate of development institutions in dynamic, rather than static, terms to
encourage them to move on to new activities once a certain intervention has proved
successful. Also, to increase transparency and facilitate the eventual transfer to the
private sector, the program should be operated as a separate business unit with its own
profit and loss statement. 82

82
An alternative would be creating a separate institution to operate the program, but this may create
additional costs and generates some agency and incentive problems of its own. Also, this would imply
missing an opportunity for capacity building in public development institutions, which could be useful for
conducting other direct interventions.

54
Figure 3.1: The NAFIN Reverse Factoring System

Factoring
Day 1 Day 10 Day 50 Day 80

S receives a purchase B repays F directly the full


order from B, due in S makes a delivery to B amount of the negotiable
40 days and posts a negotiable document
document on its NAFIN
website, payable to S in 30
Supplier S, Buyer B, days
and Factor F sign
contracts with NAFIN
to allow factoring
S uses the NAFIN website to factor its
receivable from B with F (at an average
rate of NAFIN’s interest rate plus 5
percent) and receives today the full
amount of the negotiable document,
less interest

Source: Klapper (2005)

55
Appendix 4

FIRA’s Structured Finance Transactions

1. Structured Finance

Structured finance can be defined as a form of financial intermediation based


upon securitization technology. 83 In its simplest form, it is a process where assets are
pooled and transferred to a third party (commonly referred to as special purpose vehicle
or SPV), which in turn issues securities backed by this asset pool. Typically, several
classes of securities (called tranches) with distinct risk-return profiles are issued. 84
Innovations abound in this market and several types of assets have been included in the
collateral pool, ranging from cash instruments (e.g., mortgages, loans, bonds, credit card
receivables) to synthetic exposures (e.g., credit default swaps). The structured finance
market in developed countries has experienced significant growth over the last years (see
BIS, 2005b). In the case of developing countries, although the volume of transactions
has also increased significantly, structured finance markets are still small and
underdeveloped. 85

Structured finance transactions involve a number of different participants. These


typically include: the originator, who originates the underlying assets in the course of its
regular business activities or purchases them in the market; the arranger, who sets up the
structure and markets the securities; the servicer, who collects payments and tracks the
performance of the asset pool; the trustee, who oversees cash distributions to investors
and monitors compliance with deal documentation; and, in some deals, financial
guarantors, who provide guarantees for certain tranches.

As described above, structured finance transactions have three main features: (i)
pooling of assets; (ii) transfer of the asset pool from the originator to a finite-lived
standalone entity (SPV); and (iii) tranching of securities that are backed by this asset
pool. Each of these features may create significant benefits for both issuers and investors.
First, the transfer of assets from the originator to the SPV provides collateral for the
transaction. This transfer also de-links the performance of the instrument for that of the
originator: payments to investors only depend on the cash flow generated by the asset
pool, but not on the performance of the originating firm. Another advantage is that the
SPV is a bankruptcy remote entity, in the sense that if the originator files for bankruptcy,
the assets in the pool do not come under court jurisdiction. All these benefits taken
together make it possible to issue securities with well-defined risk characteristics and
returns that may be more predictable than those of the originator. Pooling may improve

83
Accurately defining structured finance is quite difficult, as even among market participants there is no
agreement on exactly what it encompasses. See Davis (2005) for a survey of alternative definitions.
84
Some authors (see, for example, Alles, 2001, and BIS, 2005b) differentiate between securitization (which
only involves the pooling and transfer of assets to a third party and subsequent issuance of securities) and
structured financing (which also involves the creation of different classes of securities). In keeping with
common usage, we use the term structured finance to refer to both types of instruments.
85
See Meddin (2004) for an overview of structured finance in emerging markets and the role it may play in
fostering capital market development.

56
the liquidity of many types of assets by increasing the number of potential buyers (Duffie
and Garleanu, 2001). Finding a buyer for a specific asset (e.g., a specific loan) may be
difficult and generate high costs. By pooling homogenous assets, transaction costs can be
reduced and liquidity improved. Tranching can add value by creating securities that cater
to specific investor groups (Oldfield, 2000). Furthermore, tranching may also help to
mitigate adverse selection problems. If the originator has private information on the
quality of the assets, investors who do not know the true quality of those assets will
demand a premium (Akerlof, 1970). To reduce this problem, risk averse investors and
those with less information can purchase senior tranches (those that are more protected
from default and only face residual losses), which are less affected by adverse selection.
Also, the originator, the arranger, and the servicer may retain subordinated exposure (i.e.,
the first losses in the pool) to alleviate investor concerns. 86

2. Description of FIRA’s Structured Finance Transactions

FIRA (Fideicomisos Instituidos en Relación con la Agricultura, Agricultural


Related Trust Funds) is a Mexican development-oriented financial institution created in
1954 that provides financial services and technical assistance to the agricultural sector. 87

In recent years, FIRA has tried to increase access to finance through the use of
structured finance transactions. The structured finance transactions arranged by FIRA can
be classified in two groups: asset backed securities (ABS) and collateralized loan
obligations (CLO). FIRA’s ABS transactions are typically designed to help transform
movable assets, such as commodity inventories, into viable collateral for financial
institutions. These transactions involve the securitization of loans backed by movable
collateral and the sale of participations in the trust fund that owns these loans to investors,
typically financial institutions. They also involve an operational agent, usually a large
commercial firm, that shares the risk, screens producers, monitors inventories, and
provides an outlet for the liquidation of the collateral in case of default. FIRA’s CLO
transactions, on the other hand, are usually designed to provide working capital financing
(there is no physical collateral in this case). In this type of transactions, a large
commercial firm acts as originator, granting working capital loans to its suppliers. These
credit rights are then transferred to an SPV and securities backed by this asset pool are
issued. To help align incentives and reduce adverse selection and moral hazard problems,
various participants in the supply chain provide liquid guarantees to cover eventual credit
losses. We now turn to the description of two specific structured finance transactions
arranged by FIRA, which illustrate how structured finance can solve problems of access
to finance and also help us to understand the role played by FIRA.

86
See De Marzo (2004), De Marzo and Duffie (1999), Mitchell (2005), and Riddough (1997) for analyses
of issues related to asymmetric information in structured finance transactions.
87
FIRA is composed of four trust funds which work in coordination with one another to provide financial
services and technical assistance to the rural sector. The services provided by FIRA include second-tier
lending, credit guarantees, technical assistance, and several subsidy programs.

57
3.1 Collateralized Loan Obligation (CLO) Transaction to Provide Financing to
Shrimp Producers

FIRA designed a CLO transaction to provide working capital financing to shrimp


producers in collaboration with a large shrimp distributor called Ocean Garden. 88 The
general structure can be summarized as follows (see Figure 4.1). Shrimp producers sign
supply contracts with Ocean Garden to deliver a certain amount of shrimp at a future
date. Ocean Garden pays them a portion of these contracts (typically 75 percent) in
advance to provide them with working capital financing. These loans have a maturity of
180 days, renewable for another 90. The interest rate on these loans is determined by
Ocean Garden based on the credit quality of each producer. 89 These credit rights are
subsequently transferred to an SPV, which sells participations to investors, mostly
commercial banks. Ocean Garden not only acts as originator but also as servicer, being
responsible for transferring payments to the SPV once producers deliver their production.
This structured finance transaction helps to solve principal-agent problems by
outsourcing the screening of small producers to a large commercial firm like Ocean
Garden that has an informational advantage relative to financial intermediaries. A
significant problem in this type of transaction, as discussed above, is that the originator
may have incentives to include lower quality assets in the collateral pool. Anticipating
this possibility, investors who have less information about the quality of the assets may
not be willing to invest or may ask for a premium to compensate them. In this particular
transaction, this adverse selection problem is ameliorated by the fact that, since Ocean
Garden signs supply agreements with the producers, it depends on the fulfillment of these
agreements for its future sales and therefore has incentives to adequately screen and
monitor producers.

To further reduce incentive compatibility problems, different industry participants


provide liquid guarantees to cover the first credit losses. Shrimp producers and suppliers
of shrimp feed provide guarantees that cover credit losses up to 24 percent. 90 These
guarantees are linked to specific loans. Ocean Garden provides a general guarantee that
covers all credit losses up to 25 percent of the total asset pool. Once these guarantees are
exhausted, investors start facing credit losses. This happens when losses exceed about 32
percent. FIRA has estimated that the maximum historical annual productivity decrease in
the shrimp sector has been around 27 percent; hence these guarantees are expected, in
most cases, to cover all losses. 91

88
Ocean Garden is one of the main exporters of Mexican shrimp to the U.S. It handles approximately one
quarter of Mexico’s shrimp production and has annual sales of about 250 million U.S. dollars. The firm
was owned by the Mexican government and was recently privatized.
89
Ocean Garden has developed scoring methods to evaluate the credit quality of small producers and also
has historical data on their performance that allows it to construct credit histories.
90
Shrimp feed suppliers agreed to participate in this transaction and provide guarantees because before they
were the main source of financing to producers, which required them to invest more capital and face a
higher credit risk. Also, note that since the guarantee provided by shrimp feed suppliers are linked to
specific loans (it is not a general guarantee as the one provided by Ocean Garden), these firms have
incentives to screen and monitor shrimp producers.
91
The average credit loss in the shrimp sector, according to FIRA, has been around 4.2 percent.

58
Credit losses not covered by these liquid guarantees are divided between FIRA
(90 percent) and the banks that purchase the securities (10 percent), as shown in Table
4.1. The total net risk exposure of the banks in this scheme is 5.1 percent, while that of
FIRA is 45.9 percent, in both cases after first losses. FIRA charges a 1 percent premium
for the provision of this guarantee.

As described above, FIRA not only acts as an arranger for the transaction
(charging a fee of 0.75 percent for this service), but also as a financial guarantor,
covering second losses. Furthermore, since FIRA is a second-tier lending institution, it
requires all banks participating in this transaction to use its funding to purchase the
securities issued by the SPV.

This structured finance transaction presents several advantages in terms of dealing


with problems of access to credit. First, as mentioned above, the participation of a large
commercial firm like Ocean Garden that has a better knowledge of small producers helps
to ameliorate principal-agent problems. Second, the pooling of working capital loans to
several producers (about 150) reduces transaction costs and also helps financial
institutions to diversify their risk exposure, as they do not face the idiosyncratic risk of a
single producer. Also, financial institutions do not face Ocean Garden’s credit risk, as the
supply contracts are removed from its balance sheet and their ownership is transferred to
the SPV. This means that if Ocean Garden files for bankruptcy, the assets in the pool do
not come under court jurisdiction. This type of transaction also allows smaller, mostly
urban banks to provide financing to the agricultural sector, helping them to diversify their
portfolio. Finally, this transaction generates a more efficient and transparent distribution
of risks. Before the creation of this scheme, shrimp producers relied mostly on trade
credit from their suppliers, who in many cases faced significant credit constraints
themselves, to finance production. 92 In contrast, this CLO transaction takes advantage of
the informational advantages of industry players without requiring them to act as
financiers. It also increases transparency, by making clear the credit risk faced by each
party and how it is being compensated for it.

FIRA has been successful in using similar CLO transactions to improve access to
credit for small producers in several sectors (including wheat, corn, and sorghum
production) by using large commercial firms as originators and the loans provided
through this type of transactions now account for 5 percent of its total portfolio.

3.2 Asset Backed Securities (ABS) Transaction to Provide Financing to Sugar Mills

FIRA designed an ABS transaction to provide financing to sugar mills with the
collaboration of Cargill Mexico. The general structure can be summarized as follows (see
Figure 4.2). Sugar mills store their sugar inventories in warehouses previously selected
and authorized by Cargill. Cargill then gives credit to the sugar mills by making a
repurchase agreement (repo) for the certificates of deposit issued by these warehouses. 93
92
Another possible source of financing was Ocean Garden. However, at the time this firm was facing
financial difficulties that significantly constrained its ability to finance its suppliers.
93
A repurchase agreement (or repo) is an agreement in which one party sells an asset to another at a certain
price with the commitment to buy back the asset at a later date for another price. A repo is legally a sale

59
These loans are for an amount equivalent to 80 percent of the value of the sugar
inventories stored in the warehouse and have a maturity of 45 days, renewable for
successive periods of 45 days up to a maximum of 270 days. The implicit interest rate on
these loans is equal to LIBOR (London Interbank Offered Rate) plus 4.75 percentage
points, without any differentiation across mills. Cargill then sells the certificates of
deposit to investors, mostly commercial banks, through a funded participation agreement.

FIRA acts as an arranger in this transaction and also provides a credit guarantee to
investors, which covers 96 percent of the total value of the loans. FIRA charges a 1
percent premium for the provision of this guarantee. To reduce its risk exposure, FIRA
has an agreement with Cargill, who guarantees that it will purchase any repossessed
inventories from FIRA in case of default. Under this agreement, Cargill covers 80 percent
of the total credit losses, reducing FIRA’s exposure to 16 percent. 94 Since FIRA is a
second-tier lending institution, it requires all banks to use its credit to purchase the
participations in the fund.

Cargill acts as a servicer in this transaction. It is in charge no only of evaluating


and selecting warehouses but also of monitoring their operations and transferring
payments to the fund when sugar mills cancel their loans. Cargill also administers a
margin call system that is designed to protect investors from fluctuations in the price of
sugar. When the ratio of the market price of the sugar stored in the warehouse to the
value of the loan falls below 1.25, Cargill issues a margin call requiring the mill to
deposit additional sugar in the warehouse (or provide cash guarantees) to restore this
relation. Mills have three days to fulfill the margin call, otherwise they are declared in
default and their inventories are liquidated. 95 Cargill charges a 2.5 percent fee for acting
as a servicer and providing the guarantee to FIRA.

This structured finance transaction improves access to finance for sugar mills by
transforming their inventories into viable collateral for financial institutions. The use of
these inventories as collateral faces several difficulties. The first one, which applies to
most forms of movable collateral, especially in developing countries, is that this type of
collateral if difficult to secure. Sugar mills could pledge their inventories as collateral and
then easily sell those inventories without the bank knowing about it. In the case of
Mexico, this problem was compounded by the lack of a reliable warehousing market that
could guarantee the value and the quality of the inventories stored. Cargill’s know-how to
select and monitor commodity warehouses is crucial in this respect. The second problem
of using sugar inventories as collateral is the high volatility of sugar prices in Mexico.
There are no derivatives markets in Mexico for sugar, therefore financial institutions

and subsequent repurchase, effectively transferring the property of the asset to the creditor. However, from
an economic perspective, it is similar to a secured loan.
94
The fact that FIRA provides the guarantee to banks and then gets a guarantee from Cargill, instead of
Cargill directly providing the guarantee to the banks, is explained by regulatory arbitrage: since FIRA is a
public institution, capital requirements on loans guaranteed by FIRA are significantly lower than those on
loans guaranteed by a private party.
95
FIRA estimates that, given the historical volatility of sugar prices, the maximum expected loss during a
three day period, at a 95 percent confidence level, is 2.82 percent.

60
could not protect themselves from this risk.96 The solution to this problem adopted in this
scheme is creation of the system of margin calls administered by Cargill. Third, in many
cases financial institutions may be unwilling to grant credit even if collateral is available
due to the high costs of liquidating that collateral. In this ABS transaction, this problem
was solved by the participation of Cargill, who provides an outlet for the liquidation of
sugar inventories. As described above, in case of default FIRA can sell 80 percent of the
reposed sugar inventories to Cargill. Another important feature of this transaction is the
use of a repurchase agreement which effectively transfers legal ownership of the
inventories to Cargill, eliminating the need to go through the cumbersome collateral
repossession process in case of default.

In addition to addressing the problems related to collateral, this structured finance


transaction also helps to reduce transaction costs, by pooling loans to several sugar mills
(27 in total). This pooling also helps financial institutions to diversify their risk exposure,
as they do not face the idiosyncratic risk of a single producer. Furthermore, this
transaction increases transparency by making clear the amount and type of risk that each
party is taking and how they are being compensated for it. Cargill takes 80 percent of the
credit risk and acts a servicer, obtaining a 2.5 percent fee. FIRA takes 16 percent of the
credit risk and charges 1 percent for its guarantee. In addition, it charges .09 percentage
points over LIBOR for its second-tier funding. The banking sector takes 4 percent of the
risk and obtains an intermediation margin of 1.16 percent. Overall, sugar mills pay an
interest equal to LIBOR plus 4.75 percentage points.

FIRA has been successful in using similar ABS transactions to improve access to
credit for rural producers in several sectors (including corn, wheat, sorghum, shrimp, and
love cattle) and the loans provided through this type of transactions now account for 10
percent of its total portfolio.

3.1 Policy Discussion

In line with the stylized description of pro-market interventions presented in this


study, FIRA’s structured finance transactions are designed to foster financial market
activity, not replace it. However, one could question whether this is actually the case.
First, structured finance transactions could be arranged by private firms; therefore FIRA’s
intervention could be displacing private sector activity. At the time of these interventions,
no firm was providing structured finance to the sugar and shrimp sectors and producers in
both sectors lacked access to bank financing. As Besley (1994) notes, not all profitable
opportunities are necessarily exploited by the private sector. Financial innovation in
many cases can be hampered by the fact that once a new lending technology is introduced
and proves to be successful, others can easily adopt it. Therefore, there is little incentive
for lenders to invest in new credit technologies. In this situation, there might be a role for
the government to subsidize innovation. In the case of structured finance transactions, the
96
An alternative solution would be to hedge this price risk in international derivatives markets, but this is
not possible in the case of sugar, as worldwide sugar markets are segmented due to tariff protections and
therefore the evolution of prices across different markets may differ significantly.

61
unfamiliarity of market participants with its techniques and its seeming complexity may
further difficult the development of private solutions. Second, one could question to what
extent FIRA’s interventions actually foster financial market development as they seem to
leave very little room for private financial intermediation. In both of the transactions
described above, FIRA provides second-tier financing to banks and also gives them credit
guarantees that limit their risk exposure to about 5 percent. In more recent transactions
FIRA has reduced the level of credit enhancement, but it still remains quite high. As
discussed below, some of these features seem to be the result of institutional incentives,
as FIRA is evaluated on the basis of its loan disbursements and the volume of guarantees
it provides. It is still an open question whether these transactions would work without
such extensive FIRA involvement. Regarding the provision of second-tier lending,
interviews with banks suggest that they would be willing to participate in these
transactions without receiving FIRA’s funding. In fact, for some of the largest banks
FIRA’s financing is no longer cost-competitive, as they can get capital in financial
markets at similar or even lower rates. In the case of credit guarantees, the evidence is
less clear. The high level of guarantees provided by FIRA seems to be explained not by
banks’ risk aversion, but rather by regulatory arbitrage: since FIRA is a public institution,
capital requirements on loans guaranteed by FIRA are significantly lower than those on
regular loans. Banks would be willing to take more credit risk, but this would lead to
higher costs as lower FIRA guarantees would mean higher capital requirements. Finally,
in the case of the ABS transaction one could reasonably question whether it would be
better to improve the collateral market, by fostering the development of a reliable
warehousing system and improving collateral repossession laws and judicial procedures,
instead of designing a structured transaction to solve the problems of using inventories as
collateral. However, both measures are not mutually exclusive. The ABS transaction may
be a short-term solution while the warehousing market takes time to develop. Also, the
ABS scheme may contribute to the development of the warehouse market by providing
adequate incentives to warehouses and helping authorities to understand what regulations
or enforcement mechanisms are necessary for this market to develop.

There are several characteristics of FIRA’s structured finance transactions that may
hold important lessons for the design of pro-market interventions. First, as described
above, FIRA not only acts as an arranger in these transactions, but also provides credit
guarantees and second-tier lending. This bundling of several instruments makes it very
difficult to analyze the individual merits of each instrument and carries the risk of
distorting prices and incentives. It is not possibly to analyze whether the different
services provided by FIRA are adequately priced, as financial institutions cannot buy
them separately. The requirement to use FIRA’s second-tier lending and its credit
guarantees seems to be the result of institutional incentives: since FIRA is a second-tier
development financial institution, its performance is evaluated in terms of the volume of
loan disbursements and the amount of guarantees provided. FIRA’s experience suggests
that in order to foster pro-market interventions and avoid distortions, it may be necessary
to develop new ways of evaluating the performance of public institutions that go beyond
the volume of credit and guarantees provided and rather focus on the amount of financial
intermediation promoted.

62
Second, FIRA provides guarantees that cover most of the credit risk faced by
financial institutions. FIRA reduces its risk exposures by buying guarantees from private
parties and only taking second losses, decreasing the amount of risk shifting to the public
sector that actually takes place. As mentioned above, the high level of credit guarantees
provided by FIRA seems to be the result of regulatory arbitrage: since FIRA is a public
institution, capital requirements on loans guaranteed by FIRA are significantly lower than
those on regular loans. One of the main functions of FIRA’s guarantees therefore seems
to be reducing regulatory capital requirements. This highlights the fact that there might be
a conflict of interest in the public sector between the roles of regulator and promoter of
new activities. Finding the adequate equilibrium between both roles may not be easy.
Also, the fact that banks only face residual credit risk may reduce incentives to invest in
improving their risk assessment capabilities. Furthermore, the provision of guarantees by
FIRA may prevent the development of a private guarantors market. In developed
countries, guarantees in structured finance transactions are usually provided by private
financial guarantors (so called monolines). Since FIRA provides guarantees covering
most of the credit risk and its guarantees have a significant advantage in terms of capital
requirements, there may be little incentive for developing an active private market for
guarantees. 97

Third, an important element to take into account is that interventions should be


designed to increase competition in the financial system. Participations in the structured
finance transactions could be sold to financial institutions other than banks, including
insurance companies, mutual funds, and pension funds. FIRA’s mandate was modified to
allow it to include other financial intermediaries in its transactions. The fact that only
banks have invested in these operations so far seems to be explained by the relative small
size of these transactions, which makes it difficult to meet the minimum size thresholds
to develop a liquid market for the securities issued. However, FIRA is actively working
on including other investors in its operations.

Finally, although structured finance transactions can help to overcome some of the
limitations of the contracting environment in developing countries, they require having an
appropriate legal framework that accommodates the numerous legal relationships that
must be established for these transactions to work. The lack of an adequate legal
framework for structured finance may be a significant constraint for the replication of
FIRA’s experience in other developing countries. 98

97
The lack of a private guarantors market also makes it difficult to assess whether FIRA’s guarantees are
accurately priced.
98
See Alles (2001) for a general discussion of the elements of the legal framework that may prevent the
development of structured finance in developing countries.

63
Figure 4.1: Description of CLO Transaction to Provide Financing to Shrimp
Producers

Transfer of
credit rights +

OCEAN 3 $100 5
BANKS
GARDEN
$100
4
6
TRUST Participation
FUND certificates
Working
Supply
capital loan
agreement Second loss
$100
guarantee 7
2 1
Payments
SHRIMP
FIRA
PRODUCERS
SHRIMP FEED
Feed SUPPLIERS

Table 4.1: Distribution of Credit Losses among Participants in CLO Transaction

Shrimp and Feed


Percentage of Producers Ocean Garden
Credit Losses Guarantees Guarantee FIRA Guarantee Bank Credit Losses
10 2.4 7.6 0.0 0.0
20 2.4 7.6 0.0 0.0
30 2.4 7.6 0.0 0.0
40 2.4 2.2 4.9 0.5
50 2.4 0.0 6.8 0.8
60 2.4 0.0 6.8 0.8
70 2.4 0.0 6.8 0.8
80 2.4 0.0 6.8 0.8
90 2.4 0.0 6.8 0.8
100 2.4 0.0 6.8 0.8

Total Risk
Exposure 24 25 45.9 5.1

64
Figure 4.2: Description of ABS Transaction to Provide Financing to Sugar Mills

5
SUGAR 4 Portfolio sale
(Funded BANKS
MILL $80 participation
agreement)
3 6
CD Repo $80 7
CARGILL
1 2 Guarantee
Inventories Certificate of
$100 deposit (CD)
$100
8
Screening Guarantee
and FIRA
monitoring
WAREHOUSES
Margin calls

65
References

Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson, 2001. The Colonial Origins of


Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation, American Economic Review 91,
1369-1401.

Adrianova, S., D. Panicos, and A. Shortland, 2002. State Banks, Institutions and
Financial Development, mimeo, University of Leicester.

Akerlof, G. A., 1970. The Market for “Lemons:” Quality Uncertainty and the Market
Mechanism, Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, 488-500.

Alles, L., 2001. Asset Securitization and Structured Finance: Future Prospects and
Challenges for Emerging Market Countries, IMF Working Paper WP/01/147.

Agarwala, R., 1983. Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries, World Bank
Staff Working Paper 575.

Aliou, D. and M. Zeller, 2001. Access to Credit and Its Impact on Welfare in Malawi,
International Food Policy Research Institute Research Report 116.

Anjali K., A. Parsons, A. Nair, and E. Urdapilleta, 2006. Expanding Bank Outreach
through Retail Partnerships: Correspondent Banking in Brazil, mimeo, World Bank.

Armendariz de Aghion, B., 1999a. Development Banking, Journal of Development


Economics 58, 83-100.

Armendariz de Aghion, B., 1999b. On the Design of a Credit Agreement with Peer
Monitoring, Journal of Development Economics 60, 79-104.

Arnott, R. J. and J. E. Stiglitz, 1991. Moral Hazard and Non-market Institutions:


Dysfunctional Crowding Out or Peer Monitoring? American Economic Review 81, 179-
190.

Atieno, R., 1999. Access to Credit by Women in Agribusiness Trade: Empirical Evidence
on the Use of Formal and Informal Credit Sources in Rural Kenya, Institute for
Development Studies, University of Kenya.

Bakker, M. R., L. Klapper, and G. F. Udell, 2004. Financing Small and Medium-size
Enterprises with Factoring: Global Growth and Its Potential in Eastern Europe, World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3342.

BANSEFI, 2003. Technical Note 1: Strategic Aspects of the BANSEFI-Based Policy to


Increase Access to Financial Services.

BANSEFI, 2006. BANSEFI’s Socialization Process.

66
Barro, R. J. 1991. Economic Growth in a Cross-section of Countries, Quarterly Journal
of Economics 106, 407–443.

Barth, J., G. Caprio, and R. Levine, 2001. Banking Systems around the Globe: Do
Regulation and Ownership Affect Performance and Stability? in F. Mishkin (ed.),
Prudential Regulation and Supervision: Why is it Important and What are the Issues?
National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA.

Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and M. S. Martinez Peria, 2005. Reaching Out: Access to
and Use of Banking Services across Countries, mimeo, World Bank.

Beck, T. and R. Levine, 2005. Legal Institutions and Financial Development, in C.


Menard and M. Shirley (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Kluwer
Academic Publishers.

Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and R. Levine, 2003. Law and Finance: Why Does Legal
Origin Matter? Journal of Comparative Economics 31, 653-675.

Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and R. Levine, 2004. Finance, Inequality and Poverty:
Cross-Country Evidence, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3338.

Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and V. Maksimovic, 2002. Financial and Legal Constraints
to Firm Growth: Does Size Matter? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2784.

Beegle, K., R. Dehejia, and R. Gatti, 2003. Child Labor, Income Shocks and Access to
Credit, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3075.

Benavente, J. M., 2006. Programa de Crédito para la Microempresa BancoEstado,


mimeo, World Bank.

Benavente, J. M., A. Galetovic, and R. Sanhueza, 2006. Fogape: An Economic Analysis,


mimeo, World Bank.

Bennett, F., H. Billington, and A. Doran, 2005. Do Credit Guarantees Lead to Improved
Access to Financial Services? Recent Evidence from Chile, Egypt, India, and Poland,
Department for International Development, London, Financial Sector Team, Policy
Division Working Paper.

Besley, T., 1994. How do Market Failures Justify Interventions in Rural Credit Markets?
World Bank Research Observer 9, 27-47.

Besley, T. and S. Coate, 1995. Group Lending, Repayment Incentives, and Social
Collateral, Journal of Development Economics 46, 235-264.

Bhattacharya, U. and H. Daouk, 2002. The World Price of Insider Trading, Journal of
Finance 57, 75-108.

67
BIS 2005a. BIS 75th Annual Report.

BIS, 2005b. The Role of Ratings in Structured Finance: Issues and Implications,
Committee on the Global Financial System Publication No. 23.

Boehmer, E., R. C. Nash, and J. M. Netter, 2005. Bank Privatization in Developing and
Developed Countries: Cross-sectional Evidence on the Impact of Economic and Political
Factors, Journal of Banking and Finance 29, 1981-2013.

Booth, L., V. Aivazian, A. Demirguc-Kunt, and V. Maksimovic, 2001. Capital Structure


in Developing Countries, Journal of Finance 56, 87-129.

Brizzi, A., 2001. Rural Development and Agriculture, in M. Guigale, O. Lafourcarde and
V. H. Nguyen (eds.), Mexico: A Comprehensive Development Agenda for the New Era,
World Bank: Washington, DC.

Buchanan, J. M., 1962. Politics, Policy, and the Pigovian Margins, Economica 29, 17-28.

Burgess, R. and R. Pande, 2005. Can Rural Banks Reduce Poverty? Evidence from the
Indian Social Banking Experiment, American Economic Review 95, 780-795.

Cameron, E., 1953. The Credit Mobilier and the Economic Development of Europe,
Journal of Political Economy 61, 461-488.

Cameron, R. 1961. France and the Economic Development of Europe, 1800-1914


Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.

Capaul, M., 2003. Corporate Governance in Latin America, mimeo, World Bank.

Caprio, G. and P. Honohan, 2001. Finance for Growth: Policy Choices in a Volatile
World, World Bank, Oxford University Press: New York.

Caskey, J. P., C. Ruíz Durán, and T. M. Solo, 2004. The Unbanked in Mexico and the
United States, presented at the International Conference on Access to Finance, Brussels,
28-29 October.

CGAP, 2001. Commercialization and Mission Drift: The Transformation of Microfinance


in Latin America, Occasional Paper No. 5.

CGAP, 2003a. Microfinance Means Financial Services for the Poor, Donor Brief No. 11.

CGAP, 2003b. Scoring: The Next Breakthrough in Microcredit? Occasional Paper No. 7.

CGAP, 2004. Financial Institutions with a “Double Bottom Line:” Implications for the
Future of Microfinance, Occasional Paper No. 8.

68
CGPA, 2005a. Mexico Country-Level Savings Assessment.

CGAP, 2005b. Commercial Banks and Microfinance: Evolving Models of Success,


Focus Note No. 28.

CGAP, 2006. Using Technology to Build Inclusive Financial Systems, Focus Note No.
32.

Cho, Y. J., 1997. Credit Policies and the Industrialization of Korea, in K. B. Staking,
(ed.), Policy-Based Finance and Market Alternatives: East Asian Lessons for Latin
America and the Caribbean, Inter-American Development Bank: Washington, DC.

Claessens, S., 2005. Universal Access to Financial Services: A Review of the Issues and
Public Policy Objectives, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3589.

Clarke, G., R. Cull, and M. Shirley, 2004. Empirical Studies of Bank Privatization: Some
Lessons, presented at the World Bank, International Monetary Fund, and Brookings
Institution Conference The Role of State-Owned Financial Institutions: Policy and
Practice, Washington, DC.

Coase, R. H., 1960. The Problem of Social Cost, Journal of Law and Economics 3, 1-44.

Coutinho, L., 2006. Networking: The Case of Bansefi, mimeo, World Bank.

Daley-Harris, S. 2003. State of the Microcredit Summit Campaign Report 2003, mimeo.

Davis, H. A., 2005. The Definition of Structured Finance: Results form a Survey, Journal
of Structured Finance 11, 5-10.

De la Torre, A., 2002. Reforming Development Banks: A Framework, presentation at the


World Bank Staff Workshop on Reforming Public Sector Banks, December, Washington,
DC.

De la Torre, A., J. C. Gozzi, and S. Schmukler, 2005. Stock Market Development under
Globalization: Whither the Gains from Reforms? mimeo, World Bank.

De Marzo, P. M., 2004. The Pooling and Tranching of Securities: A Model of Informed
Intermediation, Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming.

De Marzo, P. M. and D. Duffie, 1999. A Liquidity-Based Model of Security Design,


Econometrica 67, 65-99.

Department for International Development, 2004, The Importance of Financial Sector


Development for Growth and Poverty Reduction, Policy Division Working Paper PD
030.

69
Djankov, S., C. McLiesh, and A. Shleifer, 2006. Private Credit in 129 Countries, Journal
of Financial Economics, forthcoming.

Duffie, D. and N. Garleanu, 2001. Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations,
Financial Analysts' Journal Jan.-Feb., 41-59.

Durlauf, S., P. A. Johnson, and J. Temple, 2005. Growth Econometrics, in P. Aghion and
S. Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier: Amsterdam.

Easterly, W., 1993. How Much do Distortions Affect Growth? Journal of Monetary
Economics 32, 187-212.

Easterly, W., 2001. The Lost Decade: Developing Countries’ Stagnation in Spite of
Policy Reform 1980–1990, Journal of Economic Growth 6, 135–57.

Easterly, W., 2005. National Policies and Economic Growth: A Reappraisal, in P. Aghion
and S. Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier: Amsterdam.

Easterly, W. and R. Levine, 2003. Tropics, Germs, and Crops: How Endowments
Influence Economic Development, Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 3-40.

Fernandez-Arias, E. and P. Montiel, 2001. Reform and Growth in Latin America: All
Pain and No Gain? IMF Staff Papers 48, 522-546.

Fleisig, H. W., 1996. Secured Transactions: The Power of Collateral, Finance &
Development 33, 44-46.

Fouad M., R. Hemming, D. Lombardo, and W. Maliszewski, 2004. Fiscal Transparency


and Public Banks, presented at 6th Annual Financial Markets and Development
Conference The Role of State-Owned Financial Institutions: Policy and Practice,
Washington, DC.

Francisco, M. and A. Kumar, 2004. Enterprise Size, Financing Patterns and Credit
Constraints in Brazil: Analysis of Data from the Investment Climate Assessment Survey,
World Bank Working Paper 49.

Galindo, A. and A. Micco, 2004. Do State Owned Banks Promote Growth? Cross-
country Evidence for Manufacturing Industries, Economics Letters 84, 371-376.

Galindo, A., A. Micco, and G. Ordoñez, 2002. Financial Liberalization and Growth,
presented in Financial Globalization: A Blessing or a Curse? World Bank Conference,
May.

Gelb, A. H., 1989. Financial Policies, Growth, and Efficiency, World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper Series 202.

70
Gershenkron, A., 1952. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective, in F. Hoselitz
(ed.) The Progress of Underdeveloped Areas, University of Chicago Press: Cambridge,
MA.

Gerschenkron, A., 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book of


Essays, Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA.

Ghatak, M. and T. Guinnane, 1999. The Economics of Lending with Joint Liability:
Theory and Practice, Journal of Development Economics 60, 195-228.

Goldsmith, R., 1969. Financial Structure and Development, Yale University Press: New
Haven.

Graham Bannock and Partners Ltd., 1997. Credit Guarantee Schemes For Small Business
Lending – A Global Perspective, Volume I – Main Report.

Green, A., 2003. Credit Guarantee Schemes for Small Enterprises: An Effective
Instrument to Promote Private Sector-Led Growth? United Nations Industrial
Development Organization, SME Technical Working Paper No. 10.

Greif , A., 1993. Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The
Maghribi Traders' Coalition, American Economic Review 83, 525-48.

Hall, R. E. and C. Jones, 1999. Why do Some Countries Produce so Much More Output
per Worker than Others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 83-116.

Haber, S. and N. Maurer, 2004. Related Lending and Economic Performance: Evidence
from Mexico, mimeo, Standford University.

Halac, M. and S. Schmukler, 2004. Distributional Effects of Crises: The Financial


Channel, Economia, Fall, 1-67.

Hanson, J. A., 2003. Banking in Developing Countries in the 1990s, World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper 3168.

Hardy, D., P. Holden, and V. Prokopenko, 2002. Microfinance Institutions and Public
Policy, IMF Working Paper 02/159.

Herrero Calvo, A. and P. Pombo Gonzalez, 2001. Los Sistemas de Garantia para la Micro
y la PYME en una Economia Globalizada.

Hirschman, A. O., 1958. The Strategy of Economic Development, Yale University Press:
New Haven.

71
Hoff, K. and J. E. Stiglitz, 2001. Modern Economic Theory and Development, in G.
Meier and J. E. Stiglitz (eds.), The Future of Development Economics in Perspective,
Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Holden, P. 1997. Collateral Without Consequences: Some Causes and Effects of


Financial Underdevelopment in Latin America, The Financier - Analyses of Capital and
Money Market Transactions 4, 12-21.

Honohan, P., 2004. Financial Sector Policy and the Poor: Selected Findings and Issues,
World Bank Working Paper No. 43.

Inter-American Development Bank, 2002. Acceso de las Pequeñas y Medianas Empresas


al Financiamiento, Grupo DFD, Informe de Trabajo, March.

Inter-American Development Bank, 2004. Unlocking Credit: The Quest for Deep and
Stable Bank Lending, Report on Economic and Social Progress in Latin America.

Jansson, T., 2002. Financing Microfinance: Exploring the Funding Side of Microfinance
Institutions, Inter-American Development Bank Sustainable Development Department
Technical Paper 118.

Japelli, T. and M. Pagano, 2002. Information Sharing, Lending and Defaults: Cross-
country Evidence, Journal of Banking and Finance 26, 2017-2045.

Kaminsky, G. and S. Schmukler, 2003. Short-run Pain, Long-run Gain: The Effects of
Financial Liberalization, NBER Working Paper No. 9787.

Karolyi, G. A., 2004. The Role of American Depositary Receipts in the Development of
Emerging Equity Markets, Review of Economics and Statistics 86, 670-690.

Klapper, L., 2005. The Role of Factoring for Financing Small and Medium Enterprises,
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3593.

Klapper, L. and R. Zaidi, 2005. A Survey of Government Regulation Intervention in


Financial Markets, mimeo, World Bank.

Krebsbach, K., 2003. Doing Good By Doing Well, U.S. Banker 47-48, August.

Krueger, A., 1974. The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society, American
Economic Review 64, 291-303.

Krueger, A., 1990. Government Failures in Development, Journal of Economic


Perspectives 4, 9-23.

72
Krueger, A., 2004. Meant Well, Tried Little, Failed Much: Policy Reforms in Emerging
Market Economies, remarks at the Roundtable Lecture at the Economic Honors Society,
New York University, New York, March 23.

Kumar, A., 2005. Access to Financial Services in Brazil: A Study, World Bank:
Washington, DC.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Shleifer. 2002. Government Ownership of


Banks, Journal of Finance, 57, 265-301.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and G. Zamarrita, 2003. Related Lending, Quarterly


Journal of Economics 118, 231-268.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. W. Vishny, 1997. Legal


Determinants of External Finance, Journal of Finance 52, 1131-1150.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. W. Vishny, 1998. Law and


Finance, Journal of Political Economy 106, 1113-1155.

Lanyi, A. and R. Saracoglu, 1983. The Importance of Interest Rates in Developing


Economies, Finance & Development 20, 20-23.

Levine, R., 1998. The Legal Environment, Banks, and Long-run Economic Growth,
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30, 596-620.

Levine, R., 2005. Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence, in P. Aghion and S.
Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier: Amsterdam.

Levine, R. and S. Schmukler, 2006a. Migration, Spillovers, and Trade Diversion: The
Impact of Internationalization on Domestic Stock Market Activity, Journal of Banking
and Finance, forthcoming.

Levine, R. and S. Schmukler, 2006b. Internationalization and Stock Market Liquidity,


Review of Finance, forthcoming.

Levitsky, J., 1997a. SME Guarantee Schemes: A Summary, The Financier - Analyses of
Capital and Money Market Transaction 4, 5-11.

Levitsky, J., 1997b. Best Practice in Credit Guarantee Schemes, The Financier - Analyses
of Capital and Money Market Transaction 4, 86-94.

Littlefield E. and R. Rosenberg, 2004. Microfinance and the Poor: Breaking Down the
Walls between Microfinance and Formal Finance, Finance & Development 41, 38-40.

Loayza N., P. Fajnzylber, and C. Calderón, 2005. Economic Growth in Latin America
and the Caribbean. Stylized Facts, Explanations, and Forecasts, mimeo, World Bank.

73
Lombardo, D. and M. Pagano, 2002. Law and Equity Markets: A Simple Model, in J.
McCahery, P. Moerland, T. Raaijmakers, and L. Renneboog (eds.), Corporate
Governance Regimes: Convergence and Diversity, Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Love, I. and N. Mylenko, 2003. Credit Reporting and Financing Constraints, World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper 3142.

McIntosh, C. and B. Wydic, 2004. A Decomposition of Screening and Incentive Effects


in Credit Information Systems, mimeo, University of California at San Diego.

McKinnon, R. I., 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development, The Brookings
Institution: Washington, DC.

Meddin, L., 2004. Structured Finance in the Emerging Markets, in Global Securitisation
Review 2004 / 2005, Euromoney.

Megginson, W. L., 2005. The Economics of Bank Privatization, Journal of Banking and
Finance 29, 1931-1980.

Micco, A. and U. Panizza, 2004. Bank Ownership and Lending Behavior, mimeo, Inter-
American Development Bank.

Micco A. and U. Panizza, 2005. Public Banks in Latin America, background paper
prepared for the conference on Public Banks in Latin America: Myth and Reality Inter-
American Development Bank February 25, 2005.

Miller, 2003. Credit Reporting Systems and the International Economy, MIT Press:
Cambridge MA.

Mitchell, J., 2004. Financial Intermediation Theory and the Sources of Value in
Structured Finance Markets, National Bank of Belgium Working Paper.

Moel, A., 2001. The Role of American Depositary Receipts in the Development of
Emerging Markets, Economia 2, 209-273.

Morduch, J., 1999. The Microfinance Promise, Journal of Economic Literature 37, 1569-
1614.

Murphy, K., Shleifer A. and Vishny R., 1989. Industrialization and the Big Push, Journal
of Political Economy 97, 1003-1026.

Naranjo M., 2005. NAFIN’S Reverse Factoring Program, mimeo, World Bank.

North, D., 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance,


Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK.

74
Oldfield, G., 2000. Making Markets for Structured Mortgage Derivatives, Journal of
Financial Economics 57, 445-471.

Pagano, M. and P. Volpin, 2001. The Political Economy of Finance, Oxford Review of
Economic Policy 17, 502-519.

Peachey, S. and A. Roe, 2004. Access to Finance, A Study for the World Savings Banks
Institute, Oxford Policy Management, October.

Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, 2001. Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth,
Oxford Review of Economic Policy 17, 467-482.

Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, 2003a. Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists, Crown
Business Division of Random House: New York.

Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, 2003b. The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial
Development in the 20th Century, Journal of Financial Economics 69, 5-50.

Riddough, T., 1997. Optimal Design and Governance of Asset-Backed Securities,


Journal of Financial Intermediation 6, 121-152.

Riding, A. L., 1997. Review of Costs and Benefits of Loan Guarantee Programs by R. C
Vogel and D. W. Adams, The Financier - Analyses of Capital and Money Market
Transactions 4, 107-111.

Rodrik, A., 2002, After Neo-Liberalism, What? The Economic Times, November 19th.

Rodrik, D., 2005. Why We Learn Nothing from Regressing Economic Growth on
Policies, mimeo, Harvard University.

Rodrik, D., A. Subramanian, and F. Trebbi, 2004. Institutions Rule: The Primacy of
Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development, Journal of
Economic Growth, forthcoming.

Rodriguez-Meza, J., 2004. Debtor Enhancement Policies, presented at the Inter-American


Development Bank Conference on Financial Products and Poverty Reduction in Latin
America and the Caribbean, Washington, D.C., September 30 to October 1.

Roe, M., 1994. Strong Managers and Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American
Corporate Finance, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

Rosenstein-Rodan, P., 1943. Problems of Industrialization of Eastern and South-Eastern


Europe, Economic Journal 53, 202-211.

Rostow, W. W., 1962. The Process of Economic Growth, 2nd ed., Norton: New York.

75
Roubini, N. and X. Sala-i-Martin, 1992. Financial Repression and Economic Growth,
Journal of Development Economics 39, 5-30.

Santomero, A. M., 1997. Effective Financial Intermediation, in K. N. Staking (ed.),


Policy-Based Finance and Market Alternatives: East Asian Lessons for Latin America
and the Caribbean, Inter-American Development Bank: Washington, DC.

Satta, T. A., 2002. A Multidimensional Strategy Approach to Improving Small


Businesses' Access to Finance in Tanzania, Institute for Development Policy and
Management, The University of Manchester.

Schulhofer-Wolh, S., 2004. Testing for Credit Constraints in Entrepreneurship, presented


at the Inter-American Development Bank Conference on Financial Products and Poverty
Reduction in Latin America and the Caribbean, Washington, D.C., September 30 to
October 1.

Shaw, E., 1973. Financial Deepening in Economic Development, Oxford University


Press: New York.

Singh, A., A. Belaisch C. Collyns, P. De Masi, R. Krieger, G. Meredith, and R. Rennhack


2005. Stabilization and Reform in Latin America: A Macroeconomic Perspective on the
Experience since the Early 1990s, IMF Occasional Paper No. 238.

Srinivasan, T. N., 1985, Neoclassical Political Economy, the State and Economic
Development, Asian Development Review 3, 38-58.

Srivastava, P. and P. Basu, 2004. Scaling-up Access to Finance for India’s Rural Poor,
World Bank Working Paper 30829.

Stigler, G. J., 1971. The Theory of Economic Regulation, Bell Journal of Economics 2, 3-
21.

Stiglitz, J. E., 1994. The Role of the State in Financial Markets, in Proceedings of the
World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1993, world Bank:
Washington, DC.

Stiglitz, J. E. and A. Weiss, 1981. Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect


Information, American Economic Review 71, 393-410.

Taber L., 2005. Integrating the Poor into the Mainstream Financial System: The
BANSEFI and SAGARPA Programs in Mexico, in Scaling up Poverty Reduction. Case
Studies in Microfinance, CGAP/World Bank: Washington DC.

Tejerina, L., 2004. Enterpreneurship and Financial Constraints: The Case of Nicaragua,
presented at the Inter-American Development Bank Conference on Financial Products

76
and Poverty Reduction in Latin America and the Caribbean, Washington D.C.,
September 30 to October 1.

Temple, J., 1999. The New Growth Evidence, Journal of Economic Literature 37, 112-
156.

The Economist, 2003. Hangover Cure, June 3rd.

The Economist, 2005. Survey: Microfinance. Nov 3rd.

The Economist, 2006. Making Advances, Jan 12th.

Townsend, R. and J. Yaron, 2001. The Credit Risk-Contingency System of an Asian


Development Bank, Economic Perspectives 3Q, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

Tullock G., 1967. The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies and Theft, Western
Economic Journal 5, 224-232.

Vittas, D., 1997. Policy-Based Finance: Application of East Asian Lesson to the
America, in K. B. Staking (ed.), Policy-Based Finance and Market Alternatives: East
Asian Lessons for Latin America and the Caribbean, Inter-American Development Bank:
Washington, DC.

Vittas D. and Y. J. Cho, 1996. Credit Policies: Lessons from Japan and Korea, World
Bank Research Observer 11, 277-298.

Vogel, R. C. and D. W. Adams, 1997. Costs and Benefits of Loan Guarantee Programs,
The Financier - Analyses of Capital and Money Market Transactions 4, 22-29.

Williamson, J., 1990. What Washington Means by Policy Reform, in J. Williamson (ed.),
Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? Washington, D.C.: Institute for
International Economics.
Williamson, J. and M. Mahar. 1998. A Review of Financial Liberalization, South Asia
Discussion Paper, Report No. IDP-171, World Bank.
World Bank, 1983. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington, DC.

World Bank, 1989. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington, DC.

World Bank, 1990a. Colombia Industrial Competition and Performance, Report No.
7921-Co.

World Bank, 1990b. Colombia Industrial Restructuring and Development project, Staff
Appraisal Report, October.

77
World Bank, 1993. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy, World
Bank: Washington, DC.

World Bank, 1997. The Long March: A Reform Agenda for Latin America and the
Caribbean in the Next Decade, World Bank: Washington, DC.

World Bank, 1999. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington, DC.

World Bank, 2001. Mexico Rural Finance: Savings Mobilization Potential and Deposit
Instruments in Marginal Areas, Report No. 21286-ME.

World Bank, 2002. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington, DC.

World Bank, 2003a, Colombia Rural Finance: Access Issues, Challenges and
Opportunities, Report 27269-CO, November.

World Bank, 2003b, Broadening Access to Financial Services among the Urban Poor:
Mexico City’s Unbanked, Draft Final Report, July.

World Bank, 2004a. Whither Latin American Capital Markets? Latin America and
Caribbean World Bank Regional Study, World Bank: Washington, DC.

World Bank, 2004b. Mexico - Second Savings and Rural Finance (BANSEFI) Project:
Project Appraisal Document, Report 28929-ME.

World Bank, 2005a. World Development Report, World Bank: Washington DC.

World Bank, 2005b. Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform,
World Bank: Washington DC.

Yaron, J., 1992. Assessing Development Financial Institutions: a Public Interest


Analysis, World Bank Discussion Paper 174.

Yaron, J., M. Benjamin, and S. Charitonenko, 1998. Promoting Efficient Rural


Intermediation, World Bank Research Observer 13, 147-170.

Zagha, R., 2004. Results from the Exercise on the Lessons of the 1990s, in Searching for
Alternatives – Beyond the Washington Consensus, International Policy Dialogue: Berlin.

Zingales, L., 2004. The Costs and Benefits of Financial Market Regulation, European
Corporate Governance Institute Law Working Paper 21/2004.

78

You might also like