Microeconomics Short
Microeconomics Short
Microeconomics Short
ASSIGNMENTS
INTRODUCTION TO MICROECONOMICS
E201
71
CHAPTER 1
Introduction to Economics
Specifically, this chapter will focus on specific definitions, policy, and objective
thinking. A discussion of the role of assumptions in model building will also be offered
as a basis for understanding the economic models that will be built in the following
chapters.
Definitions
72
base assumption that people act in their own perceived best interest (at least most of
the time and in the aggregate). Without the assumption of rational behavior,
economics would be incapable of explaining the preponderance of observed economic
activity. As limiting as this assumption may seem, it appears to be an accurate
description of reality.
In 1776 Adam Smith penned An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
Wealth of Nations. With its publication, capitalism was born, from the ashes of the
mercantilist system that preceded it. Smith described an economic system of cottage
industries and relatively unfettered pursuit of self-interest, and how that unfettered
pursuit of self-interest could result in a system that distributed its limited resources in an
efficient fashion.
An Inquiry in the Nature and Cause of the Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith, New York:
Knopf Publishing, 1910, p. 14.
Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1991, p. 13.
Experimental economics, using rats in mazes, suggests that rats will act in their
own best interest (incidentally, Kahneman won a Noble Prize for this sort of research –
it is serious business, not just fun and games like it sounds). Rats, it was discovered,
prefer root beer to water. The result is that rats will pay a greater price (longer mazes
and electric shocks) to obtain root beer than they will to obtain water. Therefore it
appears to be a reasonable assumption that humans are no less rational – as Adam
Smith postulates in his view of how we might best obtain our dinner.
Most academic disciplines have evolved over the years to become collections of
73
closely associated scholarly endeavors of a specialized nature. Economics is no
exception. An examination of one of the scholarly journals published by the American
Economics Association, The Journal of Economic Literature, reveals a classification
scheme for the professional literature in economics. Several dozen specialties are
identified in that classification scheme, everything from national income accounting, to
labor economics, to international economics. In other words, the realm of economics
has expanded over the centuries that it is nearly impossible for anyone to be an expert
in all aspects of the discipline, so each economist generally specializes in some narrow
portion of the discipline. The decline of the generalist is a function of the explosion of
knowledge in most disciplines.
In general, economics is bifurcated by the focus of the analysis – that is, there
are two bundles of issues that are examined by economists. These bundles of issues
are considered together, by the level of the activity upon which the analysis is focused.
Economics is generally classified into two general categories of inquiry, these two
categories are: (1) microeconomics and (2) macroeconomics.
Methods in Economics
74
microeconomics – and the aggregate economy in macroeconomics. A good theory is
one that accurately predicts future human behavior and can be supported with
evidence.
75
Samuelson, from M.I.T., published his book, Mathematical Foundations of Economic
Analysis, and from the that point forward, economic theory was to become heavily
mathematical – gone were the days of the institutionalists from the mainstream of
economic theory. (Incidentally Paul Samuelson won the Nobel Prize for Foundations,
and he is a Hoosier, Stiglitz is also from Indiana, and both are from Gary, Indiana).
The above table presents a list of those who have won Nobel Prizes in Economic
Science. Notice that the overwhelming majority of these persons are Americans – two
of whom are from Indiana, and several are from the University of Chicago. It is also
interesting to note that one must be living to receive the Nobel Prize; so many famous
economists who met their end before receiving the prize will not be listed. Further, it is
also interesting to note that the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences is the newest of the
prizes, beginning with Tinbergen’s award in 1969.
Often the theory that will be tested comes form inductive logic or sometimes
informed guess-work. The development of rigorous models expressed as equations
typically lend themselves to rigorous statistical methods to determine whether the
models are consistent with evidence from reality. The tests of hypotheses can only
serve to reject or fail to reject a hypothesis. Therefore, empirical methods are focused
on rejecting hypotheses and those that fail to be rejected over large numbers of tests
generally attain the status of principle.
However, examples of both types of logic can be found in each of the social
sciences and in most of the business disciplines. In each of the social sciences it is
common to find that the basic theory is developed using inductive logic. With increasing
76
regularity standard statistical methods are being employed across all of the social
sciences and business disciplines to test the validity and the predictability of theories
developed using these logical constructs.
77
Economic Goals, Policy, and Reality
Most people and organizations do, at least, rudimentary planning, the purpose of
planning is the establishment of an organized effort to accomplish some economic
goals. Planning to finish your education is an economic goal. Goals are, in a sense, an
idea of what should be (what we would like to accomplish). However, goals must be
realistic and within our means to accomplish, if they are to be effective guides to action.
This brings another classification scheme to bear on economic thought. Economics
can be again classified into positive and normative economics. Positive economics is
concerned with what is; and normative economics is concerned with what should
be. Economic goals are examples of normative economics. Evidence concerning
economic performance or achievement of goals falls within the domain of positive
economics.
Most nations have established broad social goals that involve economic issues.
The types of goals a society adopts depends very much on the stage of economic
development, system of government, and societal norms. Most societies will adopt one
or more of the following goals:
78
(4) economic security,
Each goal (listed above) has obvious merit. However, goals are little more than
value statements in this broad context. For example, it is easy for the very wealthy to
cite as their primary goal, economic freedom, but it is doubtful that anybody living in
poverty is going to get very excited about economic freedom; but equitable distributions
of income, full employment and economic security will probably find rather wide support
among the poor. Notice, if you will, goals will also differ within a society, based on
socio-political views of the individuals that comprise that society.
On the other hand, goals can be public spirited and accomplish a substantial
amount of good. President Lincoln was convinced that the working classes should have
access to higher education. The Morrell Act was passed 1861 and created Land Grant
institutions for educating the working masses (Purdue, Michigan State, Iowa State, and
79
Kansas State (the first land grant school) are all examples of these types of schools).
By educating the working class, it was believed that several economic goals could be
achieved, including growth, a more equitable distribution of income, economic security
and freedom. In other words, economic goals that are complementary are consistent
and can often be accomplished together. Therefore, conflict need not be the
centerpiece of establishing economic goals.
Because any society's resources are limited there must be decisions about which
goals should be most actively pursued. The process by which such decisions are made
is called prioritizing. Prioritizing is the rank ordering of goals, from the most important to
the least important. Prioritizing of goals also involve value judgments, concerning which
goals are the most important. In the public policy arena prioritizing of economic goals is
the subject of politics.
Policy
Policy can be generally classified into two categories, public and private policy.
The formulation of public and private policy is the creation of guidelines, regulations, or
law designed to effect the accomplishment of specific economic (or other) goals.
Public policy is how economic goals are pursued. Therefore, to understand goals one
needs to understand something of the process of formulating policy.
2. options - identify the various actions that will accomplish the stated
goals & select one, and
80
Both the public and private policy formulation process is a dynamic one.
Economic goals change with public opinion and with achievement. Step 1 involves the
value statement of setting goals. Step 2 involves selecting the appropriate model and
the options associated with that model to accomplish the specified goal. The final step
involves gathering evidence and the appropriate analysis to determine whether the
policy needs revision. The process of formulating policy is therefore a loop, and
requires continuous monitoring and revising.
The major difference between public policy and private policy is that private
policy is not subject to democratic processes. The Board of Directors or management
of a company will decide what goals are to be accomplished and what policy options are
best used to do so. Often private policy is made behind closed-doors without public
accountability, even though there are often public costs imposed. The strength of public
policy is created in the open, with public debate, and often has the force of law (and not
just company rules and regulations).
Objective Thinking
Most people bring many misconceptions and biases to economics. After all,
economics deals with people's material well-being – a very serious matter to most.
Because of political beliefs and other value system components rational, objective
thinking concerning various economic issues fail. Rational and objective thought
requires approaching a subject with an open-mind and a willingness to accept what ever
answer the evidence suggests is correct. In turn, such objectivity requires the shedding
of the most basic preconceptions and biases -- not an easy assignment.
There are several common pitfalls to objective thinking in economics. Among the
most common of these pitfalls, which affect economic thought, are: (1) the fallacy of
composition, and (2) post hoc, ergo prompter hoc. Each of these will be reviewed, in
turn in the following paragraphs.
The fallacy of composition is the mistaken belief that what is true for the
81
individual must be true for the group. An individual or small group of individuals may
exhibit behavior that is not common to an entire population. For example, if one
individual in this class is a I.U. fan then everyone in this class must be an I.U. fan is an
obvious fallacy of composition. Statistical inference can be drawn from a sample of
individuals, but only within confidence intervals that provide information concerning the
likelihood of making an erroneous conclusion (E270, Introduction to Statistics provides a
more in depth discussion of confidence intervals and inference).
Post hoc, ergo prompter hoc means after this, hence because of this, and
is a fallacy in reasoning. Simply because one event follows another does not
necessarily imply there is a causal relation. One event can follow another and be
completely unrelated, this is simple coincidence. One event can follow another, but
there may be something other than direct causal relation that accounts for the timing of
the two events. For example, during the thirteenth century people noticed that the black
plague occurred in a location when the population of cats increased. Unfortunately,
some concluded that the plague was caused by cats so they killed the cats. In fact, the
plague was carried by fleas on rats. When the rat population increased, cats were
attracted to the area because of the food supply. The rat populations increased, and so
did the population of fleas that carried the disease. This increase in the rat population
also happened to attract cats, but cats did not cause the plague, if left alone they may
have gotten rid of the real carriers (the rats, therefore the fleas).
82
Law of Unitended Consequences “The Legend of Pig Iron”
(David A. Dilts, Indiana Policy Review, Vol. 1, No. 5, pp. 28-29.)
Many a cliché seems to center on pork. The head of the household is
supposed to " put bacon on the table," "pork barrels," and politicians are frequently
accused of being in too close a proximity. It only seems fitting that one more story
concerning pork should be brought to your attention.
During World War II, farmers in the corn belt argued that regulation of the
price of pork had no effect on the war effort, and that they should be permitted to sell
their commodities without government interference. The farmers brought political
pressure to bear on the Congress and our representatives to deregulate the price of
pork. The end result was to shut down the steel mills in Gary.
Shut down our steel mills? How could this be?
Since it is not intuitively obvious how this happened, I'll explain. In 1942, there
had been a change in management in the Philippines. And, as luck would have it, we
didn't have good trade relations with the new management -- the Japanese.
Therefore we did not have access to Manila fibre, necessary in making everything
from rope to battleships. We had not yet developed synthetic fibre and therefore has
to rely on the fibre previously available. That fibre was hemp.
Now hemp grows in the same places, under the same climatic conditions as
does corn. Corn is what hogs eat. And because corn was not being grown in the
Midwest, the farmers sought alternative feed for the increased number of hogs they
were raising. (Remember, increased price results in a larger quantity supplied.)
Oats, wheat and barley were available from the Great Plains region. The problem
was shipping it to where the hogs were raised in the Corn Belt of the Lower Midwest.
In their search for transportation, the farmers found that railroads were
regulated and reserved for military and heavy industry; trucks needed gasoline and
rubber, both in short-supply; and airplanes were being built almost exclusively for
military purposes.
This left the farmers without a ready source of domestic transportation for the
needed grain. But they eventually found a source of shipping that was neither
regulated nor controlled, because it was international in nature -- the iron-ore barges
on the Great Lakes.
They bid up the price and the barges started hauling oats to the pigs and
stopped hauling ore to the Gary steel mills. And there you have it:
Without the requisite iron ore the steel mills could not produce; they were
actually shut down for a period as a direct result of deregulating the price of pork.
83
CHAPTER 2
Economic Problems
87
to the production possibilities model and economic systems.
Head to Head (Lester Thurow, New York: William Morrow and Company, Inc., 1992,
p. 273.)
The search for the holy grail of high profitability lies elsewhere -- in a relentless
upscale drive in technology to ever-higher levels of productivity -- and wages. Since
rapid productivity growth is a moving target and therefore hard to copy, high long-run
profits can be sustained. But to get the necessary human talent to employ new
technologies, large skill investments have to be made. High wages have to be paid,
but paradoxically high wages also leave firms with no choice but to go upscale in
technology. High wages and high profits are not antithetical -- they go together.
The resources used to produce economic goods and services (also called
commodities) are called factors of production. These resources are the physical
assets needed to produce commodities. The way that these resources are combined to
produce is called technology. For example, a man with a shovel digging a ditch is one
technology from which ditches can be obtained. Another technology that can produce
the same commodity as a man with a shovel is a backhoe and an operator -- the
former is more labor intensive, and the latter is more capital intensive.
88
Capital includes the physical assets (i.e., plant and equipment) used in the
production of commodities. Often accountants refer to capital as money balances
that are earmarked for the purchase of plant or equipment. The accounting view of
capital is not the physical asset envisioned by economists (in reality the difference is
one of a future claim (the accountant's view) and a present stock of capital (the
economist's view) and is not trivial). Capital receives interest for its contributions to
production.
There is one important variation on capital. Economists also called the skills,
abilities, and knowledge of human beings as human capital. Human capital is a
characteristic of labor. Human capital can be acquired (i.e., education) or may be
something inherent in a specific individual (i.e., size, beauty, etc.). This subject will be
examined in more depth in Chapters 10 and 11.
Entrepreneur (risk taker) is the economic agent who creates the enterprise.
Entrepreneurial talent not only assumes the risk of starting a business, but is generally
responsible for innovations in products and production processes. The vibrancy of the
U.S. economy is, in large measure, due to a wealth of entrepreneurial talent. This
factor of production receives profits for its contribution to output.
To obtain the maximum amount of output from the available productive resources
an economic system should have full employment. Full employment is the utilization
of all resources that is consistent with normal job search and maintenance of
productive capacity. Full employment includes the natural rate of unemployment,
which economists estimate to be between four and six percent (unemployment due to
job search and normal structural changes in the economy). Empirical evidence
suggests that about 80% capacity utilization is consistent with the natural rate of
unemployment. When the economy is operating at rates consistent with the natural rate
of unemployment it is producing the potential total output. However, full production,
100% capacity utilization involves greater than full employment and cannot be
maintained for a prolonged period without labor and capital breaking-down.
Underemployment has been a persistent problem in most developed economies.
Underemployment results from the utilization of a resource that is less than what is
consistent with full employment. There are two ways that underemployment manifests
itself. First, individuals can be employed full time, but not making use of the human
89
capital they possess. For example, in many European countries it is not uncommon for
an M.D. to be employed as a practical nurse. The second way that underemployment is
typically observed is when someone is involuntarily a part-time employee rather than
employed full-time in an appropriate position.
Economic Efficiency
90
Allocative Efficiency
The Economics of Welfare, fourth edition (A. C. Pigou, London: Macmillan Publishing
Company, 1932, p. 89.)
. . . Any transference of income from a relatively rich man to a relatively poor man
of similar temperament, since it enables more intense wants to be satisfied at the
expense of less intense wants must increase the aggregate sum of satisfaction. The
old "law of diminishing utility" thus leads securely to the proposition: Any cause which
increases the absolute share of real income in the hands of the poor, provided that it
does not lead to a contraction in the size of the national dividend from any point of
view, will, in general, increase economic welfare.
Pigou states the basic proposition of Pareto Superiority in the real world; an
application of income re-distribution. The “transference of income from a relatively rich
man to a relatively poor man of similar temperament” making one less poor, and the
other less rich, results in an application of the principle of diminishing marginal utility
and, hence, allocative efficiency. In other words, the cost-benefit approach on the
margin. We take the last dollar from those with less value for that dollar and add that to
those more desperate for an additional dollar of income. Not only is this allocatively
efficient, but there are those who would argue that this is also fair.
Economic Cost
Economic cost consists of two distinct types of costs: (1) explicit (accounting)
costs, and (2) opportunity (implicit) costs. Explicit costs are direct expenditures in the
production process. These are the items of cost with which accountants are concerned.
An opportunity cost is the next best alternative that must be foregone as a result
of a particular decision. Rather than a direct expenditure, an opportunity cost is the
implicit loss of an alternative because of a decision. For example, reading this chapter
is costly, you have implicitly decided not to watch T.V. or spend time doing something
else by deciding to read this chapter. Every choice is costly; that is, there is an
opportunity cost. Economic costs are dealt with in greater detail in Chapter 7.
91
Production Possibilities
The production possibilities frontier (or curve) is a simple model that can be used
to illustrate what a very simple economic system can produce under some restrictive
assumptions. The production possibilities model is used to illustrate the concepts of
opportunity cost, productive factors and their scarcity, economic efficiency
(unemployment etc.) and the economic choices an economy must make with respect to
what will be produced.
Beer
Pizza
Along the vertical axis we measure the number of units of beer we can produce
and along the horizontal axis we measure the number of units of pizza we can produce.
Where the solid line intersects the beer axis shows the amount of beer we can produce
92
if all of our resources are allocated to beer production. Where the solid line intersects
the pizza axis indicates the amount of pizza we can produce if all of our resources are
allocated to pizza production. Along the solid line between the beer axis and the pizza
axis are the intermediate solutions where we have both beer and pizza being produced.
The reason the line is curved, rather than straight, is that the resources used to
produce beer are not perfectly useful in producing pizza and vice versa. The dashed
line represents a second production possibilities curve that is possible with additional
resources or an advancement in available technology.
Economic Systems
93
and several social ills associated with the lack of protections afforded by stronger
government. What is perhaps the saving grace, is that pure capitalism does not exist in
the course of economic history. Pure capitalism exists only in the tortured minds of
economists, and pages of the Wealth of Nations.
In the following box, Thorstein Veblen discusses his view of capitalism and the
“struggle” associated with the pursuit of self-interest in a system marked with private
interests.
The Struggle
The Theory of the Leisure Class, Thorstein Veblen, New York: Penguin Books, 1899,
pp. 24-25.
94
traditions, only some of which are based in their religion. Many of these traditions
developed because of economic constraints. For example, the tradition that some
native tribes in the Arctic had of putting their elderly out of the community to starve or
freeze may seem barbaric, but because of the difficulty in obtaining the basic
requirements of life, those that could not contribute, could not be supported. Hence a
tradition that arose from economic constraints.
Class Warfare, Noam Chomsky, Monroe, Maine: Common Courage Press, 1996,
pp.19-20.
. . . People read snippets of Adam Smith, the few phrases they teach in school.
Everyone reads the first paragraph of The Wealth of Nations where he talks about
how wonderful the division of labor is. But not many people get to the point hundreds
of pages later, where he says that division of labor will destroy human beings and
turn them into creatures as stupid and ignorant as it is possible for a human being to
be. And therefore in any civilized society the government is going to have to take
some measures to prevent division of labor from proceeding to its limits.
95
Virtually all economic systems are mixed systems. A mixed system is one that
contains elements of more than one of the above pure systems. The U.S. economy is a
mixed system, with significant amounts of capitalism, command, and socialism. The
U.S. economy also has some very limited amounts of communism and tradition that
have helped shape our system. Much of the political controversies concerning the
budget deficit, social security, and the environment focuses on the what the appropriate
mix of systems should exist in our economic system.
Estranged Worker
The Economic & Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844, Karl Marx, New York: International
Publishers, 1964, p. 107-8.
The worker become all the poorer the more wealth he produces, the more his
production increases in power and size. The worker becomes an even cheaper
commodity the more commodities he creates. With the increasing value of the world
of things proceeds in direct proportion the devaluation of the world of men. Labor
produces not only commodities: it produces itself and the worker as a commodity –
and this in the same general proportion in which it produces commodities.
This fact expresses merely that the object which labor produces – labor’s
product – confronts it as something alien, as a power independent of the producer.
The product of labor is labor which has been embodied in an object, which has
become material: it is the objectification of labor. Labor’s realization is its
objectification. In the sphere of political economy this realization of labor appears as
loss of realization for the workers; objectification as loss of the object and bondage to
it; appropriation as estrangement, as alienation.
96
population, over half, live in low income economies.
Perhaps the greatest economic issue facing the current generation is what can
be done to bring the low income economies into meaningful participation in the global
economy. The poverty of the low income economies is a serious matter without any
other issue. AIDS, malaria, and a host of other health problems are associated with the
poverty in these nations. Perhaps more importantly, with rising incomes in these parts
of the world come several benefits globally. As income rise in low income countries,
cheap labor is no longer a cause for outsourcing from the high income, industrialized
parts of the world. Further, as income rise, so too does the demand for goods and
services. The often used cliché “a rise tide makes all boats float higher” is exactly the
case in these nations emergence into full participation in the global economy. More
concerning these issues will be offered later in this book.
KEY CONCEPTS
Economizing problem
Scarce Resources
Unlimited Wants
Full Employment
Underemployment
Economic Efficiency
Allocative Efficiency
Technological Efficiency
Full Employment
Opportunity Cost
Implicit vs. Explicit Costs
97
CHAPTER 4
The purpose of this chapter is to develop one of the most powerful methods of
analysis in the economist's tool kit. In this chapter we will develop the model of a simple
market – supply and demand (the industry in pure competition – discussed further in
Chapter 8). The demand schedule and supply schedule will be developed and put
together to form the analysis of a market. The market presented here is the starting
point for the analysis of all market structures.
Markets
A market is nothing more or less than the locus of exchange, it is not necessarily
a place, but simply buyers and sellers coming together for transactions. Transactions
occur because consumers and suppliers are able to purchase and sell at a price that is
determined through the free interaction of demand and supply.
Demand
116
The demand schedule (demand curve) reflects the law of demand. The demand
curve is a downward sloping function (reflecting the inverse relationship of price to
quantity demanded) and is a schedule of the quantity demanded at each and every
price.
Price
P1
P2
Demand
Q1 Q2 Quantity
As price falls from P1 to P2 the quantity demanded increases from Q1 to Q2. This is a
negative relation between price and quantity, hence the negative slope of the demand
schedule; as predicted by the law of demand.
Because consumers make rational choices, that is they act in their own self
interest, there are two effects that follow from their attempts to maximize their well-being
when the price of a commodity changes. These two effects are called the; (1) income
effect, and (2) the substitution effect. Together these effects guarantee a downward
sloping demand curve.
The income effect is the fact that as a person's income increases (or the
price of item goes down [which effectively increases command over goods] more
of everything will be demanded. The income effect suggest that as income goes
down (price increases) then less of the commodity will be purchased.
117
The substitution effect is the fact that as the price of a commodity
increases, consumers will buy less of it and more of other commodities. In other
words, a consumer will attempt to substitute other goods for the commodity that became
more expensive. The substitution effect simply reinforces the idea of a downward
sloping demand curve.
The demand schedule can be expressed as a table of price and quantity data, a
series of equations, or in a downward sloping graph. To this point, our discussion has
focused on individuals and their behavior. Assuming that at least a significant majority of
consumers are rational, it is a simple matter to obtain a market demand curve. One
needs only to sum all of the quantities demanded by individuals at each price to obtain
the market demand curve.
Movements of the demand curve itself, either to the left or right are called
changes in demand. A change in demand is caused by a change in one or more of
the nonprice determinants of demand. A shift to the right of the demand curve is called
an increase in demand; and a shift to the left of the demand curve is called a decrease
in demand.
If the tastes and preferences of consumers change they will shift the demand
curve. If consumers find a commodity more desirable, ceteris paribus, then an increase
in demand will be observed. If consumer tastes wane for a particular product then there
will be a shift to the left of the demand (a decrease in demand).
118
The prices of related commodities also effect the demand curve. There are two
classes of related commodities of importance in determining the position of the demand
curve, these are (1) substitutes, and (2) complements. A substitute is something that is
alternative commodity, i.e., Pepsi is a substitute for Coca-Cola. A complement is
something that is required to enjoy the commodity, i.e., gasoline and automobiles. If the
price of a substitute increases, then the demand for our commodity will increase. If the
price of a substitute decreases, so too will the demand for our commodity. In other
words, the price of a substitute and the demand for our commodity move in the same
direction. For complements, the price of the complement and the demand for our
commodity move in opposite directions. If the price of a complement increases, the
demand for our commodity will decrease. If the price of a complement decreases, the
demand for our commodity will increase.
Price Price
D2
D1 D2 D1
Quantity Quantity
An increase in demand is shown in the first panel, notice that at each price there is a
greater quantity demanded along D2 (the dotted line) than was demanded with D1 (the
solid line). The second panel shows a decrease in demand, notice that there is a lower
quantity demanded at each price along D2 (the dotted line) than was demanded with D1
(the solid line).
119
Changes in Quantity Demanded
Price
P1
P2
Demand
Q1 Q2 Quantity
Supply
The law of supply is that producers will supply more the higher the price of the
commodity. The supply curve is an upward sloping function showing a direct
relationship between prices and the quantity supplied. In other words, the supply curve
has a positive slope that shows that as price increase (decreases) so too does quantity
supplied.
As with the demand curve a change in the price will result in a change in the
quantity supplied. An increase in price will result in an increase in the quantity
supplied, and a decrease in price will result in a decrease in the quantity supplied.
Again, this is because the supply curve is a schedule of the quantities supplied at each
price.
Changes in one or more of the nonprice determinants of supply cause the supply
curve to shift. A shift to the left of the supply curve is called a decrease in supply; a shift
to the right is called an increase in supply. The nonprice determinants of supply are; (1)
resource prices, (2) technology, (3) taxes and subsidies, (4) prices of other goods, (5)
expectations concerning future prices, and (6) the number of sellers.
When resource prices increase, supply decreases (shifts left); and when
120
resource prices decrease, supply increases (shifts right). If a more cost effective
technology is discovered then supply increases, increases in taxes cause the supply
curve to shift left (decrease). An increase in a subsidy effects the supply curve in the
same way as a cut in taxes, an increase in supply.
If the price of other goods a producer can supply increases, the producer will
reallocate resources away from current production (decrease in supply) and to the
goods with a higher market price. For example, if the price of corn drops, a farmer will
supply more beans.
If producers expect future prices to increase, current supply will decline in favor
of selling inventories at higher prices later. In other words, supply will decrease (a shift
to the left, and exactly the opposite response will occur if producer expect future prices
to be lower. If the number of suppliers increases, so too will supply, but if the number of
producers declines, so too will supply.
Quantity Quantity
A decrease in supply is shown in the first panel, notice that there is a lower quantity
supplied at each price with S2 (dotted line) than with S1 (solid line). The second panel
shows an increase in supply, notice that there is a larger quantity supplied at each price
with S2 (dotted line) than with S1 (solid line).
121
Changes in Quantity Supplied
Price Supply
P1
P2
Q2 Q1 Quantity
Market Equilibrium
Market equilibrium occurs where supply equals demand (supply curve intersects
demand curve). An equilibrium implies that there is no force that will cause further
changes in price, hence quantity exchanged in the market. This is analogous to a
cherry rolling down the side of a glass; the cherry falls due to gravity and rolls past the
bottom because of momentum, and continues rolling back and forth past the bottom
until all of its' energy is expended and it comes to rest at the bottom - this is equilibrium
[a rotten cherry in the bottom of a glass].
122
Price and Value
Price Supply
Pe
Demand
Qe Quantity
Demand Curve is Qd = 22 - P
(Notice the negative sign in front the price variable, indicating a downward sloping
function)
123
Supply Curve is Qs = 10 + P
(Notice the positive sign in front of the price variable, indicating an upward sloping
function)
(For this market to obtain equilibrium, the quantity demanded must equal the quantity
supplied in this market)
Therefore:
22 - P = 10 + P
22 = 10 + 2P
12 = 2P or P = 6
To find the equilibrium quantity, we plug 6 (for P) into either the supply or
demand curve and get:
124
Change in Demand
Price Supply
P1
P2
D2 D1
Q2 Q1 Quantity
Considering the following graph, movement of the supply curve from S1 (solid
line) to S2 (dashed line) is an increase in supply. Such increases are caused by a
change in a nonprice determinant (for example, the number of suppliers in the market
increased or the cost of capital decreased). With an increase in supply there is a shift of
the supply curve to the right along the demand curve, therefore equilibrium price and
quantity move in opposite directions (price decreases, quantity increases). If we move
from S2 to S1 that is called an decrease in supply, possibly due to an increase in the
price of a productive resource (capital) or the number of suppliers decreased. When
supply decreases, equilibrium price increases and the quantity decreases as a result.
That is the result of the supply curve moving up along the negatively sloped demand
curve (which remains unchanged).
125
Changes in Supply
S1
Price
S2
P1
P2
Demand
Q1 Q2 Quantity
If both the demand curve and supply curve change at the same time the analysis
becomes more complicated. Consider the following graphs:
P2 D1
D2
Q Quantity Q Quantit
Notice that the quantity remains the same in both graphs. Therefore, the change
in the equilibrium quantity is indeterminant and its direction and size depends on the
relative strength of the changes between supply and demand. In both cases, the
equilibrium price changes. In the first case where demand increases, but supply
decreases the equilibrium price increases. In the second panel where demand
decreases and supply increases, the equilibrium price decreases.
In the event that demand and supply both increase then price remains the same
126
(is indeterminant) and quantity increases, and if both decrease then price is
indeterminant and quantity decreases. These results are illustrated in the following
diagram
Increase in Supply Decrease in Supply s.
and in Demand and in Demand
Price Price
D2 D1
D1
D2
P P
S2
S1 S2 S1
Q1 Q2 Quantity Q2 Q1 Quantity
The graphs show that price remains the same (is indeterminant) but when supply
and demand both increase quantity increases to Q2. When both supply and demand
decrease quantity decreases to Q2.
For example, the Former Soviet Union had a centrally planned economy and the
government decided what would be produced and for what price that production would
be sold. The government also was the sole employer and paid very low wages,
therefore prices were also controlled at below market equilibrium levels. The result was
that whenever any commodity was available in the market, there were long lines
observed at any store with anything to sell, prices were low but there was nothing to buy
(shortages). The popular Russian immigrant comedian, Yakov Simirnov, summed-up
the plight of the working class consumer in Russia prior to break-up of the Soviet Union.
He said, "In Russia we used to pretend to work, but that was alright, the government
only used to pretend to pay us!"
127
Shortage is caused by an effective price ceiling (the maximum price you can
charge for the product). Effective, in this sense, means that the government can and
does actively enforce the price ceiling. With the exception of the Second World War,
there is little evidence that the government can effectively enforce price ceilings.
Consider the following diagram that demonstrates the effect of a price ceiling in an
otherwise purely competitive industry.
SHORTAGE
Supply
Price
Pe
Price Ceiling
Demand
Qs Qe Qd Quantity
It is interesting to consider the last time that wage and price controls were
attempted during the Carter administration. These short-lived price ceilings resulted in
producers technically complying with the price restrictions, but they frequently changed
the product. For example, warranties were no longer included in the sales price, service
was extra, delivery was extra, and where possible, the product was reduced in size. For
example, in the previous administration’s failed wage and price controls (Nixon) candy
bars were made smaller and they put fewer M & Ms in the package and the price for
these treats was not changed – effectively cutting costs, but not price, hence increasing
the profit margin without raising the price of the candy. The lesson is simple, if
government is going to control prices, they must be prepared to control virtually all other
aspects of doing business.
128
SURPLUS
Price Supply
Price Floor
Pe
Demand
Qd Qe Qs Quantity
For a price floor to be effective it must be above the competitive equilibrium price.
Notice that at the floor price Qd is less than Qs, the distance between Qd and Qs is the
amount of the surplus. Minimum wages are the best known examples of price floors
and will be discussed in greater detail in Chapter 11.
Implicit in these analyses is the fact that without government we could have
neither shortage or surplus. In large measure, the suspicion of government is because
it has the power to create these sorts of peculiar market situations. Even with the
power of government to enforce law, the only way that a shortage or surplus could
occur is if the price ceiling or the price floor were effective.
As intuitively pleasing as these analyses are, they are only models, and these
models are based on assumptions that are not very good approximations of reality. In
Chapter 8 the analysis of a purely competitive market is offered. What this chapter
presents is the industry in pure competition, which is based on assumptions that do not
exist in reality. The assumptions are (1) perfect information about all past, and future
prices, (2) no barriers to entry or exit from the market, (3) no non-price competition
(advertising etc.), (4) atomized competition (so many suppliers and consumers that
none can appreciably affect price or quantity), and (5) there is a standardized product
(corn is corn is corn). If all of these assumptions accurately represent reality, then the
firm must sell at whatever price is established in the industry. To sell at a lower price
denies the firm revenue it could have otherwise earned, and to sell at a higher price
would mean the firm could sell nothing. In other words, the competitive industry impose
price discipline on all of the firms that together comprise that competitive industry.
129
Part of the controversy in almost any discussion of microeconomic activity is
whether the results of policy can be predicted by the simple supply and demand model.
Often the results of the simple supply and demand diagram are not bad rough
approximations of reality – but remember that it is only a rough approximation – based
on assumptions that are not very accurate depictions of reality. However, more often
imperfect market models are more accurate approximations of reality – because one or
more the assumptions underpinning those models more accurately reflects reality. One
must be careful in applying these models, and in policy debates concerning these
models. To the extent that the assumptions are not fulfilled, then the results may not be
accurate.
The real value of the simple supply and demand model is to provide a beginning
point for coming to understand how markets really work. In most respects the simple
supply and demand model is little more than the beginning point for constructing one of
the more realistic market models. Pure monopoly, monopolistic competition and
oligopoly are, in some important respects, refinements from the purely competitive
market model.
KEY CONCEPTS
Market
Equilibrium
Law of Demand
Demand schedule
Utility
Marginal Utility
Diminishing Marginal Utility
Income Effect
Substitution Effect
Demand Curve
Determinants of Demand
Tastes & Preferences
Number of Consumers
Money Income of Consumers
Prices of Related Goods
Substitutes
Complements
Expectations
130
CHAPTER 5
The purpose of this chapter is to extend the supply and demand analysis
presented in the previous chapter. Specifically, this chapter will develop the methods
employed by economists to measure consumer responsiveness to price changes -- the
price elasticity of demand. Other topics examined in this chapter are the price elasticity
of supply, cross-elasticities, the income elasticity of demand and the interest elasticity of
demand.
Business decisions concerning prices are not always a simple matter of adding
some margin to the cost of production of the commodity (cost-plus pricing). Suppliers
will wish to obtain the most revenue the market will bear from the sales of their products
– in other words, maximize their profits. It is therefore necessary for business to have
some idea of what the market will bear, and that is where the price elasticity of demand
enters the picture in business decision-making.
There are three methods that are used to measure the price elasticity of demand,
these are; (1) the price elasticity coefficient (midpoints formula), (2) the total revenue
test, and (3) a simple examination of the demand curve. Each of these will be
examined in turn, in the following paragraphs.
Elasticity Coefficient
The elasticity coefficient is a number calculated using price and quantity data
to determine how responsive consumers are to changes in the price of a commodity.
The elasticity coefficient may be calculated in two distinct ways. Point elasticity is
134
measuring responsiveness at a specific point along a demand curve. The other
method is using the mid-point of the difference in the price and the mid-point in the
difference of the quantity numbers. Because the midpoints formula cuts down on the
confusion of which prices and quantities are to be used, it is the only coefficient we will
use in this course.
Calculating the elasticity coefficient will yield a specific number. The value of that
number provides the answer as to whether demand is price elastic or price inelastic.
Elastic demand means that the consumers' quantities demanded respond (more than
proportionately) to changes in price; with elastic demand the coefficient is more than
one. Inelastic demand means that the consumers' quantities demanded do not respond
very much to changes in price; with inelastic demand the coefficient is less than
one. Unit elastic demand means that the consumers' quantity demanded respond
proportionately to change in price; with unit elastic demand the coefficient is exactly
one.
What this equation states is illustrated in the graph below. The midpoint between
price one (P1) and price two (P2) is labeled Midpoint along the price axis and M on the
quantity axis.
Price
P1
Midpoint
P2
Demand
Quantity
Q1 M Q2
135
On the graph this number is the difference between Q1 and Q2 divided by the
distance between the origin and the point labeled M on the quantity axis for the
numerator and the difference between P1 and P2 divided the distance between the
origin and the point labeled midpoint on the price axis for denominator. The ratio of the
numerator to the denominator on this graph is the same number yielded by the
equation.
Examining the demand curve can also provide clues concerning the price
elasticity of demand. A perfectly vertical demand curve indicates that the quantity
demanded will be exactly the same, regardless of price. This type of demand curve is
called a perfectly inelastic demand curve. A perfectly horizontal demand curve
indicates that consumers will have almost any quantity demanded, but only at that price.
This is called a perfectly elastic demand curve. Perfectly unit elastic demand curves
are not linear, they have slopes that vary across ranges.
Demand
Quantity Quantity
Perfectly Elastic and Perfectly Inelastic Demand Curves
There is a trick to remembering inelastic and elastic demand. Notice in the
above graphs that the perfectly elastic demand curve is horizontal, (add one more
horizontal line at the top of the price axis and it will look like an E). The perfectly
inelastic demand curve is vertical (looks like an I). If you have problems remembering
the concept of inelastic or elastic demand you need only draw the curves above and
observe what happens to the quantity demanded when the price changes. In the case
of perfectly inelastic demand consumers will buy exactly the same quantity of a product
without regard for its price. In the case of a perfectly elastic demand curve, if producers
raise the price of the product, then they will sell nothing.
Slope and elasticity are two different concepts. With linear demand curves,
elasticity changes along the demand curve, however its slope does not. Elasticity is
136
concerned with responses in one variable to changes in the other variable. The slope
of the curve is concerned with values of the respective variables at each position along
the curve (i.e., its' shape and direction).
Price
Elastic Unit
Demand
Inelastic
Quantity
Total
Revenue
Total Revenue
Quantity
The total revenue curve in the bottom graph is plotted by multiplying price and quantity
to obtain total revenue and then plotting total revenue against quantity. In examining
the above graphs, notice that as total revenue is increasing, demand is elastic. When
the total revenue curve flattens-out at the top then demand becomes unit elastic, and
when total revenue falls demand is inelastic. In other words, moving from left to right on
the demand curve, as price and total revenue move in the opposite direction demand is
price elastic, and when price and total revenue move in the same direction demand is
price inelastic.
The total revenue test uses the relation between the total revenue curve and the
demand curve to determine the price elasticity of demand. In general, price and total
revenue will move in the same direction of the demand is price inelastic (hence
consumers are unresponsive in quantity purchased when price changes) and move in
opposite directions if price elastic (consumers’ quantities being responsive to price
changes).
137
Consider the following numerical example:
_____________________________________________________________________
_____________________________________________________________________
1 7 7
>+5 Elastic
2 6 12
>+3 Elastic
3 5 15
>+1 Elastic
4 4 16
>-1 Inelastic
5 3 15
>-3 Inelastic
6 2 12
>-5 Inelastic
7 1 7
_____________________________________________________________________
_____________________________________________________________________
The following determinants of the price elasticity of demand will determine how
responsive the quantity demanded by consumers is to changes in price. The
determinants of the price elasticity of demand are; (1) substitutability of other
commodities, (2) the proportion of income spent on the commodity, (3) whether
the commodity is a luxury or a necessity, and (4) the amount of time that a
consumer can postpone the purchase.
If there are no close substitutes then the demand for the commodity will be price
inelastic, ceteris paribus. If there are substitutes then consumers can switch their
purchasing habits in the case of a price increase, but if there are no substitutes then
138
consumers are more likely to buy even if price goes up. For example, if the price of
Pepsi goes up, then certain consumers will buy Coke, if the price of Coke has not
increased, hence the demand for Pepsi is likely to be elastic.
All other things equal, the higher the proportion of income spent for the
commodity more price elastic will be the demand. Most home owners are familiar with
how this determinant works. The demand for single family dwellings is likely to be more
elastic than the demand for apartments, because a higher proportion of your income will
be spent on housing when you own your home.
Commodities that are viewed as luxuries typically have price elastic demand, and
commodities that are necessities have price inelastic demand. There is simply no
substitute for a insulin, if you are an insulin dependent diabetic. Because insulin is a
necessity for which there is no substitute, the demand will be price inelastic.
The time frames for producers will be discussed in more detail in Chapter 7 as
they pertain to a firm's cost structure. However, it is important to understand the basic
idea behind this classification of time as it relates to price elasticity. The market period
is defined to be that period in which the producer can vary nothing, therefore the supply
is perfectly inelastic. The long-run is the period in which the producer can vary
everything, therefore the supply is perfectly elastic. The short-run is the period in which
plant and equipment cannot be varied, but most other factors' usage can be varied,
therefore it depends on a producers capital - intensity as to how elastic supply is at any
particular point.
139
Other Elasticities
There are three other standard applications of the elasticity of demand. The
cross elasticity of demand, the income elasticity of demand, and the interest rate
elasticity of demand. Each of these will be examined, in turn, in the remaining
paragraphs of this chapter.
For example, as the price of coke increases, then consumers may purchase
proportionately more Pepsi products. In such a case, the cross elasticity of demand of
Pepsi to the price of coke would be termed elastic. The equation for the cross elasticity
of demand described here is presented below.
140
The automobile companies rarely reduce prices for their vehicles, but rather, GM,
Ford and Chrysler will offer incentives. Rebates, which are temporary reductions in
price, and attractive financing rates are the hooks offered to get the consumer in the
showroom and into the new car. In May of 2003 all of the American producers were
offering zero percent financing on all but a very few of their vehicles, and even some of
the European and Japanese producers were following suite with either very low rates,
or zero percent financing. The interest rate elasticity formula is (where interest rate is
“r”):
Interest rate sensitivity can also be understood from another perspective. The
total cost of a commodity is not just its price, but also what must be paid to borrow
money to purchase that item. With modern views of instant gratification, it is rare for
someone to save to purchase a house, or any other big ticket item, what is more
common is to borrow the money, buy the item, and make installment payments.
Therefore the interest charges are a part of the total cost of acquiring that big ticket item
– hence consumer sensitivity to interest rates when buying a house or a car.
It is also noteworthy, that purely competitive firms are price takers, and it is the
imperfectly competitive firm that has a pricing policy. What is often referred to as
“pricing power” in the business press, means the ability to take advantage of the price
elasticity of demand or one of the other elasticities examined here – hence implying
some market structure, hence market power not otherwise identified in the model of
pure competition.
141
CHAPTER 7
Costs of Production
The purpose of this chapter is to examine the production costs of a firm. The first
section develops the economic concepts of production necessary for understanding the
cost structure of a firm. The second section presents the models of short-run costs.
The final section develops the long-run average total cost curve and discusses its
implications for the strategic management of a business.
An economist's view of costs includes both explicit and implicit costs. Explicit
costs are accounting costs, and implicit costs are the opportunity costs of an allocation
of resources (i.e., business decisions). Accountants subtract total cost from total
revenue and arrive a total accounting profits. An economist, however, would include in
the total costs of the firm the profits that could have been made in the next best
business opportunity (e.g., the opportunity cost). Therefore, there is a significant
difference in how accountants' and economists' view profits B economic profits versus
accounting profits.
For the purposes of economic analysis, a normal profit includes the cost of the
lost opportunity of the next best alternative allocation of the firm=s resources. In a purely
competitive world, a business should be able to cover their costs of production and the
opportunity cost of the next best alternative (and nothing more in the long-run). In an
accounting sense there is no benchmark to determine whether the resource allocation
was wise. Instead various financial ratios are used to determine how the firm has done
with respect to similarly situated companies.
154
Time Periods Revisited
In the market period, all costs are fixed costs (nothing can be varied). In the
short-run, there are both fixed and variable costs observed. Generally, plant,
equipment, and technology are fixed, and things like labor, electricity, and materials can
still be varied. In the long-run everything is variable. That is, the plant, equipment, and
even the business into which you put productive assets can all be changed. In the
long-run, even the country in which the business is located can be changed. Because
everything is fixed in the market period, this period is of little interest in economic
analysis. Therefore, economists typically begin their analysis of costs with the short-run
and proceed to examine the operation of the firm and the industry. The long-run is of
interest because it is also the planning horizon for the business.
Production
Another view of the short-run cost structure is that fixed costs are those that must
be paid whether the firm produces anything or not. Variable costs are called variable
because they increase or decrease with the level of production. Therefore to
understand short-run costs, you must first understand production.
Total product or total output is the total number of units of production obtained
from the productive resources employed. Average product is total product divided by
the number of units of the variable factor employed. Marginal product is the change in
total product associated with a change in units of a variable factor of production.
As a firm increases its output it normally makes more efficient use of its available
capital. However, with a fixed level of available capital as variable factors are added to
the production process, there is a point where the increases in total output begin to
diminish. The law of diminishing returns is the fact that as you add variable
factors of production to a fixed factor, at some point, the increases in total output
begin to become smaller. In fact, it is possible, at some point, that further additions in
the units variable factors to a fixed level of capital could actually reduce the total output
of the firm. This is called the uneconomic range of production. In reality, most firms
come to realize that their total additions to total output diminish, long before they begin
to experience negative returns to additions to their workforce or other variable factors.
155
The following diagram provides a graphical presentation of total, average, and
marginal products for a hypothetical firm.
The top graph shows total product. After total product reaches its maximum
marginal product where marginal product changes from positive to negative (first
derivative is zero, second derivative is negative). When the total product curve reaches
its maximum, increased output results in negative marginal product. The maximum on
the marginal product curve is also associated with the first inflection point (the
acceleration or where the curve becomes steeper) on the total product curve. The
ranges of marginal returns are identified on the above graphs.
The beginning point in developing the cost structure of a firm is to examine total
costs in the short run. Total costs (TC) are equal to variable costs (VC) plus fixed costs
(FC).
TC = VC + FC
Variable costs are those costs that can be varied in the short-run, i.e., the cost of
hiring labor. Fixed costs are those costs that cannot be varied in the short-run, i.e.,
plant (interest). Therefore, total costs consist of a fixed component and a variable
component.
156
The fixed cost curve is a horizontal line. These costs are illustrated with a
horizontal line because they do not vary with quantity of output. The variable cost curve
has a positive slope because it varies with output. Notice that the total cost curve has
the same shape as the variable cost curve, but is above the variable cost curve by a
distance equal to the amount of the fixed cost. This is because we added fixed cost
(the horizontal line) to variable cost (the positively sloped line).
From the total, variable and fixed cost curves we can obtain other relations.
These are the marginal cost, and the total, variable, and fixed costs relation to various
levels of output (averages).
Average total cost (ATC) is total cost (TC) divided by quantity of output (Q),
average variable cost (AVC) is variable cost (VC) divided by quantity of output (Q), and
average fixed cost (AFC) is fixed cost (FC) divided by quantity of output (Q). Marginal
cost (MC) is the change (denoted by the Greek symbol delta), in total cost (TC) divided
by the change in the quantity of output (Q).
157
These relations are presented in equation form below:
ATC = TC/Q
AVC = VC/Q
AFC = FC/Q
Please notice that the average fixed cost approaches zero as quantity increases.
This occurs because a constant is being divided by increasingly large numbers.
Average total cost is the summation of the average fixed and average variable cost
curves. Because average fixed cost approaches zero, the difference between average
variable cost and average total cost also approaches zero (the difference between ATC
and AVC is AFC). The marginal cost curve intersects both the average total cost and
average variable cost curves at their respective minimums. In other words, as marginal
cost is below average total (and average variable) cost the average function is falling to
meet marginal cost. As marginal cost is rising above the average function then average
158
total (and average variable) cost are increasing.
The following graph relates average and marginal product to average variable
Notice that at the maximum point on the marginal product curve, marginal cost
reaches a minimum. Where marginal cost equals average variable cost, the marginal
product curve intersects the average product curve. In other words, the cost structure
of the firm mirrors the engineering principles giving rise to the firm=s production, hence
its costs.
In the long-run all costs are variable. In other words, a firm can vary its plant,
equipment, technology and any of the factors that were either fixed or variable in the
short-run. Therefore, anything that is technologically feasible is available to this firm in
the long-run. Further, any short-run average total cost curve (consistent with any size of
operation) could be selected for use in the long-run.
159
The long-run average total cost curve (LRATC) is therefore a mapping of all
minimum points of all possible short-run average total cost curves (allowing technology
and all factors of production (i.e., costs) to vary). The enveloping of these short-run
total cost curves map all potential scales of operation in the long-run. Therefore, the
LRATC is also called the planning horizon for the firm.
The shape of the LRATC is dependent upon the available resources and
technology that a firm can utilize to produce a given commodity. The downward sloping
range of the LRATC is due to economies of scale, the upward sloping range of the
LRATC is due to diseconomies of scale, and if there is a flat range at the minimum point
of the LRATC this is called a range of constant returns to scale.
Economies of scale are benefits obtained from a company becoming large and
diseconomies of scale are additional costs inflicted because a firm has become too
large. The causes of economies of scale are that as a firm becomes larger it may be
able to utilize labor and managerial specialization more effectively, capital more
effectively, and may be able to profitably use by-products from its operations.
Diseconomies of scale result from the organization becoming too large to effectively
manage and inefficiencies developing.
Constant returns to scale are large ranges of operations where the firm's size
matters little. In very capital intensive operations that must cover some peak demand,
the size of the firm may matter very little. Several public utilities, such as electric
generating companies, telephone company, and water and sewer service have
160
relatively large ranges of constant returns to scale.
Where the LRATC curve reaches its minimum, this is called the minimum
efficient scale (size of operation). Minimum efficient scale is the smallest size of
operations where the firm can minimize its long-run average costs. Minimum efficient
scale varies significantly by commodity produced and technology. For example, the
minimum efficient scale in agriculture in the Great Lakes area for dairy operations is
relatively small (in the $200,000 range). Minimum efficient scale for wheat farmers in
the Great Plains may be as large as $1,000,000.
Minimum efficient scale is the point on the LRATC where it reaches its minimum.
If that happens to be at the beginning of a long range of constant costs, it is the first
point (on the left of the range) where costs are at their minimum. Remember, that
technical efficiency requires that a firm produce at where it has attained minimum total
long-run costs.
Where minimum efficient scale is very large for capital intensive operations, it
may be more cost effective to permit one company to spread its fixed costs over a very
large number of consumers, rather than have several competing firms suffer the fixed
costs of a minimum efficient scale and have to share a customer base. There are
several industries that are very capital intensive and require large initial investments to
operate. These types of firms are frequently natural monopolies. Railroads, electric
generating companies, and air lines requires tens of millions of dollars in fixed costs.
KEY CONCEPTS
Normal Profit
Next Best Alternative
161
CHAPTER 8
Pure Competition
Chapter 4 developed the supply and demand diagram. The simple supply and
demand diagram is the model of a perfectly competitive industry. That model will be
revisited and extended in this chapter.
The purpose of this chapter is to introduce models of the firm that are not purely
competitive. After a brief introduction to imperfectly competitive models we will turn our
attention to the purely competitive industry and firm. In particular, this chapter will
develop the model of the perfectly competitive firm, examine its relation to the industry,
and then offer some critical evaluation of this important paradigm.
There are several models of market structure. In the product market, the two
extremes are perfect competition and pure monopoly. This chapter will examine pure
competition and the following chapter examines monopoly. However, there are
intermediate market structures. These intermediate market structures are oligopoly and
monopolistic competition.
(2) there is complete freedom of entry and exit into and from this market,
(5) firms in this industry must accept the price determined in the industry.
Purely competitive firms and industries do not exist in reality. Probably as close
as the real world comes to the competitive ideal is agriculture, during the period in which
this industry was dominated by the relatively small family farms prior to World War II.
165
The assumptions in pure monopoly are:
(1) there is one seller that supplies a large number of independent buyers,
166
The assumptions upon which the model of oligopoly are founded are:
(1) that there are few sellers (generally a dozen or less), these firms often
collude or implicitly cooperate through such practices as price
leadership,
Total, average and marginal product were developed with the various cost curves
in Chapter 7. The missing piece of the puzzle is revenue. Because a purely competitive
firm sells its output at the one price determined in the industry, price does not change as
the quantity sold increases. In other words, the demand curve is horizontal, or perfectly
elastic. The result is that average revenue is equal marginal revenue, and both of these
are equal to price. Further , total revenue is P x Q which is the total area under the
demand curve for the purely competitive firm.
167
The model of the purely competitive industry is the simple supply and demand
diagram you mastered in Chapter 4. The simple supply and demand diagram is a
representation of the aggregation of a large number of independent firms and
consumers. This model is revisited below:
Supply
Price
Pe
Demand
Qe Quantity
The firm in perfect competition is just one of thousands that are summed to arrive
at the industry levels of output and price. Because of the atomized competition, it a firm
charges a higher price that the industry it will sell nothing because consumers can
obtain exactly the same commodity at a lower price elsewhere. If the firm charges a
price lower that the price established in the industry it is irrational and will lose revenue
it could have otherwise had. Therefore, a firm operating in a perfectly competitive
industry has no choice save to sell its output at the industry established price. Because
the firm sells at the single price established in the industry it has a perfectly elastic
demand curve. (In other words, it is horizontal and not downward sloping).
168
The demand curve for the perfectly competitive firm is illustrated below:
Price
D = MR = AR = P
Quantity
Because the firm is a price taker, meaning that it charges the same price across all
quantities of output, marginal revenue is always equal to price, and average revenue
will always be equal to price. Therefore the demand curve intersects the price axis and
is horizontal (perfectly elastic) at the price determined in the industry.
Establishing the price in the industry is simply setting the equilibrium in the
familiar supply and demand diagram, and that is the price at which the firm is obliged to
sell its output. The following diagram illustrates how this is done:
Pe
D=MR=AR
Q Q
169
Again, the price is established by the interaction of supply and demand in the
industry (Pe) and the quantity exchanged in the industry is the summation of all of the
quantities sold by the firms in the industry. However, this yields little information save
what price will be charged and what quantity the industry produce. To determine what
each firm will produce and what profits each firm will earn, we must add the cost
structure (developed in the previous chapter).
Economic profits are total revenues in excess of total costs. Remember from
Chapter 7, that profits from the next best alternative allocation of resources is included
in the total costs of the firm. In this short-run it plausible that some firms in pure
competition can exact an economic profit from consumers, but because of freedom of
entry, the economic profit will attract new firms to the industry, hence increasing supply,
and thereby lowering price and wiping out the short-run economic profits.
The following diagram adds the costs structure to the purely competitive firm’s
demand curve and with this information it is possible to determine the profits that this
firm makes:
MC
Price
ATC
AVC
Qe Quantity
The firm produces at where MC = MR, this establishes Qe. At the point where
MC = MR the average total cost (ATC) is below the demand curve (AR) and therefore
costs are less than revenue, and an economic profit is made. The reason for this is that
the opportunity cost of the next best allocation of the firm's productive resources is
already added into the firm's ATC.
170
substantial. The following diagram illustrates the purely competitive firm making a
normal profit:
MC
Price ATC
AVC
D=MR
Qe Quantity
The case where a firm is making a normal profit is illustrated above. Where MC
= MR is where the firm produces, and at that point ATC is exactly tangent to the
demand curve. Because the ATC includes the profits from the next best alternative
allocation of resources this firm is making a normal profit.
A firm in pure competition can also make an economic loss. The following
diagram shows a firm in pure competition that is making an economic loss:
MC
ATC
Price
AVC
Economic Losses
D=MR
Qe Quantity
The case of an economic loss is illustrated above. The firm produces where MC
= MR, however, at that level of production the ATC is above the demand curve, in other
words, costs exceed revenues and the firm is making a loss.
171
Even though the firm is making a loss it may still operate. The relation of
average total cost with average revenue determines the amount of profit or loss, but we
to know what relation average revenue has with average variable cost to determine
whether the firm will continue in business. In the above case, the firm continues to
operate because it can cover all of its variable costs and have something left to pay at
least a part of its fixed costs. It is shuts down it would lose all of its fixed costs,
therefore the rational approach is to continue to operate to minimize losses. Therefore,
the profit maximizing rule of producing at where MC = MR is also the rule to determine
where a firm can minimize any losses it may suffer.
MC ATC
Price AVC
Qe Quantity
In the case above you can see that the AVC is above the demand curve at where
MC=MR, therefore the firm cannot even cover its variable costs and will shut down to
minimize its losses. If the firm continues to operate it cannot cover its variable costs
and will accrue losses in excess of the fixed costs. If the firm shuts-down, all that is lost
is the fixed costs. Therefore the firm should shut-down in order to minimize its losses.
What may not be intuitively obvious is that this analysis determines the industry
supply curve. Because firms cannot operate along the marginal cost curve below the
average variable cost curve, the firm’s supply curve is its marginal cost curve above
average variable cost. To obtain the industry’s supply curve one needs only sum all of
the firms’ marginal cost curves about their average variable cost curves.
172
CHAPTER 9
Pure Monopoly
The purpose of this chapter is to examine the pure monopoly model in the
product market. Because monopolies are price givers, there are significant differences
between monopolies and competitive firms, these differences will be examined in details
in this chapter. Once the monopoly model is mastered, it will be critically evaluated.
Further, the rate regulation of monopolies will be examined and critically evaluated.
The assumptions upon which the monopoly model is based were presented in
Chapter 8. However, a quick review of those assumptions is worthwhile here. The
assumptions of the monopoly model are:
(1) there is a single seller (or a few sellers who collude, hence a cartel),
In the purely competitive analysis, there were two different models, one model for
the industry, in which the interaction of supply and demand established the market price
and quantity. The second model was that of the firm, the firm faced a perfectly elastic
demand curve, in which demand, price, average revenue and marginal revenue were all
the same. However, in the analysis of a monopoly there is but one model. The firm, in
monopoly, is the industry (by definition). Because the firm is the industry it therefore
179
faces a downward sloping demand curve, which is also the average revenue curve for
the firm (hence the industry).
If the firm wants to sell more it must lower its price therefore marginal revenue is also
downward sloping, but has twice the slope of the demand curve. Remember when you
lower price the average revenue falls, but not as fast as the marginal, and if the average
revenue is a linear (as it is here, which is smooth, and continuously differentiable) the
there is a necessary relationship between the slope of the average and marginal
functions.
Price
El
as
ti c
Ra
ng
e
In
ela
st i
cR
an
ge
Marginal Demand
Revenue
Quantity
The point where the marginal revenue curve intersects the quantity axis is of
significance; this point is where total revenue is maximized. Further, the point on the
demand curve associated with where MR = Q is the point on the demand curve of unit
price elastic demand; to the left along the demand curve is the elastic range, and to the
right is the inelastic range (see Chapter 5 for a review of the relation between marginal
revenue and price elasticity of demand).
Unlike the purely competitive model here is no supply curve in an industry which
is a monopoly. The monopolist decides how much to produce using the profit
maximizing rule; or where MC = MR. In this sense, the monopolist is a price dictator,
in that it is the cost structure, together with the change in total revenue with respect to
change in quantity sold that directs the monopolist’s pricing behavior, rather than the
interaction of the monopolist’s supply schedule, with the demand schedule of
consumers (demand curve). With this information we can discover more about the
monopoly model.
180
competition if there is an economic profit, that profit is a signal to other assets to enter
the market. Because there are no barriers to entry into a purely competitive industry,
the supply curve increase (shifts right) as these newly attracted resources enter the
market – hence driving down the market price in the industry, and eliminating the
economic profit.
Price
Pe MC
Economic ATC
Profit
MR
Qe Quantity
The above diagram shows the economic profits that can be maintained in the long run
because of the barriers to entry into this industry. The monopolist produces where MC
= MR (where MC intersects MR), but the price charged is all the market will bear, that
is, the price on the demand curve that is immediately above the intersection of MC =
MR. The rectangle mapped out by the ATC, the indicator over the price index, the
origin, and Qm are the total costs, the rectangle mapped out by the demand curve, QM,
the origin, and Pm is the total revenue, and the difference between these rectangles is
economic profits.
On the other hand, there is nothing in the analysis that requires any given
monopolist will be profitable. In fact, a monopolist can operate at an economic loss, the
same as a competitive firm can.
181
Price MC
ATC
Economic Loss AVC
Pe
MR
Qe Quantity
This monopolist is making an economic loss. The ATC is above the demand
curve (AR) at where MC = MR (the loss is the labeled rectangle). However, because
AVC is below the demand curve at where MC = MR the firm will not shut down so as to
minimize its losses. The firm can pay back a portion of its fixed costs by continuing to
operate at this level because the AVC is still below the demand curve. As you will
remember from the discussion in Chapter 8, when AVC is above the demand curve the
firm should shut down to prevent throwing good money after bad.
There are several implications of the monopoly model; many of which lead to
criticisms of monopoly on issues of both technical and allocative efficiency. The prices
and output determined in the monopoly are not consistent with allocative efficiency
criteria. In monopoly there are too many resources allocated to production of this
product, for which we receive too little output as illustrated by comparison with the
competitive solution, the dotted line (discussed below). Consequently, because of the
barriers to entry, the price for this product is too high – hence allocatively inefficient.
182
Price
Pm MC
Economic ATC
Profit
Pc
MR
Qm Qc Quantity
The above graph shows the profit maximizing monopolist, Pm is the price the
monopoly commands in this market and Qm is the quantity exchanged in this market.
However, where MC = D is where a perfectly competitive industry produces and this is
associated with Pc and Qc. The monopolist therefore produces less and charges more
than a purely competitive industry.
This does not mean that monopolists are pure evil – in an economic sense.
Sometimes a monopolist is in the best interests of society (besides the natural
monopoly situation). Often a company must expend substantial resources on research
and development (i.e., pharmaceutical firms). If these types of firms were forced to
permit free use of their technological developments (hence no monopoly power) then
the economic incentive to develop new technology and products would be eliminated –
hence economic irrationality would have to prevail for the technological progress we
have come to expect in the beginning of the twenty-first century.
183
Regulated Monopoly
Because there are natural monopoly market situations it is in the public interest
to permit monopolies, but traditionally in the United States they are regulated with
respect to price. The purpose of the rate regulation was to ensure that the public would
not suffer price gouging as a result of the monopoly position of the firms. Examples of
regulated natural monopolies are electric utilities, cable TV companies, and telephone
companies (local).
Throughout the 1980s and 1990s, up through 2002, there was substantial
deregulation of the power industry, cable TV industry, and telecom. In the 1980s ATT
was broken-up into several local telecom companies, i.e., Verizon, Southwestern Bell,
Ameritech, and US West, among other, the long lines company (ATT) and Bell Labs
(Lucent). The idea was to permit competition in long distance and local service. What
happened was far different. The local providers had much invested in microwave
towers, switches, and telephone lines – there would be charges permitted for the use of
these assets by competitors, and what resulted was poorer service, at higher prices in
most areas. In the summer of 2001, California consumers got a taste of what Enron
could do in selling power to local public utilities. Consumers were victims of
unscrupulous business practices that resulted in billions of dollars in overcharges that
cannot be recovered.
The problem with regulating the prices that monopolists can charge is that there
are several competing goals that can be accomplished through rate regulation. If
allocative efficiency is the goal, then the monopolist should be constrained to charge a
price where MC = D or the social optimum. If technical efficiency is the goal then
some argue that the monopolist’s minimum total cost should be the basis for the rate
regulation. If we are concerned about consistently and reliably having the product of the
monopolist available, at a reasonable price, then it might be more sensible to regulate
the monopolist to charge a price at where ATC = D, or the fair rate of return. So
regulatory agencies have alternatives as to where to regulate any monopolists within
their jurisdiction. The potential prices at which a monopolist could be regulated,
and the potential results of those price levels, is called the dilemma or regulation.
This dilemma has presented the opportunity for considerable debate about whether
rate regulation is appropriate, and if so, what sorts of regulation should occur.
Consider the following diagram, this is a monopolist that is being regulated at the
social optimum (MC = D):
184
Price
MC
ATC
Pr
MR
Qr Quantity
This firm is being regulated at the social optimum, in other words, what the
industry would produce if it were a purely competitive industry. The price it is required
to charge is also the competitive solution. However, notice the ATC is below the
demand curve at the social optimum which means this firm is making an economic
profit. It is also possible with this solution that the firm could be making an economic
loss (if ATC is above demand) or even shut down (if AVC is above demand).
Consider the following diagram of a monopolist that is being regulated at the fair
rate of return:
Price
MC
ATC
Pr
D
MR
Qr Quantity
The fair rate of return enforces a normal profit because the firm must price its
output and produce where ATC is equal to demand. This eliminates economic profits
and the risk of loss or of even putting the monopolist out of business. Virtually every
185
APPENDIX B
SELECTED BIBLIOGRAPHY
(BOOK LIST)
Becker, Gary, Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1993
Friedman, Milton and Rose D. Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1972.
Galbraith, John Kenneth, The Great Crash of 1929. New York: Houghton - Mifflin,
Company, 1997.*
Heilbroner, Robert L., The Worldly Philosophers, seventh edition. New York: Simon and
Schuster, 1999.*
Higham, Charles, Trading with the Enemy: The Nazi-American Money Plot - 1933-1949.
New York: Barnes and Nobel Books, 1983.
Hilgert, Raymond L. and David A. Dilts, Cases in Collective Bargaining and Industrial
Relations, tenth edition. New York: McGraw-Hill / Irwin, 2002.
Manchester, William, The Arms of Krupp: 1587-1968. New York: Bantam Books, 1970.*
Marx, Karl, Das Kapital, New York: International Publishers, Incorporated, 1982.*
North, Douglas C. Economic Growth in the United States: 1790-1860. Seattle: DIANE
Publishing Co., 2003.
237