[go: up one dir, main page]

0% found this document useful (0 votes)
301 views24 pages

Slutsky Compensation

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1/ 24

Microeconomics Lecture Supplements Department of Economics

Hajime Miyazaki OHIO STATE UNIVERSITY


slutsk95.usc Fall 93/94/95/01/02
File Name: SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc Miyazaki.1@osu.edu



SLUTSKY COMPENSATION AND DECOMPOSITION

Throughout this note, a consumer obeys WARP (Weak Axiom of
Revealed Preference) and a typical budget set takes the form B(p, m) =
{x | px m }. For reasons stated in the preceding lecture note, we
assume income exhaustion; unless otherwise noted; all consumption
choices are made on the budget line p x = m. If the income constraint is
not binding, a comparative statics of a changing income on a consumption
choice become obtuse. Since any price change involves an effective
change in the purchasing power of money income, the income exhaustion
assumption will give us a better handle on decomposing the gross effect of
a price change into pure price effect and implied income effect. .










In what follows, as in almost all textbooks, illustrations are
exclusively for the case of a two-dimensional commodity space. It is
useful and instructive to remember that the dimension of commodity
vectors in the real market economy is very large. Theoretically, the
dimension of the vector space in a general equilibrium setting is even
larger than the real world economy. This is because duality theory

x
2

0

x
1

B(p, m)
x =x(p, m)
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 2 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
assumes a complete contingent markets over time and space. While
intuition and insights gained from two-dimensional analyses are often
generalizable to higher dimensions, there are some notable lacuna between
the two and higher dimensional. For example, in the case of Slutsky
equations and revealed preference, two dimensional analysis induce
strong results that are not extendable to three dimensions
1
.
To simplify our two dimensional illustrations further, we fix (or
normalize) p
2
= 1 and allow only p
1
to change. Further, we first draw
diagrams for a case of only p
1
increasing, which is technically identical
to a case in which the relative price p
1
/p
2
increases. The next diagram
shows such a price change; p changes to p +p = (p
1
+p
1
, p
2
) where
p
1
> 0 and p
2
= 0. The case of a decrease in p
1
as well as other
cases of a price change are left to the reader. Definitions, algebraic proofs
and theorem statements are stated for a general case.












1
Notably, WARP is equivalent to SARP (Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference) in the
two dimensional commodity space, but not at all so in higher dimensions. The Slutsky
matrix is automatically symmetric in two dimensions but not necessarily so in higher
dimensions.
0
x
2

x
1

x =x(p, m)
(p
1
/p
2
)
(p
1
+p
1
)/p
2

OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 3 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
SLUTSKY COMPENSATION
Let x =x(p, m) be a commodity bundle that a consumer buys
when the price vector is p with income m. Suppose that the price vector
changes to p +p while the consumers money income m remains
unchanged. This ceteris paribus change in the price vector affects the
consumers purchasing power of m. The consumer may no longer be able
to buy x

under the new price vector unless the money income is
increased. Of course, the price change may be favorable and the
consumers purchasing power might have increased.
For the sake of exposition, let us adopt a scenario that the initial
bundle x
o
becomes too expensive to buy. To buy the initial bundle x


under a new price vector, the consumer needs at least (p + p) x

of
money income. The extra income that the consumer needs is at least (p +
p)x
o
px

= px. Let us define the Slutsky compensation m
S
as
the minimum monetary subsidy that enables the consumer to buy the
initial bundle x

under a new price vector. Thus,
m
S
= px

= p x(p, m).
If the consumers purchasing power increased after a price change,
the new budget set will include x, and there is no need for a subsidy.
Still, we can ask for a hypothetical scenario in which we tax the
consumers increased purchasing power. What would be the maximum
tax that we can levy without making the consumer worse off than before
the price change? One way to measure this maximum levy is to ask how
much the consumer can give up and still able to purchase the initial vector
x. The change in the value of the consumption vector x

is (p +p)x


px

= (p)x. The current scenario is that this px



is negative; x

is
cheaper than before by the amount equal to px. In this scenario we
should define the Slutsky compensation as the maximum tax that can be
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 4 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
levied on the consumer while enabling him/her to buy x. Thus, |m
S
| =
|px|, and in the present scenario, m
S
= px < 0.
The purpose of Slutsky compensation m
S
is to adjust the
consumers money income so that he/she can have just enough to buy
back x

after a price change. Since the change in the value of the
consumption vector x is (p +p)x px = (p)x, the requisite
money income change is given by m
S
= px. This m
S
can be
either positive or negative depending on p. The Slutsky compensation
is positive, or a subsidy, if x becomes too expensive to buy. The
Slutsky compensation is negative if x becomes cheaper, and is like an
income tax that takes away |px| from the consumer.
The standard definition of Slutsky compensation is
m
S
= px
where p = (p + p) p. If a price change occurs only in the price of
the i-th commodity, p = (0, , p
i
, , 0). Consequently, for an
isolated price change, the Slutsky Compensation is
m
S
= p x = (p
i
)(x
i
)
In the diagram below, p = (p
1
, 0) and m
s
= (p
1
) x
1
.











x
2

m +m
S

0
x
1



x

m
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 5 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc

SLUTSKY SUBSTITUTION EFFECT
Let the price vector changes from p to p +p, and the consumer
be compensated by m
S
= px. Let the consumers budget change
from B(p, m) to the compensated budget B(p +p, m +m
S
)
2
. By
construction, x is in B(p +p, m +m
S
) as well as in B(p, m). The
consumer, given the compensated budget, however, need not choose x


again. Let x
S
be the consumers choice in B(p +p, m +m
S
). If x
S

x, x
S
is revealed preferred to x. We call x
S
the Slutsky-compensated
demand. The Slutsky substitution effect refers to x
S
x
S
x as it
measures how a consumer substitutes x
S
for x

in response to a price
change. This is illustrated in the diagram below.













The above diagram illustrates that in response to a ceteris paribus
rise in the price of commodity 1, the consumers demand for commodity 1

2
Since m +m
S
= (p +p)x, the compensated budget B(p +p, m +m
S
) can be
expressed as B(p +p, (p +p)x). Because x = x(p, m), the compensated budget set
can also be expressed as B(p +p, (p +p)x(p, m)).
m +m
S

0
x
2

x
1

x
S

x

m
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 6 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
decreases given the compensated budget. That is, p
1
x
S
1
= (+) () < 0
in the diagram. A (relatively) higher p
1
induces the consumer to
purchase less of x
1
and more of x
2
in the two-commodity world.
Generally, a ceteris paribus change in the price vector should induce a
less consumption of a commodity that has become relatively more
expensive. This negative relationship between the price change and the
Slutsky compensated demand can be generalized to p x
S
0 as a
major consequence of WARP. If the consumers choice is unique in every
budget set B(p, m), the substitution effect under WARP is strictly
negative p x
S
< 0 if x
S
0.

LEMMA (Law of Slutsky Compensated Demand or Law of Negative
Slutsky Substitution Effect): Assume that a consumer obeys WARP*,
income-exhaustive, and that a consumers choice is unique in any given
budget set B(p, m). Then, px
S
0, and the strict inequality holds
whenever x
S
0.

The Slutsky compensation guarantees that x and x
S
are both in
B(p +p, m +m
S
). The scenario is that in B(p +p, m +m
S
) the
consumer chose x
S
rather than x

, establishing the revealed preference
of x
S
over x. To consider first the case of x
S
0, let us suppose x
S

x. In the initial budget set B(p, m), however, the consumer chooses
x, not x
S
. Thus, by invoking WARP* given x
S
x, we conclude that
x
S
was outside B(p, m). If x
S
were available in B(p, m), the consumer
would have again chosen x
S
over x. Hence, px
S
> m. If the consumer
is income exhaustive, px
S
> m = px.
Summing up, we have two inequalities
3
:

3
The first inequality follows from (p +p)x
S
= m +m = (p +p)x, which says
that x
S
is purchasable with m +m
S
and that x is on the budget line (p+p)x = m
+m
S
by the construction of Slutsky compensation. Since px = m, the second
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 7 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
(p +p)x
S
= (p +p)x
px
S
> px.
These two inequalities can be re-written as
(p +p)x
S
= (p +p)x
px
S
< px.
Adding up each side, we obtain
px
S
< px
which can then be rearranged as
p(x
S
x) < 0 .
By definition, x
S
= x
S
x. Thus,
px
S
< 0 .
The only case not yet covered is when x
S
= x. In that case x
S
= x,
however, x
S
= 0, and then px
S
= 0 follows immediately.

The above lemma is derived under the dual assumption of income
exhaustion and uniqueness of consumption choice. It is instructive to
understand modifications that becomes due once either assumption is
relaxed. Suppose that income exhaustion holds but the consumers choice
is a genuine correspondence, that is, d(p, m) is multi-valued or non
singleton set. WARP now says that with respect to B(p, m), either x
s

was not affordable or x
s
(as well as x) also belonged to d(p, m). To the
extent that all choices must be income-exhausting, if x
s
is in d(p, m), px
s

= m must hold. By WARP, if x
s
is not in d(p, m), x
s
must be
unaffordable, i.e., px
S
> m. Hence, WARP implies px
s
m. Since by
income exhaustion m = px, the second inequality in the above lemma
need only be replaced by a weak inequality as px
S
px. Consequently,
the lemma holds with weak inequality, px
S
0 even when x
S
0.


inequality says that x
S
was not purchasable when x was, namely x
S
was outside the
budget set B(p, m).
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 8 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
Corollary: Assume that a consumers demand correspondence is income-
exhaustive and obeys WARP. Then, px
S
0 where x
S
is the
differenece between any two vectors x in d(p, m) and x
S
in d(p +p,
m +m
S
).

A demand correspondence allows the possibility of both x
S
and
x belonging to d(p, m) as well as to d(p +p, m +m
S
). But, income
exhaustion forces the desired inequalities we need to establish the
nonpositive Slutsky substitution effect. If the consumers choice is not
income exhaustive, the case of demand correspondence may result in a
choice of x
S
such that px
S
< px
o
, thus invalidating the inequality
required for the proof. Readers are asked to provide examples in which
Slutsky substitution effects fail to be nonpositive due to income non-
exhaustion for a demand correspondence.
The following discourse illustrates the importance of income
exhaustion even when the consumers demand choice is summarized by a
demand function. Let us maintain the assumption that the consumers
choice is unique for each B(p, m), but not necessarily income-exhaustive.
If the budget is not exhausted, a slight change in the price vector can keep
x affordable with the same money income. When px < m, for a
sufficiently small p, we can guarantee (p +p)x < m. Since the
consumer can buy the original bundle after the price change, there is no
need to give a Slutsky compensation. The new budget set is B(p +p, m)
to which x again belongs. If x
S
different from x is chosen, then by
WARP*, we must conclude that x
S
was unaffordable previously, that is,
px
S
> m and m > px. Thus, the second inequality in the above lemma
is met as px
S
> px. But, there is no guarantee that the first inequality is
also met. Because income exhaustion is not assumed, it is quite possible
that m (p +p)x
S
> (p +p)x, the derivation of the desired
inequality is not assured. Readers, try to provide two-commodity
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 9 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
examples in which the substitution effect can be positive if no such
compensation mechanism is adopted.
To carry out the Slutsky compensation analysis in a non income-
exhaustive case, therefore, we still insist that the consumer be given just
enough income to buy the initial bundle. Such a budget adjustment is
consistent with the approach we have taken for the case of a price change
that induced an increase in the purchasing power of money income. We
shall require that the Slutsky compensated budget set be B(p +p, m
S
)
where m
S
= (p +p)x, or more compactly expressed,
B(p +p, (p +p)x).
The implied Slutsky compensation adjustment m
S
in this case is less
than p x: m
S
= m
S
m = (p +p)x m = (p x m) + p x
< p x because p x m < 0 by the assumed non-exhaustion of
income.
We summarize the above qualifications regarding the validity of
the negative Slutsky substitution effect in the following table. The entry,
(valid), for the non income-exhaustion cum demand function case means
that the Slutsky compensation need to be modified accordingly.

D-FUNCTION D-CORRESPONDENCE
income exhaustion valid valid
income non exhaustion (valid) not valid

OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 10 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
REMARK 1: Consider two budget situations B(p, m) and B(p, m),
and let x(p, m) be a demand vector in B(p, m). As (p, m) changes to (p,
m), we define the generalized Slutsky compensation as
m
S
= px(p, m) m,
and the Slutsky compesated demand becomes
x(p, m + m
S
) = x(p, px(p, m))
where m + m
S
= px(p, m). The Slutsky substitution effect is
x
S
= x(p, px(p, m)) x(p, m)
We then have the Law of Slutksy compensated demand
(p p) [x(p, px(p, m)) x(p, m)] 0,
a restatement of px
S
0 where p = p p.
REMARK 2: Let B(p, m) and B(p, m) be two distinct budget
situations, and let x(p, m) be a demand vector in B(p, m) and x(p, m) a
demand vector in B(p, m). Suppose that p x(p, m) = m. It means that
the (new) income m is just adequate enough to purchase the intial bundle
x(p, m) under the (new) price vector p. We can thus regard B(p, m) as
the Slutsky-compensated budget set when the price changes from p to p.
The implied Slutsky compensation is m
S
= m m because it is equal
to px(p, m) m. Hence, x(p, m) = x(p, px(p, m)) is the Slutsky
compensated demand and the substitution effect is x
S
= x(p, m)
x(p, m). We can express the Law of Slutsky compensated demand as (p
p) [x(p, m) x(p, m)] 0.


Theorem: Assume that a consumers demand correspondence is income-
exhaustive and obeys px
S
0 for all price changes that are
accompanied by Slutsky compensation. Then, the demand
correspondence obeys WARP.

OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 11 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
The logic behind this theorem is another important lemma that WARP
holds for demand correspondence if and only if WARP holds for Slutsky
compensated demand correspondence. A Slutsky compensated demand
correspondence is defined by d(p, px) or d(p, m) subject to m = px.
Thus, x
S
= x(p +p, (p +p)x) x(p, px) which is same as x(p +
p, m +m
S
) x(p, m) because m
S
= px and m = px.

INCOME EFFECT
Whenever a price vector changes, with the money income m
remaining constant, the consumers purchasing power also changes. To
capture the substitution effect, we need to neutralize the effect of
purchasing power change as a result of a price change. The Slutsky
compensation is designed just to achieve this end. It is also useful to
know the pure effect of a purchasing power change. The pure income
effect is an effect of a change in money income while the price vector
remains constant. In terms of the budget set geometry, because prices are
held fixed, the budget lines make parallel shifts as money income changes.
An increase in money income shifts the budget line outward, while a
decrease in money income shifts the budget line inward.
Income effect is defined as a change in consumption (x) in
response to a ceteris paribus money-income change (m). Component
wise we can express it as x
i
/m. The diagram below indicates possible
hypothetical changes in the consumers demand vector as income
increases
4
.

4
A more detailed exposition of the income effect is given in the appendix of the
preceding lecture note Budget Sets, Demand and Revealed Preference.
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 12 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc











SLUTSKY DECOMPOSITION
As a starting point, let a consumer choose x in the initial budget
set B(p, m) = {x | px m}. In the new budget set B(p +p, m) = {x |
(p +p) x m}, let the consumer chooses x
G
. Our task is to decompose
the consumers move from x to x
G
into the income effect and
substitution effect. To isolate the substitution effect, we need to neutralize
the effect of purchasing power change due to the price change. That is,
we must adjust the consumers income in the manner of Slutsky
compensation. Having benchmarked the Slutsky substitution vector under
a new price vector, we then identify the income effect as we restore the
consumers income to m while maintaining the new price vector.
SLUTSKY DECOMPOSITION:
gross price effect = substitution effect + income effect.

To facilitate the ease of diagrammatic illustration of the Slutsky
decomposition, we again normalize p
2
= 1 and change only p
1
. In what
follows in diagrams, we consider only the case of p
1
increasing, which is
essentially identical to the case in which the relative price p
1
/p
2

increases. In all diagrams in this section, p changes to p +p = (p
1
+
x
x
2

x
1

OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 13 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
p
1
, p
2
) where p
1
> 0 and p
2
= 0. Because p
1
has increased, with
the same money income m, the consumers purchasing power has
decreased. In other words, the consumer cannot buy back x
o
under the
new price vector unless the money income is increased. The Slutsky
compensation m
S
is the minimum monetary subsidy that enables the
consumer to buy the same initial bundle x
o
under a new price vector.










Step 1: The Slutsky substitution term measures the pure effect of
price on the consumers consumption substitution as the consumers
purchasing power itself is unaffected by the Slutsky compensation. The
movement from x to x
S
in the diagram measures the consumers
response to a price change p while simultaneously compensated by
m
S
. The vector difference, or the located vector, x
S
= x
S
x, is the
Slutsky substitution effect.
0
x
2

x
1

x
G

x
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 14 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc













Step 2: The movement from x
S
to x
G
in the diagram measures
the consumers response as m
S
is taken away while price vector is
maintained at p + p. The vector difference, or the located vector, x
I
=
x
G
x
S
is the income effect, or the pure effect of the ceteris paribus
income reduction.












The Slutsky decomposition is the vector equation given by
x
G
x

= (x
G
x
S
) + (x
S
x)
which we rearrange as
x
1

x
2

0

x
G


x
x
s
0
x
1

x
2

x
G


x
x
s
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 15 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
x
G
x

= (x
S
x) + (x
G
x
S
)













Although the diagrammatic exposition has been limited to an isolated
price change in p
1,
exactly the same decomposition works for any general
price change. Any p will induce the same vector formula as above.
Compactly stated, the Slutsky decomposition is







The Slutsky decomposition is often expressed in terms of a ceteris
paribus change in the i-th commodity price. This means that we measure
the effect of an isolated p
i
change on consumption decisions. To
express such a ceteris paribus effect, we can divide the above vector
formula by p
i
, so that the Slutsky decomposition becomes

i
I
i
S
i
G
p
x
p
x
p
x

.
0
x
1

x
2

x
G


x
x
s
x
G

x
S

x
G
x
I
x
S

x


x x x
G S I
= +
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 16 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
It is desirable to convert the income effect term from x
I
/p
i
into
the form expressed in terms of an income change. To repeat, any price
change p
i
induces a change in the consumers purchasing power of a
given money income. To compensate for this change in purchasing power
of money income, the consumer was given (p
i
)x
i
= m
S
. The income
effect measured in the Slutsky Equation is the effect of taking away m
S

from the consumer. The vector x
I
= x
G
x
S
traces the consumption
change as the consumer gives up |m
S
|. Thus, the correct sign of Slutsky
compensation is given by m
S
= (p
i
)x
i
or p
i
= ( x
i
)/ m
S
. We
thus obtain

S
I
i
i
S
i
G
m
x
x
p
x
p
x

.
This is the vector version of Slutsky Equation. Note that these are vectors
in n-dimensions. Component wise, the Slutsky Equation can be expressed
component-wise as

x
p
x
p
x
x
m
j
G
i
j
S
i
i
j
I
S
=
Scomp
(i, j = 1, , n) .

where Scomp is a shorthand to say that it is a comparative static after the
Slutsky compensation.
The analytic geometry of our decomposition method is transparent,
and the derived formula is valid for finite as well infinitesimal changes.
When a price change is infinitesimal, we can replace by , and obtain

S
I
j
i
i
S
j
i
G
j
m
x
x
p
x
p
x

o
Scomp
(i, j = 1, , n).
The derivative version, which is the about the only way almost all
textbooks express the Slutsky equation, is stated without superscripts G, S
and I.
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 17 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
m
x
x
p
x
p
x
j j j
i
i i

o
Scomp
(i, j = 1, , n).
In the next section, we demonstrate this version by taking derivatives of
an identity equation that translates a Slutsky compensated demand as a
Marshallian demand.

CALCULUS DERIVATION OF THE SLUTSKY EQUATION
The foregoing derivation of Slutsky equation has relied on Slutsky
compensation and vector additions. The primary use of Slutsky
compensation is to let a consumer have just enough income to buy back
the initial vector after a price change. That is, the Slutsky compensated
demand x
S
(p, x
o
) and the Marshallian demand x(p, m) are identical as
long as we maintain m = p x
o
for all price vectors for the Marshallian
demand.
x
S
(p, x
o
) x(p, m) subject to m = p x
o
,
that is,
x
S
(p, x
o
) x(p, p x
o
).
Differentiate both sides with respect to p
i
to derive for each j = 1, , n,
i
j
i
j
i
S
j
p
m
m
x
p
x
p
x

where
o
o
i
i i
x
p
px
p
m
=

) (
.
Thus, we obtain
m
x
x
p
x
p
x
j
i
i
j
i
S
j

o

which we rearrange as
m
x
x
p
x
p
x
j
i
i
S
j
i
j

o

That is,
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 18 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
) , ( ) , ( ) , ( m p
m
x
x x p
p
x
m p
p
x
j
i
i
S
j
i
j

o o
where m = p x
o
.
At an initial price-income pair (p
o
, x
o
), we have x
S
(p, x
o
) = x
o
= x(p
o
,
m
o
) as well as m = p x
o
. If we evaluate the Slutsky Equation at (p
o
, x
o
),
we get
) , ( ) , ( ) , (

m p
m
x
x x p
p
x
m p
p
x
j
i
i
S
j
i
j o o

Starting with an arbitrary price-income pair, therefore, we have
) , ( ) , ( ) , ( m p
m
x
x x p
p
x
m p
p
x
j
i
i
S
j
i
j



SLUTSKY EQUATION WITH AN INITIAL ENDOWMENT VECTOR
Suppose that a consumer is endowed with = (
1
,,
i
,,
n
).
This consumer can sell all of its initial endowment vector for p = (p
1
,,
p
i
,, p
n
) to obtain money income p , which is the market valuation of
the consumers initial endowment. In addition to an initial commodity
endowment , the consumer may also have a separate money income m.
The consumers total income is p + m, and the consumers budget set
becomes
B(p, ) = { x | p x p + m} = { x | p (x ) m}.
Under the proviso of budget exhaustion, the consumer buys a commodity
vector on the budget hyperplane p (x ) = m.
Once again, by the same vector decomposition as before we obtain
x x x
G S I
= + . It is imperative that we compute the correct
amount of Slutsky compensation for this consumer to buy back exactly the
initial bundle x. Since we assume budget exhaustion, after the price
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 19 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
change the consumer can afford x if and only if the compensation m
S

meets the budget equality: (p +p)(x ) = m + m
S
. Thus
5
,
m
S
= p (x ).
When the price change entails only a ceteris paribus change in p
i
, the
compensation needed to effect the Slutsky substitution demand becomes
m
S
= (p
i
) (x
i

i
).
To effect the income effect that moves the consumer from x
S
to x
G
, we
need to take away this take away m
S
from the consumer. We can then
substitute 1/p
i
= (x
i

i
)/m
S
in the Slutsky decomposition under
the ceteris paribus price change:
i
I
i
S
i
G
p
x
p
x
p
x

, and we obtain

S
I
i i
i
S
i
G
m
x
x
p
x
p
x

) ( .
Component-wise, the derived Slutsky decomposition is

S
I
j
i i
i
S
j
i
G
j
m
x
x
p
x
p
x

) (
comp
(j = 1, , i, , n) .
The calculus derivation of the above Slutsky Equation is as
follows. The Slutsky compensated demand x
S
(p, x
o
) with initial
endowment is then same as the Marshallian demand x(p, m) subject to m
= p (x
o
). That is,
x
S
(p, x
o
) x(p, m) subject to m = p (x
o
)
Thus, setting the Slutsky compensated demand as
x
S
(p, x
o
) x(p, p(x
o
)),
we can differentiate both sides of the equation with respect to p
i
and
obtain for each j = 1, , n,
i
j
i
j
i
S
j
p
m
m
x
p
x
p
x

where
i i
i i
x
p
px
p
m
=

o
o
) (
.

5
By the assumed budget exhaustion, the consumer buys x in the initial budget condition
by meeting p (x ) = m.
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 20 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
The upshot is that
m
x
x
p
x
p
x
j
i i
i
j
i
S
j

) (
o

which we can rearrange as
m
x
x
p
x
p
x
j
i i
i
S
j
i
j

) (
o
.
In a full expression,
) , ( ) ( ) , ( ) , ( m p
m
x
x x p
p
x
m p
p
x
j
i i
i
S
j
i
j

o o

where m = p (x
o
).

If we let (p, m) be an initial price-income pair as (p, m), we
have x
S
(p, x
o
) = x = x(p, m) as well as m = p (x
o
). More
concisely stated, the initial condition is
x
S
(p, x
o
) = x = x(p, p(x
o
)).
Slutsky equation evaluated at (p, m) is
) , ( ) ( ) , ( ) , (
o o o o o o o
m p
m
x
x x p
p
x
m p
p
x
j
i i
i
S
j
i
j

.
Given an arbitrary initial condition (p, m), we can thus express the Slutsky
equation as
) , ( ) ( ) , ( ) , ( m p
m
x
x x p
p
x
m p
p
x
j
i i
i
S
j
i
j


where m = p (x ).

The set up of initial endowment is an indispensable component of
a general equilibrium analysis, especially of a pure exchange economy.
The Edgeworth exchange economy cannot be analyzed without having
consumers with initial endowment vectors. But, the setup of initially
endowed consumers is a useful framework in many applied economic
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 21 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc
theory even within the context of partial equilibrium analysis. For
example, the labor supply decision of a homo economicus is an income-
leisure choice in which the initial endowment vector is given by = (
1
,

2
) = (24 hours of leisure, unearned money income), and the budget set
is given by {(C, leisure) | C w(24 leisure) +(unearned money
income)} wherein the price of consumption is $1, and the price of leisure
is the hourly wage rate w. We then have the comparative statics of a
wage rate change income on the demand for leisure express as the
following Slutsky equation:
) , ( ) 24 ( ) , ( ) , ( m w
m
x w
w
m w
w
S

l
l
l l
o


Other important applications of Slutsky equations with initial endowments
occur in the analysis of intertemporal consumption decision and also
insurance markets wherein state-contingent demand is analyzed.
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 22 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc

EXERCISES
The diagrammatic exposition has so far assumed that p
2
= 1 and
considered only cases of price increase in p
1
. There are a number of
exercises that are straightforward, but that may facilitate the understanding
of, and the potential applications of, the Slutsky decomposition. As
immediate exercises, try to duplicate the diagrammatic analysis for p
1

decreases, i.e., p
1
< 0.











Also, it will make a good practice to reconstruct the analysis while fixing
p
1
= 1 and changing p
2
. This exercise pivots the budget line around
(m, 0) on the horizontal axis. As such, it has applications to leisure-
income choice, and can be generalized to the case of a consumer with an
initial endowment vector. Readers, try to depict the case of p
2
increase
as well as p
2
decrease while p
1
is fixed (or normalized) at 1.
0
x
2

x
1

x
G

x
S
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 23 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc

Case: p
2
> 0











Case: p
2
< 0










Finally, readers are encouraged to analyze the case of both prices
changing. It amounts to the case of a relative price change
0
x
m / p
2

m


x
G

x
S




(m+m
S
)/p
2

m / (p
2
+p)
m +m
S

0
x
m / p
2

m

x
S




(m+m
S
)/p
2

m / (p
2
+p
2
)
m +m
S
OSU Econ 804 Slutsky Equations
Fall 93/94/95/01/02/03 - 24 - Hajime Miyazaki


SLUTSKY2003Draft.doc



Case: p
1
/ p
2
decreases











Case: p
1
/ p
2
increases










0
x
m / p
2

m / p
1

x
G

x
S


0
x
m / p
2

m / p
1

x
S

x
G

You might also like