T N T C: HE EW AX Redits
T N T C: HE EW AX Redits
T N T C: HE EW AX Redits
Mike Brewer
Financial support from the ESRC-funded Centre for the Microeconomic Analysis of Public
Policy at IFS is gratefully acknowledged. Data from the Family Resources Survey are used
with the permission of the Department for Work and Pensions. The author is very grateful to
Stuart Adam, Robert Chote, Michal Myck and Howard Reed for comments on earlier drafts,
to Tom Clark and Howard Reed, who programmed the new tax credits in the IFS tax and
benefit model, and to Judith Payne for copy-editing. None of these people or institutions bears
any responsibility for the views expressed here.
What is new?
The child tax credit provides income-related support to the main carer. By
April 2004, around 90% of families with dependent children should be entitled
to it.7
The working tax credit provides in-work support to around 1 million single
people and couples with or without children in low-paid work.8
Both credits were introduced in April 2003. As described above, families will
continue to be entitled to child allowances and family premium in IS or
income-related JSA during 200304, unless they have already claimed the
child tax credit. The rates of IS were altered in October 2002 to ensure that
these families did not lose out during this transition period.
What is staying?
Child benefit is a universal, non-means-tested payment. All 7 million families
with dependent children in the UK are entitled to receive it. It is unaffected by
the reforms.
Those without children who might be entitled to the working tax credit do
not tend to be in poverty on standard government definitions (i.e. in
households with income below 60% of the national median).
As shown later, the working tax credit has an ambiguous impact on work
incentives, improving the reward to work for some but worsening it for
others.
This suggests that the working tax credit may be aimed more at raising the
income of those on low incomes in a way that does not create any
disincentives to work.
Families with annual gross incomes below 13,230 are entitled to the full
amount. Incomes above 13,230 reduce entitlement to the per-child elements
at the rate of 37p in the pound until a family is left with just the family element
(this happens at 17,135 p.a. for a one-child family and at 21,040 p.a. for a
two-child family).14 Incomes above 50,000 p.a. reduce entitlement to the
family element at the rate of 6.7p in the pound, meaning that families with
children with incomes over 58,134 (or 66,269 if they have a child under 1)
will be entitled to child benefit only.15
Together, this means that:
around 90% of families with children are entitled to some child tax credit;
around 50% of families are entitled to both the per-child element and the
family element;
The government has promised to increase the per-child element at least in line
with average earnings growth until the end of this Parliament. This means that
the rate from April 2004 will be around 2.3% higher in real terms than the rate
in 2003 if earnings rise in line with their trend of recent years.17 This, though,
is a much smaller annual increase in child-related payments than families saw
between 1996 and 2003, and equates to a real increase in incomes of only
0.7% for couples with two children on income support or income-related
jobseekers allowance (0.8% for a lone parent with two children).18
Couples with or without children and lone parents are entitled to a credit of
3,025 p.a. (approximately 58.15 a week).
Families with children where all adults are working, caring or disabled can
receive help with approved childcare costs. This operates in the same way
as the childcare tax credit under the WFTC, paying 70% of approved
childcare costs below a generous maximum (135 a week for those with
one child under 16, 200 for others).19
There are extra amounts for some adults with disabilities and for people
over 50 returning to work.
Families with annual incomes below 5,060 are entitled to the full amount.
Incomes above this level reduce entitlement at the rate of 37p in the pound.
Entitlement is exhausted at around 10,857 p.a. for a single person without
children, 13,230 for a lone parent or a couple with children working parttime, and 14,911 for a lone parent or a couple with or without children
working full-time. It is theoretically possible for a family with children
spending the maximum allowed on childcare (10,430 a year) to be entitled to
the working tax credit at incomes of 34,586.
Figure 1. Financial support for a family with one child under the outgoing
system ( per week)
120
100
80
60
40
20
IS
WFTC adult
WFTC child
0
0
200
400
600
800
1,000
1,200
Gross income
Notes: IS is adult allowance, F is the family premium and C is the child allowance in income
support or income-related JSA. The graph uses hypothetical April 2003 rates for the WFTC
and the childrens tax credit assuming the usual uprating rules. It does not show the childcare
tax credit, housing benefit or council tax benefit, and it ignores extra support paid in the first
year of a childs life.
Figure 2. Financial support for a family with one child under the new tax
credits ( per week)
120
100
80
60
Working
IS tax credit
Child tax
credit
40
20
Child benefit
0
0
200
400
600
800
1,000
1,200
Gross income
Notes: The new tax credits are annual systems but this graph treats them as weekly. It also
assumes that the new tax credits are implemented fully in April 2003 and that a family
qualifies for working tax credit at 16 hours of minimum-wage work (67.20 p.w.) and for the
30-hour premium at 126 p.w. It does not show the childcare tax credit, housing benefit or
council tax benefit, and it ignores extra support paid in the first year of a childs life.
Figure 3. Financial support for a couple without children under the new
tax credits ( per week)
120
100
80
IS
60
Working
tax credit
40
20
0
0
200
400
600
800
1,000
1,200
Gross income
Notes: The working tax credit is an annual system but this graph treats it as weekly. It also
assumes that a family loses entitlement to income support at 16 hours of minimum-wage work
(67.20 p.w.) and qualifies for working tax credit at 30 hours of minimum-wage work (126
p.w.). It does not show housing benefit or council tax benefit.
The structures of the new tax credits and the systems they replace are
illustrated in Figures 1, 2 and 3.
Some of the novel and most complicated aspects of the new tax credits
concern how they react to changes in families circumstances (the Appendix
contains some worked examples):
Formally, the tax credits depend on income in the current tax year. From
2004 onwards, most families will apply for or renew an award in the
summer, at which point an award will be made based on annual income in
the previous tax year (there are different arrangements for 200304:
families should already have applied, and the awards are initially based on
income in 200102).
After the end of the tax year, though, the Revenue will recalculate awards
based on peoples actual income in the tax year. Families whose income
has fallen and that are therefore entitled to more tax credit will receive the
balance due to them. Families whose income has risen and that have been
paid too much tax credit may have to pay some of the extra back, although
the first 2,500 of income changes will be disregarded when performing
this calculation. These corrections will be made either by adjusting future
awards or by one-off payments.
People can apply for the tax credits in mid-year and can ask for their
awards to be recalculated at any point. In these cases, awards will be based
on an estimate of their current-year income. To prevent manipulation of
the system, in these cases, payments will be recalculated at the end of the
year, as above, but there will be no disregard for income rises.
These features mean that the tax credits are not a pure annual system, such as
the earned income tax credit in the USA. There is a danger that this will cause
uncertainty amongst families, as people cannot be sure that they will not have
to pay back credit they are currently receiving. It also means that the amount
of tax credit being received by families in a given month may bear little
relationship to their circumstances in that month.
The government estimates that in 200405 and later years, 1 million families
will be entitled to extra tax credit and a further 750,000 families will face the
possibility of having to pay back credit to the Revenue because they
experience a rise in income of over 2,500. These 1.75 million families (a
quarter of families in Britain) do not include those whose award may change
when children enter or leave the household, nor those who experience changes
in marital or relationship status; these families will have to reapply for the tax
credits when such an event occurs.20
This problem will be worse in 200304, because awards were based on
income data that were two years out of date rather than one. Around 1 million
families (rather than 750,000) face the possibility of having to pay back credit
to the Revenue.21 This means that Summer 2004 when families awards for
200304 will be finally reconciled and awards for 200405 set to recover the
overpayments will see a crucial test of the popularity of the new tax credits.
200304
(m)
2,450
250
200405
(m)
2,300
300
However, this cost should be seen in the context of the increases in benefits
and tax credits for families with children seen so far under Labour. The total
level of central government financial support that is conditional on having
children has risen from 13.7 billion in 1997, to 19.2 billion in 2002 and
21.2 billion in 2003.24 The government estimates that 13 billion of support
will be channelled through the child tax credit,25 which means that it will
replace child benefit as the most important programme for supporting families
with children.
Amongst the 7 million families with children in Great Britain, around
4.1 million will gain and 300,000 will lose from the new tax credits (changes
of less than 50p a week have been ignored, and numbers are rounded to the
nearest 100,000).26 The majority of the gainers are families that would have
been eligible for either income support or the WFTC.
The main explanations for the changes are:
Families with incomes below 8,000 a year paid insufficient income tax to
benefit fully from the childrens tax credit. In addition, everyone on the
WFTC taper and receiving the childrens tax credit saw the tax cut that the
old credit represented partially offset by a reduction in WFTC awards. The
childrens tax credit is now the family element of the child tax credit, and
so these two sets of families gain by up to 545 a year.
Some well-off two-earner couples are worse off because the child tax
credit begins to be withdrawn when joint income exceeds 50,000,
whereas the childrens tax credit began to be withdrawn when the higher
income exceeded 34,000 regardless of the size of joint incomes. For
example, a couple with joint incomes above 50,000 but where neither
partner earns more than 34,000 is 545 a year worse off. We estimate that
around 200,000 well-off couples will lose by at least 50p a week through
this change.
For the same reason, some well-off couples are better off under the child
tax credit than under the childrens tax credit. For example, a couple where
the higher earner earns at least 42,000 but joint income is less than
50,000 is 545 a year better off. We estimate that around 600,000 welloff families will gain by at least 50p a week through this change.
Families with new-born children and low incomes gain from the extra
child tax credit for children under 1, previously only available to those
qualifying for the childrens tax credit.
Families with only dependent children aged 1619 may gain as they will
be entitled to the child tax credit whereas previously they could not claim
the childrens tax credit.
The definition of income for the new tax credits is different from that used
when calculating IS/JSA and WFTC, and this will lead to a few small
changes in tax credit awards.
Figure 4. Distributional effects of the new tax credits and the tax rises in
April 2003
4.0%
3.5%
3.0%
2.5%
2.0%
1.5%
1.0%
0.5%
0.0%
-0.5%
-1.0%
Poorest
Richest
Income deciles
New tax credits
Notes: Income deciles are derived by dividing all families (with and without children) into 10
equally sized groups according to income adjusted for family size using the McClements
equivalence scale. Decile 1 contains the poorest tenth of the population, decile 2 the second
poorest and so on, up to the top decile (decile 10), which contains the richest tenth.
Source: IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, based on 200001 Family Resources Survey.
10
The effective tax rates of about a third of parents (including those not
working) will change. Around 1.6 million will face a higher effective
marginal tax rate because of the new tax credits. These are mostly people
who previously earned too much to be entitled to the WFTC, but who are
now on the first taper of the child tax credit. For every extra pound they
earn, they now get to keep less. Conversely, 2.4 million will see their
effective marginal tax rates fall, mostly because the credits will be
assessed against gross income, which particularly benefits those who earn
too little to pay basic-rate income tax.
Another important set of changes occur because the old childrens tax
credit, which was withdrawn based on the income of the higher earner in a
two-earner family, is being replaced by the child tax credit, which is based
on joint income. The change means that both individuals in a couple whose
joint income places them on the second taper of the child tax credit now
face an increase of 6.7 percentage points in their effective marginal rate.
Under the childrens tax credit, though, only the higher earner faced this
addition to his or her effective marginal rate. We estimate that the number
of individuals whose effective marginal tax rate is 6.7 percentage points
higher thanks to the child tax credit (600,000) is therefore higher than the
number affected similarly by the childrens tax credit (400,000).
11
In general, those whose marginal rates fall tend to have high marginal rates
to start with, and those whose rates rise tend to have low marginal rates to
start with.
This only tells half the story, as there are both negative and positive effects:
The working tax credit will improve the financial reward from moving into
work for some (single people and the primary earner in a couple) but
worsen it for others (some second earners in couples). This is very similar
to the impact of introducing the WFTC.
It is difficult to see how the working tax credit will help tackle the poverty
trap (cited above), because, on our estimates, if all those who are entitled
to the credit were to claim it, around 800,000 people without children
would see their effective marginal tax rate increase and around 50,000
would see it fall. Overall, the number of adults without children facing
marginal deduction rates between 50% and 70% would increase by around
490,000.
12
amounts; even so, non-take-up of the WFTC, for example, saved the
government around 1.4 billion a year in 200001.30
The governments estimate of the take-up rate for the child tax credit is around
90%, as it has claimed that 90% of families with children will be eligible for
the new tax credits and that 5.75 million will receive them, and as there are
around 7.25 million families with children in the UK. This implies that around
775,000 families with children will not claim the child tax credit despite being
entitled, slightly more families than did not claim the WFTC in 200001
despite being entitled.31 There are several ways that the introduction of the
child tax credit and the working tax credit might change take-up behaviour
compared with that for the existing tax credits and benefits:
The child tax credit will go to the vast majority of families with children,
with all save the richest 10% entitled to something. This should reduce the
likelihood that families do not claim because they think that they will not
be entitled or that they will only be entitled for a short time.
However, experience from family credit and the WFTC suggests that takeup will probably take a couple of years to rise to its new long-run level, as
awareness of the reform spreads amongst the population.
The nature of the means test and the administration of the credits will be
different from those of the old tax credits. The claim form requires more
information than for the childrens tax credit but less than for the WFTC or
income support. Also, as discussed earlier, the tax credits will require an
end-of-year reconciliation which may involve people paying money back
to the Inland Revenue. These changes may make families more or less
likely to claim compared with the 200203 system.
We estimate that average entitlements to working tax credit for those without
children are less than 20 a week, with around 650,000 families entitled. It is
not clear what take-up rate is being assumed by the government for the
working tax credit for people without children. Our estimates of the total cost
of the working tax credit for people without children assuming full take-up are
over twice those of the government, although it is unclear whether all other
assumptions are the same in both models. Given related reforms in the past, it
is perfectly plausible that the take-up rate for working tax credit for people
without children could be below 50%.32
Conclusion
The new tax credits are a substantial reform, affecting nearly 7 million
families in Britain. Their distributional impact is fully in keeping with that of
past Labour reforms, with the largest gains going to the poorest families, and
with households with children gaining far more, on average, than those
without.
13
Those who are entitled to the tax credits may find that both their financial
reward to work and their effective marginal rates of tax change slightly. For
those with children, the changes are relatively small, and the overall impact is
ambiguous. For those without children, their reward to full-time work
increases but their effective marginal tax rates also increase.
Labours previous reforms to the personal tax and benefit system have merely
involved changing the generosity of existing programmes. But the success or
failure of the new tax credits depends as much on the practicalities of
administration and delivery as on calculations of the precise amounts of
money involved. This makes it hard to predict whether the government will
manage to persuade the vast majority of those who are entitled to claim the tax
credits actually to do so, and whether people will understand the complicated
way in which the credits react to changes in family circumstances.
The new tax credits underline the governments frustration with individual
taxation and the Pay-As-You-Earn (PAYE) mechanism as ways to target
resources on the basis of household need. They also show that the government
is happy to increase the administrative responsibilities of basic-rate taxpayers
with children, many of whom will now complete a form similar to the annual
tax return completed by those who undergo self-assessment (those earning
more than 34,000, the self-employed and those with complicated tax affairs).
Both of these changes may point to the way Labour would ultimately like to
see the income tax system structured.
14
Year 2
Annual income rises by
1,000 to 16,000
1.
No change
to award
2a.
2b.
2c.
No change
to award
3.
No change
to award
Award falls by
37% of
estimated change
ignoring first
2,500 of
changes
(i.e. 555)
Award falls by
37% of
estimated change
ignoring first
2,500 of
changes
(i.e. 185)
Year 3
Actual income in Year 2
(16,000) compared
with income in Year 1
(15,000); no action as
income change less than
2,500
Actual income in Year 2
(19,000) compared
with estimate of income
in Year 2 (19,000); no
reconciliation needed
Actual income in Year 2
(19,000) compared
with estimate of income
in Year 2 (18,000);
family must repay 37%
of the difference to
Inland Revenue
(i.e. 370)
Actual income in Year 2
(19,000) compared
with income in Year 1
(15,000); family must
repay 37% of the
difference ignoring first
2,500 to Inland
Revenue (i.e. 555)
Actual income in Year 2
(14,000) compared
with income in Year 1
(15,000); family
entitled to 37% of the
income fall from Inland
Revenue (i.e. 370)
Notes
1.
2.
In all of this, a dependent child is one under 16, or under 19 and in full-time education.
15
3.
Inland Revenue, Working Families Tax Credit Statistics: Quarterly Enquiry, May 2002,
London, 2002 (www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/wftctables/wftc_may_02.pdf).
4.
See note 3.
5.
Department for Work and Pensions, Income Support: Quarterly Statistical Enquiry,
August 2002, London, 2002
(www.dwp.gov.uk/asd/asd1/qse/aug2002/is_aug2002_pub.pdf).
6.
It is difficult to obtain comparable figures on how many parents gain from each of these
benefits separately: what follow are from different sources, but all relate to 2002, with the
month in parentheses: 2,832 families received child additions through ICA (May); 53,700
parents received child additions through bereavement benefits (March); 96,700 families
received child additions through IB or SDA (August); and 23,000 pensioners were
receiving child additions to the state pension (May).
7.
HM Treasury, The Child and Working Tax Credits, The Modernisation of Britains Tax
and Benefit System 10, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/new_tax_credits.pdf).
8.
See note 7.
9.
See HM Treasury, Supporting Children through the Tax and Benefit System, The
Modernisation of Britains Tax and Benefit System 5, London, 1999 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/media//F174F/children.pdf).
16
20. Chapter 4 of HM Treasury, The Child and Working Tax Credits, The Modernisation of
Britains Tax and Benefit System 10, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/new_tax_credits.pdf).
21. See note 20.
22. Inland Revenue, The New Tax Credits: A Regulatory Impact Assessment, London, 2002
(www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/ria/ntcria.pdf).
23. See note 22.
24. In January 2003 prices. Authors calculations as part of ongoing work funded by the
Joseph Rowntree Foundation, updating S. Adam, M. Brewer and H. Reed, The Benefits of
Parenting: Government Financial Support for Families with Children Since 1975, IFS
Commentary 91, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/taxben/c91.pdf).
25. Annex A of HM Treasury, The Child and Working Tax Credits, The Modernisation of
Britains Tax and Benefit System 10, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/new_tax_credits.pdf).
26. Our estimates in this section come from the IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, based
on the 200001 Family Resources Survey.
27. See chapter 9 of R. Chote, C. Emmerson and H. Simpson (eds), The IFS Green Budget:
January 2003, IFS Commentary 92, London, 2003 (www.ifs.org.uk/gb2003/ch9.pdf).
28. See appendix B of R. Chote, C. Emmerson and H. Simpson (eds), The IFS Green
Budget: January 2003, IFS Commentary 92, London, 2003
(www.ifs.org.uk/gb2003/appb.pdf) for a full analysis of the changes announced in
Budget 2002 and due in 200304.
29. Paragraph 2.5 and footnote 3 of Inland Revenue, The New Tax Credits: A Regulatory
Impact Assessment, London, 2002 (www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/ria/ntcria.pdf).
30. WFTC take-up rates from Inland Revenue, Working Families Tax Credit: Estimates of
Take-Up Rates in 200001, London, 2002
(www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/stats/wftc/wftc_takeup.pdf). Family credit take-up rates
from A. Marsh, S. McKay, A. Smith and A. Stephenson, Low-Income Families in
Britain, DSS Research Report 138, Corporate Document Services, Leeds, 2001. Take-up
rates for other means-tested benefits from Department for Work and Pensions, Income
Related Benefits: Estimates of Take-Up in 19992000, London, 2001
(www.dwp.gov.uk/asd/income_analysis/tu9900f.pdf).
31. The take-up rate for the childrens tax credit is not known, unfortunately.
32. The take-up rate for WFTC amongst couples with children is around 50%, and this is a
group whose mean entitlement is 53 a week far in excess of the 20 a week mean
entitlement to the working tax credit for those without children. In the late 1990s, a
policy called Earnings Top-Up was piloted in a number of areas. Its design was similar to
that of the working tax credit for those without children, although it was less generous. Its
take-up rate was very low less than a quarter although the benefit was only publicised
during its first six months, after which word of mouth was the only means by which
people could find out about it. One point from the evaluation of this pilot is that word of
mouth is an important way by which people hear about benefits and tax credits and that
there is a critical mass below which awareness fails to spread (A. Marsh, Earnings TopUp Evaluation: Synthesis Report, DSS Research Report 135, Corporate Document
Services, Leeds, 2001).
17