Guide To Municipal Finance
Guide To Municipal Finance
Guide To Municipal Finance
Municipal
Finance
Guide to
Municipal
Finance
Nairobi, 2009
Sec1:i
The Human Settlements Financing Tools and Best Practices Series
HS/1146/09E
ISBN: 978-92-1-132113-5
ISBN(Series): 978-1-132027-5
Disclaimer
The designations employed and the presentation of the material in this publication do
not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Secretariat of
the United Nations concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area
or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers of boundaries.
Views expressed in this publication do not necessarily reflect those of the United
Nations Human Settlements Programme, the United Nations, or its Member States.
Excerpts may be reproduced without authorization, on condition that the source is indicated.
Acknowledgements:
ii
Table of Contents
iii
chapter 6 Municipal Budget, Financial Reporting and Auditing 56
Expenditures at the local level 56
Municipal budgeting 56
Accounting standards 61
Accounting concepts 62
Auditing 63
Performance-based measurement 63
chapter 7 Municipal Borrowing and Access to the Capital Market 65
Role of municipal borrowing 65
Capital markets 66
Pooling municipal debt 66
Borrowing instruments 67
Credit ratings 68
chapter 8 Concluding Comments 71
REFERENCES 78
appendix 78
iv
LIST OF TABLES ,FIGURES AND boxes
Tables
Table 1 Distribution of Municipal Expenditures, Selected OECD Countries, 2006 (%) 4
Table 2 Distribution of Municipal Expenditures, Selected Countries in
Central and Eastern Europe, Asia, Africa, and Latin America, 2006 (%) 5
Table 3 Distribution of Municipal Revenues, Selected OECD Countries, 2006 (%) 6
Table 4 Distribution of Municipal Revenues, Selected Countries in
Central and Eastern Europe, Asia, Africa, and Latin America, 2006 (%) 7
Table 5 Local Government Expenditures as a Percentage of GDP
and Total Government Expenditures 9
Table 6 Urban Population by Major Area, Selected Periods, 1950-2050 10
Table 7 Percentage Urban by Major Area, Selected Periods, 1950-2050 11
Table 8 Sources of Municipal Operating Revenues for Selected Cities 22
Table 9 Base for Property Taxes 27
Table 10 Types of Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers 36
Table 11 Development Charges, Greater Toronto Area, 2007 49
Table 12 The Steps in the Capital Budget 58
Figures
Figure 1 Public Debt, Spending and Investments – the Role of Local Governments (2000) 15
Figure 2 Different Financing Tools for Different Services 18
Figure 3 Calculating the Tax Increment 53
Figure 4 Steps in the Budgetary Process 59
Boxes
Box 1 Public Finance Principles 20
Box 2 Characteristics of a Good Local Tax 22
Box 3 How Property Tax Capitalization Works 23
Box 4 Road Pricing in Singapore 34
Box 5 Public Finance Principles for Designing Fiscal Transfers 39
Box 6 Types of Public-Private Partnerships 44
Box 7 Calculating Development Charges 47
Box 8 Implementation of Tax Increment Financing 50
Box 9 Steps for Tax Increment Financing 52
Box 10 Citizen Involvement Participatory Budgeting in Porto Alegre 60
Box 11 Municipal Finance and Management Initiative in Ghana 67
Box 12 Illustration of a Tax-Free Bond 67
v
ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS
vi
FOREWORD
vii
viii
Definition of Municipal Finance
and Objectives of the Guide
CHAPTER 1
Interest in cities around the world is on the rise, OBJECTIVES OF THE GUIDE
in large part, because more and more people
The objective of this Guide to Municipal
are living in cities in both developed and less
Finance is to introduce government officials,
developed countries. The rapid increase in the
policy makers, professional practitioners, civil
urban population has put pressure on local
society, and academics in UN member states
governments to provide a range of services
to the current issues in municipal finance
from water and sewer infrastructure to social
in countries around the world. The Guide
services and housing. To meet the rising
emphasizes the important role that municipal
demands of urbanization, municipalities need
finance plays in local service delivery,
adequate revenue tools to pay for services and
particularly in the context of globalization,
infrastructure.
decentralization, and a focus on sustainable
development. It highlights some of the new
DEFINITION OF MUNICIPAL FINANCE trends in financing services that are being
used in different countries around the world
Municipal finance is about the revenue such as increased reliance on the private
and expenditure decisions of municipal sector to invest in infrastructure and services.
governments. It covers the sources of revenue Finally, an important objective of the Guide
that are used by municipal governments – is to provide policy makers with some basic
taxes (property, income, sales, excise taxes), economic tools and a framework for analyzing
user fees, and intergovernmental transfers. public finance issues and evaluating different
It includes ways of financing infrastructure ways of financing both operating and capital
through the use of operating revenues and expenditures at the local level.
borrowing as well as charges on developers and
public-private partnerships. Municipal finance Given the length of the Guide, it is not
also addresses issues around expenditures possible to delve into all topics in depth and
at the local level and the accountability for some topics, such as the governance of cities
expenditure and revenue decisions, including and metropolitan areas, are not included at
the municipal budgetary process and financial all. It is also only possible to provide examples
management. of municipal finance techniques from a few
selected countries. For this reason, references
are provided throughout the Guide for those
who seek more information on specific topics
or specific countries.
1
Guide to
Municipal Finance
2
Municipal Finance Issues,
Challenges, and Trends
CHAPTER 2
3
4
Table 1: Distribution of Municipal Expenditures, Selected OECD Countries, 2006 (%)
General Public Services Public Economic Total Environmental Housing & Health Recreation, Education Social Total
Guide to
Australia 1.6 24.4 2.6 21.5 26.7 9.5 13.7 1.2 15.7 0.4 5.8 100
Austria 0.5 16.9 2.1 n.a. 14.2 2.6 2.8 16.3 7.1 16.7 21.3 100
Canada 2.7 8.7 9.2 11.6 13.2 5.9 7.8 1.5 6.9 41.2 5.5 100
Czech Republic 0.7 14.5 1.8 18.9 21.4 7.3 9.1 2.2 7.5 27.5 8.7 100
Denmark 0.5 6.1 0.3 2.8 4.7 0.9 0.4 20.4 2.7 12.9 51.5 100
Finland 0.6 14 2.1 4.1 6.1 0.7 0.4 28.4 4.6 20.5 23.3 100
France 1.4 19.2 2.8 n.a. 13.1 6.9 15.2 0.6 10.2 16.2 15.8 100
Germany 3.2 17.4 5.4 n.a. 13.5 6.8 7.7 2.3 n.a. 7.2 39.7 100
Hungary 0.5 19.3 1.2 n.a. 5.7 3.9 6.9 15.4 4.8 29.9 12.8 100
Iceland 3.1 10 0.9 11 11.7 2.4 4.5 0.8 17.3 37.2 15 100
Ireland 0.9 11.4 3.2 n.a. 23.8 8.7 22.7 0 4.1 20.7 5.4 100
Italy 1.6 14.6 1.5 n.a. 14.8 4.6 4.7 43.9 3 8.3 4.5 100
Luxembourg 1.3 20.9 1.7 n.a. 15.9 12.1 7.6 0.3 13.1 24.6 3.9 100
New Zealand 2.9 18.3 0.5 29.7 35 21.3 7.3 0 12.1 0 5.5 100
Norway 2.7 10.7 1 4.9 6.5 3.6 4.2 15.2 4.8 28.4 25.6 100
Poland 0.8 9.4 1.8 13 14.8 4 5.6 15.3 5.2 29.6 14.2 100
Slovak Republic 0.7 17.5 1 11.3 15.9 6.2 9.9 0.3 7.1 35.4 6.6 100
Spain 1.3 33.4 7.8 9.8 14.5 10 9.6 1.2 10.9 4.5 8.1 100
Switzerland 3.3 14.3 5.2 7.3 8.7 5.3 2.5 20.5 5.6 21.7 16.2 100
Notes: Sub-categories of general public services include public debt transactions and general transfers between levels of government. Sub-categories of economic affairs include agriculture,
forestry, fishing, and hunting; fuel and energy; mining, manufacturing and construction; transport; and communications. Sub-categories of health include outpatient services, hospital services, and
public health services. Public debt transactions include interest payments and outlays for underwriting and floating government loans. Sub-categories of education include pre-primary and primary
education; secondary education; and tertiary education.
Information for Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, New Zealand, Norway, and Slovak Republic are preliminary estimates for 2006. Information for France, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, and Switzerland are
for 2005. Information for Finland and Spain are preliminary estimates for 2005.
Source: International Monetary Fund, Government Finance Statistics, Yearbook, 2007, Table 7 and IMF Statistics Department, Government Finance Statistics Manual, 2001.
Table 2: Distribution of Municipal Expenditures, Selected Countries in Central and Eastern Europe, Asia,
Africa, and Latin America, 2006 (%)
General Public Public Order, Economic Affairs Environmental Housing & Health Recreation, Education Social Total
Services Safety, Defense Protection community culture and protection expenditures.
amenities religion
Public debt Total Transport Total
transactions
Central and Eastern Europe:
Belarus 0.2 7.1 2 5.2 13.3 0 16.8 21.3 5.1 28.5 5.9 100
Bulgaria 0.3 11.5 3.1 9.5 12.1 -6.7 26.3 4.7 5.3 35.7 8 100
Croatia 0.5 16.8 2.6 9.8 13.4 3.5 18.6 4.6 13.2 20.1 7.2 100
Georgia 0.6 9.2 2.1 0.1 -0.3 0 59.7 2.7 8.9 8.7 9 100
Kazakhstan 0.1 16.6 3.9 7.7 12.9 0.4 13.5 18.6 4.4 26 3.8 100
Kyrgyz 0 13.3 1.9 0.6 1.7 0 10.6 5.2 4.3 58.4 4.7 100
Republic
Latvia 0.8 13.5 1.4 7.5 8.1 n.a. 14.6 2.8 7.8 44.1 7.8 100
Lithuania 0.2 5 0.7 1.8 7.1 2.3 5.9 21.9 5.4 40.5 11.2 100
Moldova 0.5 12.7 3.1 2.8 9.6 0 17.7 1.7 5.1 45.9 4.1 100
Romania 0.4 10.7 1 14.6 16.7 2.8 18.9 0.7 5.6 30.9 12.8 100
Russian Fed. 0.4 10.7 1.7 2.7 3.4 0.2 19 14.1 4.2 38 8.7 100
Slovenia 0.1 9.5 1.4 8.4 13.2 4.5 5.1 11.8 8 42.5 4 100
Ukraine 0.4 9.9 0.2 4 10.6 0.6 10.3 20.9 4 28.7 14.9 100
Asia, Africa and Latin America:
China, PR 0.1 21.3 6.0 1.3 39.7 4.4 0.4 3.4 1.6 12.4 10.8 100
Kenya 0.2 32.7 0.0 9.4 45.6 0.0 6.3 6.6 0.0 6.7 2.1 100
Mauritius 0.2 30.9 0 22.4 30.2 0 17.7 1.7 5.1 45.9 10.2 100
South Africa 0 4.9 0.7 4.5 7.1 0.5 3.1 20.8 0.9 34.9 27 100
Uganda 0 24.4 0.8 n.a. 10.8 0.4 3.2 14.1 0.3 44.6 1.3 100
Bolivia 2.1 12.9 1 14.5 21.5 7.3 20.4 11.5 6.9 16.3 2.1 100
Challenges, and Trends
Municipal Finance Issues,
5
Notes and Sources: See Table 1. Also, information for Uganda is preliminary for 2006. Information for Romania, China, and Kenya is for 2005. Information for
South Africa is for 2004.
6
Table 3: Distribution of Municipal Revenues, Selected OECD Countries, 2006 (%)
Guide to
Austria 14.6 3.7 10.3 5.5 12.1 4.4 4.8 55.3 4.6 13.9 26.2 100
Canada 0 0 0 37.8 0 0 2.1 39.9 0 41.8 18.3 100
Czech Republic 13.2 13.5 0 1.4 18.8 0 1.3 48.2 0 39.9 11.9 100
Denmark 46.4 1.1 0 3.4 0 0 0 50.9 1.6 39.1 8.4 100
Finland 40.8 3.8 0 2.4 0 0 0 47.1 0.1 28.6 24.2 100
France 0 0 3.1 33.7 0 3.7 4.1 44.6 0.2 29.1 26.1 100
Germany 15.8 0.2 0 5.4 1.8 0 18.8 42 1.3 33.8 23 100
Hungary 15.8 0 0 4.5 13.1 0 2 35.5 0.2 48.4 15.9 100
Iceland 53.1 0 0 10.5 0 0 9.4 72.9 0 8.8 18.3 100
Ireland 0 0 0 9.4 0 0 0 9.4 3.5 59.6 27.6 100
Italy 7.9 0.7 0 5.7 2.2 2.7 25.3 44.5 0.6 43.4 11.5 100
Luxembourg 0 28.6 0 2.2 0 0 0.7 31.4 0.2 46.6 21.7 100
New Zealand 0 0 0 54.5 0 0.5 0 55 0 11.2 33.8 100
Norway 40.1 0 0 4.1 0 0 0.9 45.1 0 36.1 18.8 100
Poland 14.7 4.3 0 9.4 0 0 3.9 32.5 0 50.6 16.9 100
Slovak Republic 38.5 0 0 6.4 0 0 6.8 51.8 0.6 35.1 12.6 100
Spain 7.5 2.3 0 16 13.3 3.1 10 52.2 0.5 34.5 12.8 100
Switzerland 33.8 5.2 0 7.1 0 0 0.1 46.3 0 16.3 37.4 100
Notes: Social contributions are actual or imputed receipts from either employers on behalf of their employees or from employees, self-employed, or non-employed persons on their own behalf that
secure entitlement to social benefits for the contributors, their dependents, or their survivors. The contributions may be compulsory or voluntary. Grants are noncompulsory transfers received by
government units from other government units or international organizations. Grants may be classified as capital or current and can be received in cash or in kind.
Information for Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, Ireland, New Zealand, Norway, and Slovak Republic are preliminary for 2006. Information for Spain is for 2004 and for Switzerland 2005.
Source: International Monetary Fund, Government Finance Statistics, Yearbook, 2007, Table 1 and IMF Statistics Department, Government Finance Statistics Manual, 2001.
Table 4: Distribution of Municipal Revenues, Selected Countries in Central and Eastern Europe,
Asia, Africa, and Latin America, 2006 (%)
Taxes Social Grants Other Total
contributions revenue revenues
Individual Corporate Payroll Property Goods and Excise Other Total taxes
income income services
Central and Eastern Europe:
Belarus 17.9 10.5 0 9.2 21.4 1.1 7.2 67.3 0 30.2 2.5 100
Bulgaria 0 0 0 20.1 0 0 0.1 20.3 0 69.9 9.9 100
Croatia 39.5 15.5 0 3.5 0.4 0 2.3 61.2 0 12.3 26.5 100
Georgia 50 2.1 0 11.1 0 0 3.7 66.9 0 28 5 100
Kazakhstan 17.2 0 24.6 5.9 0 3.3 5.3 56.3 0 43 0.6 100
Kyrgyz Republic 9.2 7.5 0 7.8 11.1 2.4 1.7 39.8 0 45.8 14.4 100
Latvia 48.4 0 0 6.5 0 0 0.8 55.6 0 31.3 13.1 100
Lithuania 30.2 0 0 4.1 0 0 0.9 35.3 0 57.9 6.8 100
Moldova 23.4 13.8 0 4.9 0.8 0.1 4.9 47.9 0 45.2 6.9 100
Romania 38.6 0.2 0 7.8 31.4 0 3.7 81.7 0 8.4 10 100
Russian 19.2 4.2 0 3.6 0 0 3.7 30.7 0 58.2 11.1 100
Federation
Slovenia 24 0 0 7.2 0 0 2.8 34.1 0 47.5 18.5 100
Ukraine 32.9 1.4 0.2 2.3 0 0.1 5 41.8 0 47.9 10.3 100
Asia, Africa and Latin America:
China, PR 2 5 0 2.4 18.4 0 2.2 30 13.3 28.9 27.9 100
Kenya 0 0 0 15.6 0 0 5.9 21.4 0 32.8 45.8 100
Mauritius 0 0 0 11.9 0 0 13.9 25.8 0 67.1 7.2 100
South Africa 0 0 0 16.8 0 0 2.8 19.7 0 24.9 55.4 100
Uganda 1.2 0 0 2.8 0 0 0.9 4.9 0 91.3 3.8 100
Bolivia 0 8.2 0 18.6 18 24.5 3.1 72.3 0 17.6 10 100
Notes and Sources: See Table 3. Information for South Africa and Uganda are preliminary for 2006.
Challenges, and Trends
Municipal Finance Issues,
7
Information for China and Kenya is for 2005. Information for Romania is for 2004.
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Tables 3 and 4 provide a breakdown of local One of the reasons for differences in
government revenues in selected countries. As expenditures and revenues at the local level
with expenditures, the dependence on various around the world is that the importance of local
revenue sources is different from country to government overall varies. Table 5 shows local
country. Property taxes, for example, are levied government expenditures both as a percentage
by local governments in all of the countries in of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and as a
the tables but only provide a significant source percentage of total government expenditures
of local revenue in Australia, Canada, New (including all levels of government) for most
Zealand, and France. Property taxes are also of the countries in Tables 1 to 4. Table 5 shows
an important source of revenue in the United that local government expenditures account
Kingdom which is not included in these tables. for a significant portion of GDP and of
Income taxes are more important at the local total government expenditures in the Nordic
government level in Nordic countries where countries (especially in Denmark and Finland
social expenditures are also significant at the and to a somewhat lesser extent in Norway and
local level. For all local taxes, the extent to Iceland). Local governments are also significant
which local governments have the autonomy in some central European countries (such as
to set their own taxes is not clear from these Kazakhstan and Ukraine) and in China. Local
tables but, in many countries, local tax rate governments account for a very small portion
setting does not exist or is limited. of GDP and total expenditures in Australia
where the state governments perform many
Dependence on intergovernmental transfers by local functions. It is also very small in Kenya.
local governments is widespread but the extent
of that dependence varies in the different
countries. For example, government transfers
are still the most significant revenue source for
local governments in many countries but they
have been decreasing in many North American
and European jurisdictions. Finally, the
components of the “other revenues” category
are not set out but likely include user fees,
fines, and other miscellaneous local revenues.
These revenues appear to be less significant
in central and eastern Europe than in other
countries.
8
Municipal Finance Issues,
Challenges, and Trends
10
Municipal Finance Issues,
Challenges, and Trends
11
Guide to
Municipal Finance
The population outside of the city uses The “knowledge workers” who increasingly
services in the city that are not available in hold the key to economic success are attracted
the periphery with resulting impacts on water by such quality of life factors as diversity,
pollution, traffic, crowding of hospitals and tolerance, a lively arts scene, recreational
public schools, and crime rates (Rezende, opportunities, high quality public schools,
1998). strong neighbourhoods, and safety from crime
(Florida, 2002).
From a municipal finance perspective,
the unique characteristics of large cities Globalization also affects the ability of local
and metropolitan areas are reflected in the governments to raise revenues. The taxation
magnitude and complexity of the expenditures of non-residential properties, for example,
that local governments in those areas are is affected by the mobility of industries in
required to make on municipal services. These a globalized environment. Businesses are
characteristics are also reflected in their ability more mobile in this context and respond
to pay for services. Generally, large cities and to differential property taxes in different
metropolitan areas have greater fiscal capacity locations (Kitchen and Slack, 1993). Local
than smaller municipalities and rural areas, governments have to be aware of the impact
both in terms of greater responsibility for local of their tax policies on businesses. Cities also
services and greater ability to levy their own have to manage their finances responsibly to
taxes and collect their own revenues. attract private investors and to access capital
markets (Serageldin et al., 2008).
Rarely are large cities treated differently,
however, in terms of their taxing authority or
the intergovernmental transfers they receive. Millennium Development Goals
One possible exception is the German structure,
In 2000, leaders from 189 countries set out
which distinguishes among governments of
a vision in the UN Millennium Declaration
different sizes giving broader responsibilities to
to eradicate poverty and increase the welfare
“city-states” (Berlin, Bremen, and Hamburg)
of the world’s poorest by 2015. To provide a
and allowing other large municipalities to
framework to measure progress towards this
assume responsibilities of counties.
vision, they established eight goals, 18 targets,
and 48 indicators. The UN Millennium
Globalization Development Goals (MDGs) include:
eradicate extreme poverty and hunger; achieve
Globalization is another challenge facing universal primary education; promote gender
municipalities. To be globally competitive, cities equality and empower women; reduce child
need to provide the supportive infrastructure mortality; improve maternal health; combat
to attract business and they need to provide HIV/AIDS, malaria, and other diseases; ensure
a wide range of services: transportation, environmental sustainability; and develop a
water, sewers, garbage collection and disposal, global partnership for development (United
police and fire protection, parks, recreation Nations, 2008).
and culture, affordable housing, and social
assistance. Cities must also provide services
to attract and retain highly trained human
capital.
12
Municipal Finance Issues,
Challenges, and Trends
14
Municipal Finance Issues,
Challenges, and Trends
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
Austria
Belgium
Denmark
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Ireland
Italy
Luxembourg
Netherlands
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
United Kingdom
Local debt as % of the total public debt
Local expenditures as % of the total public expenditures
Local investments as % of the total public investments
Source: Dexia (2000) Local Finance in Eleven Countries of Central, Eastern and Baltic Europe (Paris) as reproduced
in Swianiewicz, P. (ed.) (2004) Local Government Borrowing Risks and Reward, A Report on Central and Eastern
Europe, Budapest: Open Society Institute, p. 17.
15
Guide to
Municipal Finance
16
Principles of Municipal Finance
CHAPTER 3
This chapter provides the theoretical framework According to the “subsidiarity principle”
that will be used to evaluate municipal financial (Barnett, 1997), the efficient provision of
tools in subsequent chapters. It begins with services requires that decision-making be
the appropriate role for local government in carried out by the level of government that
the economy, then describes the benefit model is closest to the individual citizen. As long as
of local government finance, and sets out some there are local differences in tastes and costs,
principles of municipal finance. there are clear efficiency gains from delivering
services at the local level. This principle goes
on to say that expenditure responsibilities
ROLE OF LOCAL GOVERNMENT IN THE should only be assigned to a higher level of
ECONOMY government if it can be demonstrated that it
can carry out the function more efficiently
In terms of economic theory, the major role
than the lower level. With few exceptions (such
assigned to local governments is to provide
as national defence and services that involve
goods and services within a particular
income redistribution), almost all public
geographic area to residents who are willing
services should be provided at the local or
to pay for them. Local governments should
regional level with local policy-makers making
not do stabilization policy because they do
decisions about what services to provide, how
not have access to monetary policy tools and
much to provide, and who should pay for
because capital and labour flow freely across
them.
local jurisdictions. They should also not
engage in redistribution because local efforts
to address income disparities will likely result
in the movement of high-income groups to
low-tax areas and low-income groups to high-
tax areas (Kneebone and McKenzie, 2003).
Although local governments do engage in
some redistribution through the act of taxing
and spending, redistribution should not be
the primary focus of what they do (Bird and
Slack, 1993).
17
Guide to
Municipal Finance
18
Principles of Municipal Finance
19
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Fairness (equity) based on benefits-received is achieved when those who consume public services pay
for them, just as someone who benefits from a private good pays for it. Fairness based on ability to pay
suggests that those with similar ability should pay similar amounts in taxes and user charges (horizontal
equity) and those with different ability should pay different amounts (vertical equity).
Accountability means that taxes (charges) and expenditures should be designed in ways that are clear to
taxpayers so that policymakers can be made accountable to the taxpayers for the services they deliver and
the costs they incur. The more direct the relationship between the beneficiaries of a government service
and payment for that service and the less the complexity of the revenue system, the greater is the degree
of accountability.
Adequacy and Stability requires that revenues provide governments with sufficient funds to finance
services on a regular and continuing basis. Revenues should be stable and predictable so that
municipalities can budget and plan for future expenditures.
Autonomy means that municipal governments have autonomy and flexibility to set their own priorities.
To do this, they should minimize their dependence on revenues from other levels of government.
Ease and cost of administration means that the time and resources devoted to assess, collect, and account
for revenues should be minimized. Moreover, costs of compliance on the part of taxpayers should be
minimized.
20
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
CHAPTER 4
Municipal Revenues
This chapter sets out the characteristics of a Table 8 illustrates the sources of municipal
good local tax and then discusses a number revenue for four cities – Cape Town (South
of taxes and user fees that have been or could Africa), Toronto (Canada), Madrid (Spain),
be used by local governments. Because the and Mumbai (India). As noted above, cities
property tax is levied by local governments generally rely on local taxes, intergovernmental
in many countries, there is an extensive transfers, and user fees for local services but
description and analysis of this tax. The the dependence on each varies across cities.
chapter also devotes considerable time to All four cities in Table 8 levy a property tax;
intergovernmental transfers because many in Cape Town and Toronto, the property
local governments rely to a great extent on tax is the only local tax.1 Mumbai levies an
these transfers. octroi (a tax on the entry of goods into a local
area for consumption, use, or sale). Madrid
levies a variety of local taxes (including a tax
SOURCES OF MUNICIPAL REVENUE on land value, vehicles, construction, and
The sources of revenue for municipal business). User charges (or service fees) are
governments vary across countries but levied by all four municipalities but are most
generally include taxes, user fees, and significant in Cape Town where they are levied
intergovernmental transfers. Other revenues for electricity, water, sewerage, and cleansing.
may include investment income, property Dependence on government grants also varies
sales, and licenses and permits, for example. In among municipalities.
terms of taxes, the property tax is levied by local
governments in many countries. Other local
taxes can include income taxes, general sales
taxes, and selective sales taxes (for example,
taxes on fuel, liquor, tobacco, hotel occupancy,
vehicle registration), and land transfer taxes
(or stamp duties). To meet capital expenditure
requirements, some municipalities charge
developers for growth-related capital costs. In
some countries, particularly in South America,
a land value capture tax is sometimes levied to
1 Starting in 2008, Toronto also levies a vehicle registration tax and
pay for infrastructure. a land transfer tax.
21
Guide to
Municipal Finance
22
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
23
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Another reason why property taxes are A competing view sees the property tax as a
appropriate as a source of revenue for local tax on capital. For example, Zodrow (2000)
governments relates to the connection argues that the property tax in the United
between the types of services funded at the States results in distortions in the housing
local level and the benefit to property values. market and in local fiscal decisions. According
Fischel (2000), for example, has argued that to this view, the property tax (based on market
the property tax in the United States is like value) discourages building and results in
a benefit tax because taxes approximate the the underutilization of land. The amount of
benefits received from local services. Under capital per unit of land is less than what is
these circumstances, the property tax promotes economically efficient.
efficient public decisions because taxpayers
will support those measures for which the Both of these approaches have some validity.
benefits exceed the taxes. Both the benefits The property tax is not purely a benefits tax,
derived from local services (for example, good because homeowners who improve their
schools, access to roads and transit, and so houses will face higher taxes and will therefore
on) and the taxes are capitalized into property be discouraged from doing so. At the same
values. Because taxpayers are willing to pay time, the benefits and costs of local programs
more for better services and lower tax rates, are reflected in local property values.
this translates into higher property values.
Unique Characteristics of the
Of course, this analysis is based on a number Property Tax
of assumptions such as that local property There are at least four characteristics of the
taxes do finance services that benefit property property tax that differentiate it from other
values, that the incidence of such taxes is on taxes. First, the property tax is a highly visible
local residents, that both tax rates and service tax. Unlike the income tax, for example, the
levels are decided by local residents, that property tax is not withheld at source. Rather,
those who wish to ’buy’ other combinations taxpayers generally have to pay it directly in
of services and tax rates are free to move to periodic lump-sum payments. This means that
other jurisdictions, that – impelled by their taxpayers tend to be much more aware of the
sensitivity to property values – people will property taxes they pay. The exception is where
act rationally in response to such signals, and mortgage institutions include property tax
that local governments do what voters want payments with monthly mortgage payments.
them to do. The strength and validity of The property tax also finances services that
many of these links is obviously suspect in the are highly visible, such as roads, garbage
context of many developing countries (Bird collection, and neighborhood parks. Visibility
and Slack, 2004). Moreover, this argument enhances accountability but it restricts the
becomes particularly tenuous when it comes to ability of local governments to raise or reform
explaining the commonly found phenomenon than tax.
of higher taxation on non-residential property
(the over-taxation of non-residential property
is discussed further below).
24
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
Second, the base of the property tax does At the same time, this differential treatment
not increase automatically over time, because does not necessarily reflect the differential use
property values respond more slowly to annual of services by different property types. Indeed,
changes in economic activity than incomes. some observers have suggested that non-
It is said to be an inelastic tax. Furthermore, residential properties use fewer services than
very few jurisdictions update property values residential properties, but pay more in taxes.
for taxation purposes on an annual basis. This For example, users of nonresidential property
means that to maintain property tax revenues often provide their own garbage collection,
in real terms or to raise property tax revenues, security, and fire protection (Kitchen and
jurisdictions have to increase the rate of the Slack, 1993). Moreover, since businesses
tax. As with visibility, inelasticity leads to tend to be more mobile than homeowners
greater accountability (taxing authorities (in other words, they are more responsive to
have to increase the tax rate to increase tax tax changes), efficiency arguments lead to
revenues), but it also leads to greater taxpayer the conclusion that non-residential property
resistance. should be taxed more lightly than residential
property. For these reasons, some authors have
Third, the property tax can be an important suggested that the non-residential property tax
instrument of local autonomy to the extent is not a good tax for local government and have
that it is only levied by local governments. recommended that it be replaced by a business
To ensure local autonomy, however, tax rates value tax (Bird, 2001a).
must be set locally and not by a senior level of
government. Mechanics of the Property Tax
Fourth, the property tax commonly favors The property tax is levied on residential,
single-family, owner-occupied, residential commercial, and industrial properties. Several
properties over apartments and commercial steps are involved in the process of taxing
and industrial properties in most jurisdictions real property: identifying the properties
around the world (Bird and Slack, 2004). In being taxed, preparing an assessment roll that
most transition economies, enterprises tend contains a description of the property and the
to pay higher property taxes than individuals amount of assessment, setting the tax rate or
(Malme and Youngman, 2000). Favorable series of rates, issuing tax bills, responding
treatment of single-family residential properties to assessment appeals, collecting taxes, and
is achieved by deliberately under-assessing addressing arrears. This section of the chapter
single-family residential property compared focuses on property identification, assessment,
to apartments and commercial and industrial tax rates, and tax collection. For information
property of comparable value; by legislating on the other steps in the process, see Dillinger
lower tax rates on single-family residential (1992) and Bird and Slack (2004).
property; and by providing property tax relief
measures to residential property owners in the
form of tax credits, homeowner grants, or tax
deferrals. These measures are not generally
available to non-residential properties.
25
Guide to
Municipal Finance
26
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
Value-based assessments use market value use and this is expected to continue, rental
(including site value assessment), rental value, value will bear a predictable relationship to
and self-assessment. Market value is defined market value: the discounted net stream of
as the price that would be struck between a net rental payments is approximately equal to
willing buyer and a willing seller in an arm’s- market value.
length transaction. Market value assessment
estimates the value that the market places on Self-assessments require property owners to
individual properties. Site value taxation is a place an assessed value on their own property.
special case of market value taxation where only In some countries, the taxing authority has
the land portion of the property is taxed; the the right to buy the property at the assessed
assessment base excludes any improvements to value. A system where the taxing authority
the land. can buy the property will only be credible if
it can and will buy property, but this right has
Under the rental value (or annual value) rarely been exercised, partly because of the
approach, property is assessed according to political impossibility of large-scale purchases
an estimate of rental value or net rent. One of residences.
rationale for using rental value is that taxes are
paid from income (a flow) rather than from Table 9 summarizes the different bases and
wealth (a stock), and thus taxing the net rental provides examples of countries where they are
value of real property is appropriate. In theory, used.
however, no difference should exist between a
tax on market value and a tax on rental value -
when a property is put to its highest and best
27
Guide to
Municipal Finance
28
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
In reality, however, tax jurisdictions generally Low collection rates can be attributed to lack
apply lower rates to residential properties. of political will, lack of transparent collection
On the basis that higher property taxes on and enforcement mechanisms, and lack of
buildings tend to slow development and that taxpayer confidence or understanding of
lower taxes speed up development, a municipal how the tax is levied, collected, enforced, and
policy to develop some neighborhoods instead used (Kelly, 2000). To improve compliance
of others would call for differential taxes in and collection, political will is needed and
different locations as well as for different administrative systems have to be improved.
property classes. In this case variable tax rates Local officials also have to be willing to use
are used to deliberately distort decisions to legal enforcement provisions. Local residents
achieve certain land use objectives. and businesses need to be convinced to pay
their taxes and this process can be facilitated
by improved service levels and the perception
Tax Collection that taxes are being administered fairly. In
Tax collection involves sending out tax bills, short, people are more willing to pay taxes if
collecting the taxes, and ensuring payment. they feel they are getting something for them.
Since the primary purpose of the property Community involvement in local decisions
tax is revenue generation, tax collection through mechanisms such as participatory
and enforcement are the most important budgeting (see section 6 below), for example,
components of the property tax system (Kelly, may also improve revenue collection.
2000).
Shortcomings of the Property Tax
If the property tax is not paid within a specified Although the property tax is generally regarded
time period after the due date, interest and a as a good tax for local governments, there are
late fee are generally charged. In cases of long- some problems in relying too heavily on this
term delinquency, other enforcement measures one tax. First, property taxes are costly and
are usually taken eventually leading to the sale difficult to administer well and these problems
of the property to satisfy the tax obligation. increase with the size of the tax burden (Bird,
Such sales are rare in most countries, 2001a). Lack of training, particularly in
however. Often, a more effective enforcement less developed countries, exacerbates these
mechanism (at least for properties transferred problems. Second, as noted earlier, there is a
within the formal legal system) is that property general tendency in most countries to over-tax
transfers are not permitted unless property non-residential properties which results in tax
taxes are paid (Bird and Slack 2004). exporting to residents of other jurisdictions
who are consumers of the products or services
Tax arrears reduce the revenues generated
produced in those properties. Tax exporting
from the property tax. Although tax arrears
reduces accountability because those bearing
as a proportion of taxes collectible are low in
the burden of the tax are not the same as
most developed countries (for example, 3 to
those enjoying the benefits. There is thus an
4 per cent in Japan and the U.K), they can be
incentive on the part of local residents to
very large in some less developed countries (for
demand greater expenditures because some of
example, 50 per cent in parts of Kenya and the
the cost is borne by others. Third, the property
Philippines). Tax arrears obviously tend to be
tax cannot finance major social expenditures
highest in countries that do not have sufficient
(such as social assistance, health, and
resources, expertise, or will to administer the
education) in most communities. The result is
property tax and where enforcement is weak.
that cities either have to restrict themselves to
delivering services such as garbage collection
and street cleaning or they have to rely on
intergovernmental transfers.
29
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Although the property tax is an appropriate The situation is somewhat similar in Iceland.
tax for local governments, it has been under- The local income tax is a big revenue raiser in
used particularly in developing countries Nordic countries yielding revenues of up to 15
where it accounts for only 0.6 percent of per cent of GDP.
GDP on average compared to more than 2
percent in industrialized countries (Bahl and Local income taxes have been levied only
Martinez-Vazquez, 2008). The main reasons occasionally in developing countries (Bahl
are inadequate administration and lack of and Linn, 1992) but subnational governments
enforcement. If decentralization continues in have been assigned significant shares of
developing countries and central governments income tax revenues in transitional economies
insist on local revenue mobilization, however, (Bird, 2001a). Local governments do not set
interest in local property taxes may increase the tax rates themselves, however. The result
significantly in the future (Bahl and Bird, is revenue sharing whereby local governments
2008). receive an intergovernmental transfer, the
amount of which is based on locally- collected
central government income tax revenues.
Personal Income Taxes
Unlike the property tax, the incidence of the
Although income taxes are used to some extent income tax is generally progressive though
at the local level, they are not as prevalent as it may not be clearly related to the benefits
property taxes. There are two quite different received municipal services. Moreover, income
types of income tax. The first, which is most tax revenues are more elastic than property tax
commonly used in Europe, is to levy a local revenues in that they increase automatically
income tax which is simply a proportion of as the economy expands. Of course, revenue
the central or state/provincial income tax or elasticity can be a problem when there is an
is at least calculated on the same tax base. The economic downturn.
second type is a separate, locally administered
income tax. The second type is less common One drawback of local income taxes is that the
because it is more difficult to implement and current practice in many countries is to lower
very expensive to administer. reliance on income taxation and increase
reliance on consumption-based taxes. This
Local governments in Nordic countries, which move, it is argued, creates fewer distortions
have large expenditure roles especially for social and reduces the deadweight costs associated
services and health, are permitted to impose with taxation (Boadway and Kitchen, 1999).
an income tax and to choose the rate of tax. Increasing local income taxes would counteract
Local governments set a flat tax that is applied current policy in those countries.
to the personal taxable income assessed for
national income tax purposes. The local flat Nevertheless, income taxes can be justified
rate is added to the national progressive rates. at the local level on the grounds that local
There is a risk that local authorities will use governments are increasingly being called
the income tax for excessive local tax increases upon to address issues of poverty, crime,
(Lotz, 2008). Although this is not a concern regional transportation, and other region-wide
in Sweden, this risk has led to a formalised needs. To the extent that local governments
system of negotiations in Denmark. In are required to provide social services, an
Norway, a maximum for the local tax rate was income tax is probably more appropriate than
established many years ago with the result that a property tax because the former is more
all Norwegian municipalities apply the capped closely related to ability to pay.
rate.
30
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
31
Guide to
Municipal Finance
32
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
33
Guide to
Municipal Finance
34
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
There are cases where charging full user fees Finally, users often regard public sector
may not be appropriate, however. Where a pricing as a revenue grab on the part of
good or service exhibits externalities, pricing local governments. Not only is it difficult to
at the marginal cost may not be appropriate. implement pricing under these circumstances
Externalities are benefits or costs of services but it is difficult to increase public sector prices.
that are not priced and may therefore not be Unlike prices in the private sector, once prices
taken into account by the user. Recreation are set in the public sector, users believe that
programs for at risk youth, for example, have they should not increase. Local governments
significant external benefits in terms of success have not done a good job of explaining to the
in school, lower crime rates, etc. When society public the important role that user fees play
puts a high value on these positive externalities, (Bird and Tsiopoulos, 1997).
then below-cost provision or subsidies are
warranted.
INTERGOVERNMENTAL TRANSFERS
Problems with Pricing
Transfers from senior levels of government
The most important general public concern are an important source of revenue for
with user fees is that they have an adverse municipalities around the world. These
impact on equity: low-income families cannot transfers can take different forms, as shown in
afford to pay user fees and will either not Table 10.
use the services or will have to reduce their
consumption of other services. Many studies
have shown that it is untrue in large urban areas, Types of Transfers
however, that those who benefit most from
Transfers can be broadly categorized as
under-pricing services make the most use of
unconditional (general purpose) or conditional
them, and the poor are not well-represented in
(specific purpose). Unconditional transfers
this group (Bird and Miller, 1989). Relatively
have no conditions attached to their use; funds
simple pricing systems, such as low initial “life-
can be spent on any local service or they can
line” charges for the first block of service use,
be used to reduce local taxes. In some cases,
can deal better with any remaining perceived
unconditional transfers are given on a per
inequity by introducing more adequate pricing
capita basis; in other cases, the amount of the
systems. These schemes are used for water, for
transfer depends on a formula which might
example, and for basic recreation programs,
take account of the expenditure needs of the
such as swimming programs for children and
municipality, the size of its tax base, or other
youth.
factors.
Some further problems with user fees include
Conditional transfers have to be spent on
the cost of pricing. For example, charging the
specific expenditures, for example, roads, parks,
marginal cost of water requires the metering
or some other local service. Conditional grants
of water and the installation of meters has
are “fungible,” however, in the sense that, even
a cost attached to it. There are also costs
though they come with strings attached, there
associated with the cost of information that
is no guarantee that the recipient will spend
municipalities need to price services correctly.
the funds on what the donor government
For example they need to know long-term
intended. For example, municipalities that
capital costs, infrastructure investments,
are already spending considerable funds in the
etc. Many municipalities lack the necessary
area specified by the donor government will
expertise to price correctly.
be able to divert grant funds to other purposes
and still meet donor requirements.
35
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Within the category of conditional transfers, would have to raise their own funds to cover
there are matching transfers and lump sum the remaining 40 percent of the cost. Lump
transfers. Matching transfers require that the sum conditional transfers (also known as
municipality match donor funds. For example, block grants) do not require the municipality
the donor may offer a transfer that covers to provide matching funds.
60 percent of the cost of road construction.
Municipalities, under this type of transfer,
36
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
The advantage of revenue sharing over ad hoc Equalization grants, based on expenditure
grants is that the transfer to municipalities needs and the ability of local governments to
automatically increases as the yield from that levy taxes, can ensure that those municipalities
revenue source increases. To be a stable source with relatively small tax bases and relatively
of revenue to municipalities, however, the high costs and needs will be able to levy tax rates
percentage share going to municipalities has to that are comparable to other jurisdictions.
be maintained over time. Revenue sharing does
not enhance local autonomy, accountability, Externalities (Spillovers)
or efficiency because local governments do not Grants are also appropriate where services spill
set the tax rates or the tax base. over municipal boundaries. If the municipality
responsible for the service bases its expenditure
Fiscal gaps can be closed in other ways. decisions only on the benefits captured within
For example, senior levels of government its jurisdiction, it will likely under-allocate
can give additional revenue-raising powers resources to this service.
to local governments or they can reduce
the expenditure responsibilities that local One way to provide an incentive to allocate
governments are required to undertake. more resources to the service generating the
Moreover, municipalities themselves could externality is a transfer from a senior level
reduce their expenditures or raise their taxes of government. The type of transfer that is
to close the fiscal gap. appropriate for addressing externalities is a
conditional, matching grant. The grant should
Horizontal Fiscal Imbalance be conditional in that it has to be spent on
Horizontal fiscal imbalance refers to the the service which generates the externality. It
differences in resources among governments should be matching to reflect the extent of the
at the same level. Some municipalities are externality. For example, if 50 percent of the
unable to provide an adequate level of service benefits of highway expenditures spill over
at reasonable tax rates compared to other existing municipal boundaries, the matching
municipalities for three reasons. First, tax bases rate should be 50 percent. For services that
differ from one municipality to another and spill over municipal boundaries, a provincial/
thus, to collect the same amount of revenue, state transfer is appropriate. For services
a municipality with a small tax base will have that spill over provincial/state boundaries, a
to levy a higher tax rate than a municipality national transfer is justified.
with a larger tax base. Second, the costs of
providing public services may be higher in one Matching grants require that the municipalities
municipality than another so that more tax contribute a portion of the funds to deliver
revenues are required to provide the same level the service. A uniform matching rate tends
of service. Third, the need for particular public to favour richer municipalities because they
services may be greater in one municipality are more able to match funds than poorer
than another, thereby necessitating higher municipalities, unless there is an equalization
expenditures (and higher tax revenues). component to the grant. Moreover, a matching
grant will only stimulate spending if the
Under these circumstances, an equalization municipality has the power over expenditures
grant is appropriate (Bird and Smart, 2002). and the ability to increase taxes.
These grants are usually unconditional but
can be used for specific expenditure categories
(e.g. education).
37
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Another way to address spillovers and, more are set out in Box 5. As with any list of criteria,
generally, to coordinate service delivery across it is not possible to design one transfer that
municipal boundaries within a metropolitan simultaneously meets all of these objectives.
area, is to change municipal boundaries so Different types of transfers can be designed to
that the government jurisdiction coincides meet different objectives.
with the service delivery region. The drawing
of municipal boundaries in this way is rarely
done, however, with the possible exception Problems with Transfers
of South African metropolitan municipalities Although there are solid economic and political
where the Municipal Demarcation Board sets justifications for intergovernmental transfers,
the boundaries (for a discussion of different grant funding is not always the best way to
models for governing large metropolitan areas, address municipal fiscal problems: “these
see Slack, 2006b, Slack, 2007b, and Bird and systems of grants, although serving legitimate
Slack, 2008). purposes, can, under certain circumstances,
be a source of serious fiscal mischief ” (Oates,
Political Rationales 2008: 330).
In addition to the economic rationales for
intergovernmental transfers set out above, Transfers can distort local decision-making.
there are political rationales. For example, Conditional transfers require municipalities
transfers are often introduced in response to to spend the funds they receive according to
a public outcry over deteriorating services or provincial/state (or national) guidelines and
infrastructure. Upper levels of government often require matching funds on the part of
may also use grants to encourage local the municipality. A matching transfer, by
governments to provide at least a minimum lowering the price of some services, encourages
standard of service in areas such as road safety, municipalities to spend more on those services.
policing, or water and waste water treatment. In the presence of externalities, this change
Intergovernmental transfers are often used in behaviour may be appropriate. Where
to provide incentives for local governments there are no externalities, however, or where
to act as agents of the donor government. the amount of the grant exceeds the amount
In this way, the donor government benefits of the externality, the resulting distortion in
from local management in providing a service. municipal behaviour is inappropriate.
Conditional grants are sometimes given to
Funding from senior governments can also
acquaint local governments with services
lead to inefficient local revenue decisions. In
they would not have provided on their own
particular, there is no incentive to use proper
with the expectation that they will eventually
pricing when grants cover a large proportion
take over the funding for them and the senior
of operating and capital costs. Large grants
governments can withdraw. To meet these
for water treatment plants, for example, can
political objectives, conditional, lump sum
reduce the incentive to use volumetric pricing
grants are usually used.
to reduce the demand for water or to engage in
asset management. As noted earlier, charging
Design of Transfers wherever possible and getting the prices right
is important for local governments to ensure
The design of fiscal transfers has important efficient service delivery. Intergovernmental
implications both for local service transfers should not be working against
provision and for the overall fiscal health of that objective. Transfers can undermine the
municipalities. Ten public finance principles incentives for sound fiscal behavior (Oates,
that can be helpful in designing fiscal transfers 2008).
38
Case Study of the Baan
Mankong (Secure Housing) Program
Efficiency: Efficiency is achieved if the grant is neutral with respect to local government decisions on the
allocation of resources to different activities. The exception is where the grant corrects existing distortions
in expenditure practices. For example, municipalities do not have the incentive to provide the correct
level of services where the benefits extend to residents of other jurisdictions. A grant provides the
incentive to increase expenditures to the optimal level.
Fairness (equity): Equity dictates that all municipalities should be able to provide an adequate level of
service without resorting to unduly high tax rates. To achieve this objective, the transfer to municipalities
should vary directly with the fiscal need and inversely with the fiscal capacity of the municipality
(capacity to raise own-source revenues).
Clear Objectives: Grant objectives should be clearly specified.
Accountability: The donor government should be accountable for the design and operation of the grant
program. The recipient government should be accountable to citizens and the donor government for the
use of the funds.
Transparency: This principle is an extension of the accountability principle. Transparency is enhanced
when the recipient government and citizens/taxpayers have access to information about the grant formula
and the allocation of funds.
Stability and predictability: Revenues should be stable and predictable so that municipalities can budget
and plan for future expenditures.
Revenue adequacy: Municipal governments should have adequate revenues to discharge their expenditure
responsibilities.
Autonomy: Municipal governments should have autonomy and flexibility to set their priorities and not be
constrained by grant funding.
Responsiveness: The grant formula should be flexible enough to allow municipalities to respond to
changing economic circumstances.
Simplicity: The grant formula should be based on objective factors over which local governments have
limited control. The formula should be easy to understand.
Source: Based on Shah (2007)
Transfers can reduce accountability. When Local governments are more likely to carry
two or more levels of government are funding out their expenditure responsibilities in a
the same service, accountability problems responsible manner if they are also raising the
can arise. When users or taxpayers want to revenues to pay for them.
complain about the service, they are not sure
which level of government is responsible for Transfers are rarely a stable and predictable
the problem. Moreover, when the level of source of revenue. The amount of money
government making the spending decisions local governments receive varies from year to
(municipalities) is not the same as the level year, in part depending on the fiscal state of
of government that is raising the revenues the donor governments. Lack of predictability
to pay for them (provincial/state or national makes it difficult for municipalities to
governments), accountability is blurred. There plan expenditures. When grants decline,
is no incentive to be efficient when someone municipalities have to make up the lost
else is responsible for funding. revenue by increasing property or other taxes,
user fees, or other revenues or by reducing
expenditures.
39
Guide to
Municipal Finance
One way to get around the problem of User fees are appropriate for financing many
unstable and unpredictable revenues is to set local services but most countries make much
the transfer amount as a percentage of national less use of charging than is desirable and, where
or provincial/state government tax revenues or user fees are charged, they are generally poorly
as a percentage of Gross Domestic Product designed from an efficiency point of view.
(GDP). In this way, municipalities know that Designing and implementing user charges can
their grants will increase each year with the be difficult and costly because the municipality
growth in the economy. has to distinguish among services for which
charges can be levied, calculate the marginal
cost of the service, and find ways to exclude
IMPLEMENTATION AND MANAGEMENT people who do not pay for the service. Even if
OF MUNICIPAL REVENUES properly designed, however, user fees are not
very popular with citizens, administrators, or
According to the theory of fiscal federalism, the
politicians.
only good taxes for local governments are those
that are easy to administer locally, are imposed Vehicle taxes such as vehicle registration fees,
mainly on local residents, and do not raise especially if they are piggybacked onto central
problems of harmonization or competition or state/provincial taxes, are not that difficult
between local or regional governments or to implement. Other taxes (such as income,
between local/regional governments and sales, and hotel) can be very expensive to
national governments (Bird, 2006). The only administer at the local level. Piggybacking
major revenue sources that pass these tests are onto regional or national taxes, however,
property taxes and possibly taxes on vehicle allows municipalities to set local surcharges on
and user fees. these taxes and minimize administrative and
compliance costs.
Property taxes, however, are often costly and
difficult to administer and these problems Finally, transfers may appear, in some ways, to be
increase with the size of the tax burden. Even the easiest source of revenue for municipalities
though the property tax is a good tax for because they do not have to raise the funds
local government, it rarely provides sufficient themselves. The donor governments, however,
revenues to meet expenditure needs. Revenues may demand that a lot of conditions be met
are insufficient at least in part because of to receive grant funds and they may require
ineffective administration -- inadequate land documentation on how the money has been
registration systems, inefficient assessment spent. Grants are not a stable and predictable
practices, and deficient tax collection and source of revenue for local governments and,
enforcement. Moreover, property taxes are as noted earlier, they reduce accountability
never politically popular because of their because the government spending the funds
visibility and the inherent arbitrariness in is not the same as the government raising the
assigning values to individual properties. funds.
40
Financing Capital Expenditures
CHAPTER 5
Municipal infrastructure is essential to the The remainder of this chapter describes the
economic, social, and environmental health different ways the local governments finance
of cities. Cities not only have to provide different types of infrastructure.
roads, transit, water, sewers, and other “hard”
services, they also have to provide “soft”
services that enhance the quality of life in their FUNDS FROM OPERATING REVENUES3
communities such as parks, libraries, social The use of current operating revenues to
housing, and recreational facilities. Cities finance capital spending is desirable to the
need adequate revenues to make the needed extent that the benefits of the spending accrue
infrastructure investments. to current users. Municipalities often use
The appropriate financing tool depends current operating revenues for assets with a
not only on the type of infrastructure (for short life expectancy (such as police cars or
example, roads, sewers, libraries, etc.) but also computers) or recurrent expenditures (such as
on the nature of the infrastructure investment the maintenance and upgrading of sidewalks
(Slack, 2005a). For example, there may be a and roads). Since operating expenditures
need to invest in new developments (provide (especially wages and salaries and supplies
infrastructure for greenfield developments and services) are often seen as the most
or intensification within urban areas), to urgent expenditures, however, maintenance of
provide new services in existing developments existing assets is often deferred (Serageldin et
(where communities are not fully serviced al., 2008).
or where the service has not been provided),
to maintain and replace old services (where
existing capacity has been exceeded because of
increased density in urban areas), or to invest
in mega-projects (for example, a transit system
or a water treatment plant that affects more
than one jurisdiction).
2 Capital expenditures generally refer to expenditures on goods
that have a useful life of more than one year. These expenditures 3 Operating revenues are revenues that the municipality collects
include, for example, the acquisition or construction of buildings, on a regular basis to meet current expenditures (for example,
structures, facilities, equipment, rolling stock or furnishings; wages, salaries, rents, and materials). Some municipalities set aside
expenditures on rehabilitation; and the purchase of land a portion of their total annual operating budget each year for
(Kitchen, 2003). capital expenditures.
41
Guide to
Municipal Finance
42
Financing Capital Expenditures
The use of private capital is limited in scope Long-term borrowing is generally restricted
to infrastructure that has a revenue stream. As to financing capital expenditures. For
Annez (2006) notes, even for infrastructure infrastructure whose benefits accrue to
such as water where it is possible to have future residents, fairness, efficiency, and
a revenue stream from user fees, full cost accountability are enhanced if these projects
recovery is rarely achieved. Although it is are financed by borrowing with annual interest
possible to attract private investment for charges and repayment of the borrowed funds
commercial activities (for example, water and coming from local tax revenues (for capital
toll roads), however, even these services tend assets that benefit the municipality in general
to involve considerable subsidies. Significant but for which specific beneficiaries cannot
subsidies on current operations significantly be identified) and user fees (for capital assets
reduce the attractiveness of the investment to that benefit specific users) imposed on future
the private sector. beneficiaries (Bird and Wilson, 2003: 24).
Examples of capital expenditures for which
borrowing is appropriate include fire and
MUNICIPAL BORROWING police infrastructure, recreational facilities,
Borrowing to make capital expenditures libraries, roads and streets, public transit, solid
permits municipalities to synchronize the waste facilities, and water and sewer systems.
costs and benefits of infrastructure over time. Long-term borrowing offers additional benefits.
A project built today will result in benefits over It spreads the impact on the operating budget
the next, say, 25 years. If funds are borrowed, over a number of years. It allows projects to be
the project is paid for over the next 25 years constructed simultaneously during a period of
through repayment of the principal and rapid growth and assessment. It may reduce
interest. This means that those who benefit the real cost of projects during periods of
from the facility (the users over the next 25 increasing cost inflation (this occurs when the
years) also pay the costs through taxes and user cost of labour and materials increases without
fees. Borrowing is more equitable and efficient any improvement in technology or quality of
when those paying for services are enjoying inputs). And it is a useful tool for handling
the benefits. emergency situations such as sudden declines
Borrowing allows a municipality to enjoy in other capital funding sources (such as
the immediate benefit from the capital grants) or sudden increases in capital needs.
improvement, which is not always possible The main disadvantage of borrowing from a
when relying on current revenues. Current municipal perspective is that potential revenues
revenues (taxes and user fees) are usually not are dedicated to debt repayment and are thus
sufficient to fund large expenditures on a “pay- not available for other uses. When the costs are
as-you-go basis” (PAYG). The pattern of capital spread over time, a significant portion of local
expenditures is lumpy and this means that budgets becomes a fixed obligation and debt
a municipality may find it needs substantial charges can constrain local fiscal flexibility.
funds to finance an infrastructure project for A municipality with low debt also has more
one year and then the need declines for a few flexibility to respond to unanticipated future
years. Borrowing allows municipalities to avoid events.
large year-to-year fluctuations in tax rates.
43
Guide to
Municipal Finance
44
Financing Capital Expenditures
45
Guide to
Municipal Finance
landowners – depends to a large extent on the Box 7 sets out a methodology for calculating
demand and supply conditions in the market a development charge in eight steps. It also
for new housing. Most studies conclude that, describes the data that need to be collected
over the long term, development charges to estimate the charge and identifies some of
are borne by the new homebuyer. In some the policy decisions that need to be made in
cases, the predevelopment landowner, calculating the charge.
or some combination of the homebuyer,
predevelopment landowner, and the developer, Table 11 provides some examples of
may bear the cost. To the extent that the new development charges for municipalities in the
homebuyer bears the cost, then those who Greater Toronto Area for 2007 for different
receive the benefits from infrastructure are types of residential and non-residential
paying for them. properties. In each municipality, developers
are required to pay the development charge at
If properly implemented, development charges the local level as well as at the regional level.
can lead to efficient development patterns (i.e., In Georgina Township in York Region, for
discourage urban sprawl). To be efficient, the example, the residential development charge
charges have to be differentiated by location on single and semi-detached housing would
to reflect the different infrastructure costs. be under $20,000; in King Township, it would
For example, costs tend to be higher for be almost $26,000. The development charge
developments located further away from major on multiple units is generally lower per unit
facilities and for low-density developments. To than on single and semi-detached housing,
be efficient, development charges would have with the exception of Peel Region and its
to be higher in these locations. constituent municipalities where the charge
is the same as on single and semi-detached
One of the differences between levying housing. Apartments are charged less than
development charges and property taxes to multiple unit dwellings with apartments with
pay for capital costs concerns who borrows two or more bedrooms paying more per unit
the funds for the infrastructure. In the case than apartments with less than two bedrooms.
of the property tax, the municipality borrows On the non-residential side, retail is generally
funds; in the case of the development charge, charged more than industrial on the basis of
developers and new homebuyers borrow gross floor area, although in some cases the
funds. In developed countries, it is probably charge is the same. In a few cases, the city has
the case that municipalities can borrow chosen not to charge industrial properties any
funds more cheaply than new homebuyers development charge in an effort to promote
and probably more cheaply than developers. industrial development.
Development charges may thus be less efficient
than municipal borrowing in those countries.
In countries where municipalities are unable
to borrow, however, development charges may
provide a good alternative.
46
Financing Capital Expenditures
The following sets out a methodology for calculating development charges in eight steps:
Step 1: Estimate growth
The first step is to provide a forecast of housing units (for the residential charge) and square metres of
non-residential building space (for the non-residential charge). Information is needed on the anticipated
population growth rate, the housing stock composition, and occupancy rates (number of persons per
unit) for different types of housing. The accuracy of the population projections is key to the development
charge calculation because the projections determine the need for services and the levels of service are
generally calculated on a per capita basis.
To project the number of square metres for non-residential building space, employment forecasts are used
to estimate floor space per worker which is then converted into gross floor area for new development.
Step 2: Determine the services that will be covered by the charge
In theory, any capital costs that are needed because of growth should be included in the charge. In
reality, however, some costs are easier to assign to growth than others. For example, it is not difficult
to determine the proportion of costs that are growth-related for hard services such as water, sewers and
roads. There are some “grey areas,” however, with respect to what is growth-related. For example, the
expansion of a municipally-owned museum is unlikely to be fully attributable to growth and determining
the proportion that is attributable to growth may be difficult. One can think in terms of a continuum
of services ranging from those that are relatively easy to determine the growth-related portion to those
that are fairly difficult (and will be harder to justify). At the easy end would be water and sewers. The
next group would include roads, transit, recreational facilities, police, fire, public works, libraries, parks
and waste management. At the most difficult end would be museums, city halls, art galleries, convention
centres, and tourist facilities.
Step 3: Estimate the total capital costs to service growth
For each service for which a charge is going to be levied, capital costs have to be forecast over a period of
say 10 years. The estimates of capital costs need to be quite detailed, noting when in the planning period
they will be required based on estimates of the future growth. Where possible, capital costs should be
identified by specific areas of the municipality and by specific project (e.g. roads, traffic signs, etc.). The
magnitude of the costs needs to be reasonable and defensible. Where land costs are involved, for example,
land prices need to be realistic given current trends.
The next step is to determine what proportion of the estimated total capital cost is growth-related. In
most cases, the proportion is determined as the percentage of new population to the total population
(existing and new) and/or by the percentage of new employment to total employment (existing and
new).
Step 4: Determine service standards
To determine what portion of the growth-related capital costs is eligible for the charge for each service,
it is necessary to determine service standards. Municipalities need to establish realistic service standards
and they need to show that they are not trying to fund levels of service that are in excess of what they are
currently providing.
Examples of service standards include the average standard over the past 10 (or 5) years, the highest
standard achieved in the last 10 (or 5) years, or the standard in the current year. There are problems
with using the highest level of service in the last 10 years, however. For many services, the highest level
occurred in a year in which there was a major capital expansion. To the extent that facilities were built
to accommodate future growth, the levels of service in that year contains a significant amount of excess
capacity.
47
Guide to
Municipal Finance
48
Financing Capital Expenditures
49
Guide to
Municipal Finance
50
Financing Capital Expenditures
The widespread use of TIFs is, in part, because Debt repayment depends on future increments
they offer a way for municipalities to get in property tax revenues and the municipality
around borrowing limits; tax increment bonds has no obligation to pay bond holders if
are not subject to municipal debt limits or sufficient increment taxes are not generated.
public referendum requirements in most states.
This financing method results in more capital The calculation of the tax increment requires a
for infrastructure than would be available with comparison of expected property tax revenues
traditional general obligation bonds (different in the absence of any new development with
types of borrowing tools are described more the expected property tax revenues once the
fully in Chapter 7). development has occurred. The first part of
this calculation involves an estimate of the base
There are some potential problems associated level property taxes on all properties in the TIF
with TIFs, however. TIFs may not be able to district now and in the future. The second
generate the predicted tax revenues and the part involves the calculation of the estimated
resulting lack of funds could threaten efforts property tax revenues for the development.
to revitalize the designated area. Other taxing This latter estimate is based on a determination
authorities (such as school districts) resent of the ultimate use, built form, and density for
that their property taxes are frozen at a time all of the land that will be redeveloped as well
that they are experiencing growth in demand as the timing and location of the development.
as a result of the revitalization. TIFs may The detailed methodology used to determine
merely accelerate development that would the viability of a tax increment is set out in
have occurred anyway. TIFs target funds to a Box 9.
designated area and this targeting may be at the
expense of areas on the periphery of the TIF
district or at the expense of overall municipal
growth. Financing TIFs is expensive because
the default risk is transferred to bond holders
instead of the municipality.
51
Guide to
Municipal Finance
52
Financing Capital Expenditures
Base taxes
10 Natural growth increment
Increment to TIF
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
53
Guide to
Municipal Finance
54
Financing Capital Expenditures
or suburban use, changes in the use of the The land value increment tax is levied in
property by changing the use of all property addition to other taxes on property values
located in a certain zone of the city, increases such as the valorization contributions. When
in the level of exploitation by increasing the a valorization contribution has been imposed,
proportion of land on which construction is however, the factors in its determination cannot
allowed or the relation between the area of be considered in calculating the appreciation
construction and the area of land or both, and in property values for the land value increment
the construction of public improvements that tax. For example, if the municipality imposes a
are not financed by valorization contributions valorization to capture the cost of a new road,
(Bird, 2004: 277). the impact of the new road on property values
cannot be included in the calculation of the
The owners or occupiers are liable for the land land value increment tax.
value increment tax. The tax base is the amount
of the appreciation of land value which is Colombia has had considerable success in
calculated as the difference in the value of the recouping some of the benefits to adjacent
property before and after the “urban actions.” property owners from certain public
Municipal councils set the tax rate which investments using this tax (Bird and Slack,
has to be between 30 and 50 percent of the 2007). It is neither easy nor costless to
appreciation of the property. implement such a tax under conditions
found in most developing countries, however.
Perhaps this is why few developing countries
have managed to do much with this potentially
useful fiscal instrument.
55
Guide to
Municipal Finance
CHAPTER 6
Municipal Budget,
Financial Reporting and Auditing
56
Municipal Budget,
Financial Reporting and Auditing
1937). The budget is a very important Operating budgets may take different forms
document because, if properly prepared, and each form provides a different type
it will eliminate unnecessary expenditures, of information for fiscal decision-making
increase efficiency in the methods of collecting (Schaeffer, 2000). A line-item budget relates
revenues, and preserve the credit rating of the revenues and expenditures to commodities
municipality (Tassonyi, 2002). with the underlying purpose of control of
the municipal budget. A performance budget
Budgeting has always been important as relates revenues and expenditures to workload
a means of controlling expenditures and with the underlying purpose to achieve
identifying revenues. In recent years, however, management efficiency. A program budget
the importance of budgets has grown relates revenues and expenditures to public
significantly as cities face increasingly difficult goals with the objective of meeting planning
expenditure and revenue decisions in an goals.
environment of increased demands for services
and infrastructure. Not only do budgets serve The capital budget sets out the local
as a necessary management and planning tool, government’s long term plan which is to be
they also contribute to the accountability and carried out over a number of years, usually a
transparency of the overall financial system of period of at least five years. Capital budgeting
local governments and reduce the possibility sets out a plan to acquire or rehabilitate long
of corruption and misappropriation of funds. term assets such as roads, water and sewer lines
and treatment plants, public buildings, and
sanitary landfills. At the same time, this plan
Operating and Capital Budgets indicates how all capital expenditures are to
Municipalities generally prepare two budgets: be financed (own source revenues, borrowing,
(1) an annual operating or current budget that grants, or other revenues).
consists of projected revenues and expenditures
The capital budget is an important management
plus relevant capital asset transactions for
tool because it allows the municipality and the
the upcoming fiscal year and (2) a capital
public to be informed on the need for capital
budget that lays out future capital expenditure
expenditures (short term and long term)
projects and anticipated revenues for funding
and it allows them to make more informed
these projects.
recommendations with respect to future
Municipalities face expenditure obligations capital spending. Schaeffer (2000) describes
on a recurring basis to provide the day-to- five steps in the development of the capital
day operation of services. Operating budget budget; these stages are set out in Table 12.
expenditures include wages and salaries,
pension contributions, the purchase of short-
life equipment, the purchase of services from
other agencies, materials and supplies, and
expenditures on repair and maintenance.
They may also include recurring financial
transactions such as servicing the long-term
debt (annual interest cost and principal
repayment) and contributions to reserve funds
established for specific purposes. Current
funds may also be transferred to the capital
budget to provide a portion of costs of capital
projects.
57
Guide to
Municipal Finance
58
Municipal Budget,
Financial Reporting and Auditing
Departmental budget
Initial requests at
requests and development
departmental level
of revenue constraint
Step 3:
Step 5: Step 4:
Audit of municipal
Execution of the budget
financial records
The first stage of the budgetary cycle is the the implementation and monitoring of the
preparation of initial requests for funds on budget throughout the fiscal year by the chief
the part of each department (for example, financial officer. The fifth stage is the audit of
transportation, water, recreation). The second municipal financial records by an independent
stage of the budget cycle involves the various auditor after the completion of the fiscal year.
departments sub¬mitting their budgetary The audit ensures that the municipality has
requests to the chief administrative or financial adhered to legal requirements regarding local
officer. This officer compiles, combines, and expenditures and that local officials have not
coordinates all requests for funds. The chief misappropriated local funds intentionally or
financial officer and his/her staff are also unintentionally (auditing is discussed further
responsible for estimating the anticipated below).
revenue yields for the year and acceptable
tax increases. Given the revenue constraint, As with any fiscal process, there are practices
priorities are set among the competing and pressures that can adversely affect
demands for expenditures. Inevitably, conflicts the budgetary process (Tassonyi, 2002).
arise and need to be resolved (Kitchen, 2003). Extra-budgetary funds (commonly used in
Departmental requests may be denied or municipalities in China, as noted in Chapter 5)
the financial constraint may be expanded. are funds that are outside of municipal budgets
Ultimately, the chief financial officer arrives and therefore independent of the scrutiny of
at a budget that is presented to the budget the formal budget process. Earmarked funds
committee of the municipal council. (funds that are mandated by local governments
to be spent on specific services) are tied up in
The third stage is the adoption of the budget reserve funds and provide the municipality
by the council. In some municipalities in all with no flexibility to use them for any other
countries, the public (taxpayers) is invited purpose. Unpredictability (for example,
to comment at public meetings on the when the amount or conditions attached to
proposed budget prior to council approval. intergovernmental transfers change) makes
Public participation (described further it difficult for local governments to plan for
below) is designed to add transparency and the future. Finally, unreliable information
accountability to the budgetary process. The hampers the ability of local governments to
fourth stage of the budget cycle involves make sound financial decisions.
59
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Citizen involvement
Box 10: Citizen Involvement:
Participatory budgeting refers to the practice of Participatory Budgeting in
including citizens in formulating the budget. Porto Alegre
Anyone interested in participating can do so
The first city to engage in participatory
individually or as part of an organization (such budgeting is Porto Alegre, Brazil which
as a residents’ association). There are four main introduced the practice in 1989. It is now
features of participatory budgeting (Serageldin used by 180 municipalities in Brazil and many
et al., 2008: 28): The first is the representation countries in Latin America and elsewhere.
of residents in each sub-area of the municipality Participatory budgeting was introduced, in
in the decision-making process. The second is part, as a way to address severe inequalities in
services (especially water and sanitation) and
that municipal officials are held to account for quality of life around the city.
the previous year’s budget and for estimates of
expenditures and revenues for the current year Participatory budgeting gives residents
some control over the annual allocation of
in order to determine the budget allocations. capital expenditures. Residents can decide on
The third is transparency which is achieved local matters, such as the location of street
through direct popular participation and an improvements or a park, as well as citywide
open voting system. The fourth is objectivity issues such as programs for helping the
through the use of quantitative criteria to homeless population.
prioritize funding requests and the allocation Regular decision-making forums of elected
of resources. representatives have been created at a number
of levels: sixteen regional forums bring people
Participatory budgeting improves together from different parts of the city; five
communication and dialogue between city thematic forums (such as health, education,
hall and citizens. It fosters social inclusion housing, sanitation) bring together people
from throughout the city; and a municipal
by allowing the poorest citizens to have a
budget council comprises representatives of the
voice in budgeting decisions and it empowers regional and thematic forums.
neighbourhood associations and small
The process covers all capital expenditures
organizations. Nevertheless, it can take a long
which range from 5 to 15 percent of the total
time to implement budgetary decisions, in budget of Brazilian municipalities. In Porto
part because it is necessary to teach citizens the Alegre, the number of participants in the
details of how the process works. Moreover, budgeting process is now more than 14,000
the number of people from the community people per year.
that participate is often very small and they Source: Abers, 2001, Goldsmith and
are not always representative of the youngest Vainer, 2002 and Serageldin et al., 2008
or the poorest in the population.
60
Municipal Budget,
Financial Reporting and Auditing
61
Guide to
Municipal Finance
62
Municipal Budget,
Financial Reporting and Auditing
Many countries have implemented some Financial audits often focus on financial
form of modified accrual accounting in the statements and thus do not address the
past 10 years. However, only four OECD efficient use of resources or the achievement
countries (Australia, Finland, Iceland, and of performance standards. Value-for-money
New Zealand) have implemented full accrual audits or performance audits (which are
accounting and others, such as Canada and discussed below) examine areas of waste and
the U.K., are rapidly moving in that direction mismanagement to suggest how a municipality
(Schaeffer, 2008). One of the reasons for lack can improve the efficiency of its operations
of widespread use of accrual accounting is the (Schaeffer, 2008).
difficulty and cost of implementation. For
example, governments may not know the full Some of the problems with local government
amount of tax revenue they are likely to receive audits, particularly in developing countries,
at any given time (Schaeffer, 2008). Moreover, are summarized in Schaeffer (2008) along
it can be costly to develop new computer with some suggestions for improvement: local
systems to support accrual accounting. governments need to build staff capacity,
establish uniform and transparent accounting
and auditing procedures, and standardize local
AUDITING government financial information.
63
Guide to
Municipal Finance
64
Municipal Borrowing and
Access to the Capital Market
CHAPTER 7
Municipalities in some countries are permitted Nevertheless, local access to capital markets is
to borrow to make capital expenditures. often heavily restricted in developing countries
This chapter looks at the role of municipal (Rodden et al., 2003). Smaller municipalities,
borrowing and borrowing instruments. It even in countries with well-developed capital
also sets out the factors that are used by bond markets, may be able to borrow only through
rating agencies to determine the credit rating a financing authority or state/provincial body,
of a municipality. partially to reduce borrowing costs by pooling
the requirements of different municipalities.
65
Guide to
Municipal Finance
66
Municipal Borrowing and
Access to the Capital Market
because it issues debentures more frequently In the case of general obligation bonds, the
than most individual municipal borrowers government uses its general revenues to
and it operates in a volatile capital market that support the debt service payments. These
is subject to a large amount of uncertainty. It bonds would be used for activities that do not
can exercise a greater degree of flexibility over produce revenues such as public education,
issue terms and costs to municipal clients. Box health, and welfare expenditures. Revenue
11 shows an example of a municipal finance bonds, unlike general obligation bonds, are
authority that pools debt for municipalities in legally secured by a specific revenue source.
Ghana. For example, a revenue bond issued by a
water and sewer utility would be backed by
the specific revenues of that utility (generally
Box 11: Municipal Finance
user fees) rather than the general revenues of
and Management Initiative
in Ghana the municipality. The advantage of revenue
bonds is that they promote full-cost pricing
A major new urban development initiative has of services and shift the risk to the investors.
been launched by the Government of Ghana.
As part of this initiative, it has introduced
The disadvantage is that they are often charged
legislation to help local authorities to access higher borrowing rates because they are not
long-term financing for infrastructure backed by the government’s overall revenues
and service delivery. The government has and are therefore considered to be riskier.
established the Municipal Finance Authority
which will borrow from domestic and Tax-exempt bonds enable municipalities to
international markets and then on-lend to local issue bonds at a lower interest rate because the
authorities including metropolitan, municipal interest is tax-free. The interest income is not
and district assemblies.
taxable by the personal or corporate income
Source: Cities Alliance without Slums: tax. Box 12 illustrates how a tax-free bond
http://www.citiesalliance.org/mfmi/overview.html.
works.
67
Guide to
Municipal Finance
68
Municipal Borrowing and
Access to the Capital Market
Debt: The debt position of the municipality as a percentage of revenue. This indicator
is another factor that goes into its credit shows the portion of municipal revenues
rating. Some factors relate to the size of the used to pay debt service costs. It reflects the
debt; others relate to debt service costs. In debt burden in relation to recurrent annual
terms of the size of the debt, one variable that resources potentially available to cover debt
is used is total debt relative to market value service. A high debt ratio may mean that the
of taxable property. This measure reflects the municipality has taken too much debt but it
use of property taxes to pay for debt service could also mean that it is aggressively paying
charges. Typically, a growing municipality down debt to avoid interest costs. Similarly,
with new development has a greater need a low debt ratio could indicate that the
for infrastructure and therefore it will incur municipality is financially strong but it could
higher costs. At the same time, it will have an also mean that it has deferred capital projects
increasing tax base to finance the debt through and allowed infrastructure to deteriorate.
property taxes. A second measure is debt per Finally a fourth factor is debt service costs as a
capita. This indicator reflects the ability and/ percentage of the municipal levy. This measure
or willingness of residents to pay debt service shows the portion of the property tax that is
costs and allows the municipality to compare its used for debt service. It is possible that a high-
per capita debt with other municipalities and growth municipality could manage a higher
to determine how debt is changing over time. debt service cost ratio since its property tax
It does not take into account fiscal capacity, revenues are likely increasing with assessment
however, because the tax base (the assessment growth more so than for other municipalities.
base in the case of property taxes, for example)
could be growing faster than population. A Finances: The bond rating agencies look at the
third measure is the debt to income (GDP) trend in financial performance and control
ratio. This measure relates the amount of debt including budgetary planning, daily spending
to economic activity and reflects the potential control, spending growth, use of surpluses,
debt servicing capacity of the municipality. and shortfall contingency plans. Agencies also
look at the general fund balance relative to
The factors that relate to debt service costs revenues, a measure of the financial reserves
include debt service costs per capita. This potentially available to fund unforeseen
measure reflects the willingness and/or ability contingencies. They want to ensure that
of residents to pay debt service costs. This general fund balances are sufficient to address
indicator will be conservative if the tax base normal contingencies. Other factors include:
(for example, property assessment) is growing revenues and expenditures; control over setting
faster than population. A fast growing taxes and other own-source revenues; types
assessment base reflects the greater capacity of taxes available to municipal governments;
of the municipality to pay the debt service reliance on inter-governmental transfers, their
costs. A second factor is debt service costs as stability, and restrictions on use; annual growth
a percentage of operating expenditures. This or volatility in expenditures and revenues;
measure shows the proportion of the operating inter-fund transfers; composition of assets
budget that is devoted to debt service and the and liabilities; cash position; and financial
direct impact of its indebtedness on the budget. performance relative to budget.
It also reflects the amount of budget flexibility
a municipality will have. If debt service costs
represent a large percentage of expenditures,
there will be fewer funds available for other
functions. A third factor is debt service costs
69
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Politics, Management, and Institutional The bond rating agencies have recognized a
Framework: Elements of management number of concerns and challenges in rating
strength that are reviewed include: division emerging market subnational debt. These
of responsibilities, professional qualifications; include (Vaillancourt, 2006: 55): unpredictable
sufficiency of power to perform functions; legal and regulatory frameworks, risky debt
management strategies; debt practices; and profile, unaudited financial data, burdens
economic development policies. Political imposed by publicly-owned companies,
considerations include political dynamics changing intergovernmental political and
and social climate. The institutional fiscal relationships, incomplete demographic
framework includes constitutional powers data, inflation effects, enormous infrastructure
and responsibilities, borrowing authority, and needs, and uncollected taxes and user fees. If
intergovernmental relations. local governments are given permission to
borrow in these countries, they will need to
address these issues.
70
Concluding Comments
CHAPTER 8
Concluding Comments
Interest in cities is increasing around the world, The choice of revenue tools will also have an
in part, because more people are living in cities impact on the ability of local governments
than ever before and, in part, because recent to deliver services and attract business. The
trends towards fiscal decentralization and benefit model of local government finance
globalization have highlighted the importance starts with the premise that the main role
of cities. Fiscal decentralization has resulted in for local government is to deliver goods and
the devolution of powers and responsibilities services to local residents. Wherever possible,
from central and state/provincial governments local government services should be paid for
to the local level making local governments on the basis of the benefits received. Where
responsible for a wide range of services and the beneficiaries can be identified and where
infrastructure. Globalization has meant the services are not primarily redistributive
that it is cities that are competing on the in nature, user fees are recommended. Some
international stage. They not only have to services that are financed, at least in part in
provide the services and infrastructure needed some countries, by user fees include water,
to attract businesses and skilled workers but sewers, recreation, and transit. There may,
they have to maintain relatively low taxes on however, be scope for greater use of user fees
businesses so that they do not adversely affect for these and other services. Local governments
their competitive position. In short, cities are need to make citizens understand that user fees
critical to the success of the new economy. are not a tax grab but rather an important way
to gauge the quantity of services that people
A solid financial structure is essential to the want and are willing to pay for.
success of cities in meeting the challenges
of urbanization, decentralization, and
globalization. The financial structure affects the
quantity and quality of services, the efficiency
with which those services are provided,
whether the costs are shared across the city
in a fair and efficient way, and both citizen
access to government and local government
accountability to citizens.
71
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Where services provide benefits of a collective Finally, it is important to remember that “one
nature to the local community, a case can be size does not fit all” when it comes to the
made for property taxes or other local taxes finance of services and infrastructure by local
borne by local residents. Examples include governments. Not all of revenue tools described
local roads, policing, and fire protection. To in this Guide will be appropriate for all local
be truly local taxes, municipalities have to governments under all circumstances. It may
set their own tax rates (although it is often be necessary to treat different municipalities in
administratively easier for senior levels of different ways. For example, experience tells us
government to administer and collect the that large metropolitan areas can and should
taxes on their behalf ). Unless municipalities have greater fiscal autonomy than other urban
are given the freedom to set their own tax or rural areas. Autonomy means both greater
rates, even if it means making mistakes, responsibility for delivering local services and
truly accountable and responsive municipal greater ability to levy their own taxes. All local
government will never be a reality. governments, however, need to be responsible,
accountable, and efficient. To do so, they need
There is also a role for intergovernmental to raise their own revenues as much possible,
transfers in this model of local finance. Where adhere to an open and visible municipal
there are spillovers in the provision of local budgetary process, and engage in transparent
services but where local provision is still and prudent financial management.
desirable, for example, conditional transfers
may be used. Equalization transfers may also
be required to ensure at least a minimum
level of service is provided by those cities
with relatively little fiscal capacity. Where
intergovernmental transfers are used, however,
they should not be designed to discourage
municipalities from charging the right price
for services.
72
References
REFERENCES
73
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Bird, R.M. (2006) “Local and Regional Bird, R.M. and Vaillancourt, F. (1998) “Fiscal
Revenues: Realities and Prospects.” In Bird, Decentralization in Developing Countries: An
R.M. and Vaillancourt, F. (Eds.) Perspectives Overview,” In Bird, R.M. and Vaillancourt, F.
on Fiscal Federalism. Washington, D.C.: The (Eds.) Fiscal Decentralization in Developing
World Bank, pp. 177-196. Countries, Cambridge, England: Cambridge
University Press, pp. 1-48.
Bird, R.M. and Gendron, J.P. (1998) “Dual
VATs and Cross-Border Trade: Two Problems, Bird, R.M. and Wilson, T.A. (2003) “A Tax
One Solution?” International Tax and Public Strategy for Ontario,” Research Paper No.
Finance, 5, pp. 429-42 32 prepared for the Panel on the Role of
Government in Ontario (http://www.law-lib.
Bird, R.M. and Miller, B.D. (1989) “Taxation, utoronto.ca/investing/reports/rp32.pdf ).
Pricing and the Urban Poor,” In Bird, R.M.
and Horton, S. (Eds.) Government Policy and Boadway, R. W. and Kitchen, H.M. (1999)
the Poor in Developing Countries, Toronto: Canadian Tax Policy, third edition, Toronto:
University of Toronto Press, pp. 49-80. Canadian Tax Foundation.
Bird, R.M. and E. Slack (1993) Urban Public Burke, J. (2006) “Ontario’s Municipal
Finance in Canada, second edition, Toronto: Performance Measurement Program: Fostering
John Wiley and Sons. Innovation and Accountability in Local
Government,” Government Finance Review,
Bird, R.M. and Slack, E. (Eds.) (2004) June, pp. 22-7.
International Handbook on Land and Property
Taxation, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Chernick, H. and Tkacheva, O. (2002)
“The Commuter Tax and the Fiscal Cost of
Bird, R.M. and Slack, E. (2007) “Taxing Commuters in New York City,” State Tax
Land and Property in Emerging Economies: Notes, 25 (6), pp. 451-6.
Raising Revenue … and More?” In Ingram,
G.K. and Hong, Y. (Eds.), Land Policies and Cities Alliance (2005) “Financing for Cities and
their Outcomes, Cambridge, Mass.: Lincoln the Urban Poor,” (http://www.citiesalliance.
Institute of Land Policy. org/activities-output/topics/finance/finance.
html).
Bird, R.M. and Slack, E. (2008) “Fiscal Aspects
of Metropolitan Governance.” In Rojas, Dewees, D.N. (2002) “Pricing Municipal
E., Cuadrado-Roura, J.R., and Fernández- Services: The Economics of User Fees,”
Güell, J.M. (Eds.), Governing the Metropolis: Canadian Tax Journal, 50(2), pp. 586-599.
Principles and Cases, Washington, D.C.: Inter-
American Development Bank. Dillinger, W. (1992) Urban Property Tax
Reform Guidelines and Recommendations,
Bird, R.M. and Smart, M. (2002) Washington, D.C.: World Bank
“International Fiscal Transfers: International
Lessons for Developing Countries,” World Dirie, I. (2005) “Municipal Finance: Innovative
Development, 30 (6), pp. 899-912. Resourcing for Municipal Infrastructure and
Service Provision”, report prepared for the
Bird, R.M. and Tsiopoulos, T. (1997) “User Commonwealth Local Government Forum in
Charges for Public Services: Potentials and cooperation with ComHabitat.
Problems,” Canadian Tax Journal, 45 (1), pp.
25-86.
74
References
Ebel, R.D. and Vaillancourt, F. (2001) “Fiscal Keong, C.K. (2002) “Road Pricing: Singapore’s
Decentralization and Financing Urban Experience,” Essay prepared for the third
Governments: Framing the Problem,” In seminar of the IMPRINT-EUROPE Thematic
Freire, M. and Stren, R. (Eds.), The Challenge Network on “Implementing Reform on
of Urban Government: Policies and Practices. Transport Pricing: Constraints and Solutions:
Washington, D.C.: The World Bank Institute, Learning from Best Practices, October.
pp.155-70.
Kitchen, H. (2003) Municipal Revenue
Fischel, W.A. (2001) “Homevoters, Municipal and Expenditure Issues in Canada, Toronto:
Corporate Governance, and the Benefit View Canadian Tax Foundation.
of the Property Tax,” National Tax Journal, 54
(1), pp. 157-73. Kitchen, H. and Slack, E. (1993) Business
Property Taxation, Kingston: Queen’s
Florida, R. (2002) The Rise of the Creative University School of Policy Studies, The
Class, New York, N.Y.: Basic Books. Government and Competitiveness Project.
75
Guide to
Municipal Finance
Montgomery, M. R., Stren, R., Cohen, B. and Serageldin, M., Jones, D., Vigier, F., and
Reed, H.E. (Eds.) (2003) Cities Transformed: Solloso, E. (2008) Municipal Financing and
Demographic Change and its Implications in the Urban Development, Human Settlements
Developing World, Washington, DC: National Global Dialogue Series, No. 3, United
Academy Press. Nations Human Settlements Program (UN-
HABITAT).
Moody’s Investors Services (2005) “Proposal
to Apply Joint Default Analysis to Regional Shah, A. (2007) “A Practitioner’s Guide
and Local Governments,” Special Comment, to Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers,”
December, pp. 1-16. In Boadway, R. and Shah, A. (Eds.),
Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers: Principles
Oates, W. E. (2008) “On the Evolution of and Practice. Washington, D.C.: The World
Fiscal Federalism: Theory and Institutions,” Bank, pp. 1-53.
National Tax Journal, 61(2), pp. 313-334.
Slack, E. (2002) “Municipal Finance and the
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Pattern of Urban Growth,” Commentary 160,
Development (OECD) (2006) Competitive Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute.
Cities in the Global Economy, OECD Territorial
Review, Paris: OECD. Slack, E. (2005a) “Municipal Financing of
Capital Infrastructure in North America,”
O’Meara, M. (2001) “Exploring a New Vision Journal of Property Tax Assessment and
for Cities,” In Freire, M. and Stren, R. (Eds), Administration, 2(1), pp. 63-77.
The Challenge of Urban Government: Policies
and Practices. Washington, D.C.: The World Slack, E. (2005b). “Land Value Capture
Bank Institute, pp. 337-55. Taxes.” In Cordes, J.J., R.D. Ebel and J.G.
Gravelle (Eds.) The Encyclopedia of Taxation
Rezende, F. (1998) “Fiscal Decentralization and Tax Policy, Second Edition. Washington,
and Big Cities Financing in Brazil,” Paper D.C.: The Urban Institute Press, pp. 237-9.
presented at the 54th IIPF Congress, Cordoba,
Argentina, August 2007. Slack, E. (2006a) “Alternative Approaches
to Taxing Land and Real Property,” In Bird,
Rodden, J.A., Eskeland, G.S., and Litvack, R.M. and Vaillancourt, F. (Eds), Perspectives
J. (2003) Fiscal Decentralization and the on Fiscal Federalism. Washington, D.C.: World
Challenges of Hard Budget Constraints, Bank Institute, pp. 197-223.
Cambridge, Mass: The MIT Press.
Slack, E. (2006b) “Fiscal Aspects of Alternative
Schaeffer, M. (2000) “Municipal Budgeting,” Methods of Governing Large Metropolitan
Background Series, 4, Washington, D.C.: Areas,” In Bird, R.M. and Vaillancourt,
World Bank. F. (Eds.), Perspectives on Fiscal Federalism.
Schaeffer, M. (2008). “Access to Fiscal Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, pp. 101-
Information and Audit: Challenges and 22.
Strategies,” In Péteri, G. (Ed.) Finding the Slack, E. (2007a) “Grants to Large Cities and
Money, Public Accountability and Service Metropolitan Areas,” In Boadway, R. and Shah
Efficiency through Fiscal Transparency, Budapest: A. (Eds.), Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers:
Open Society Institute, pp. 144-88. Principles and Practice. Washington, D.C.:
The World Bank, pp. 453-81.
76
References
Stren, R. (2001) “Metropolitan Issues,” In Wong, C. and Bird, R.M. (2008) “China’s
Freire, M. and Stren, R. (Eds), The Challenge Fiscal System: A Work in Progress,” In Brandt,
of Urban Government: Policies and Practices. L. and Rawski, T.G. (Eds.) China’s Great
Washington, D.C.: The World Bank Institute, Economic Transformation, New York, N.Y.:
pp. 1-46. Cambridge University Press, pp. 429-66.
77
Guide to
Municipal Finance
78
appendix
79
Guide to
Municipal Finance
80
Interest in cities is increasing around the world, in part, because of rapid urbanization in
developed and less developed countries but also because of recent trends towards fiscal
decentralization and globalization. These trends have put pressure on cities to provide
a wide range of services (for example, water, sewers, police and fire protection, solid
waste collection and disposal, roads, transit, social services, health, and housing) and to
maintain and expand infrastructure to meet the growing demands of the urban population.
Although local governments in many countries have experienced an increase in powers and
responsibilities in recent years, however, few countries have allowed local governments to
levy the taxes they need to match their expanding local needs.
This Guide to Municipal Finance describes the current issues in municipal finance and the
ways in which local governments finance services and infrastructure. It sets out a basic
economic framework that is used to evaluate the different aspects of municipal finance
and that can be used by readers to evaluate other options. The Guide emphasizes that
responsible, accountable, and efficient local governments need to raise their own revenues
as much possible, adhere to an open and visible municipal budgetary process, and engage
in transparent and prudent financial management.
HS/1146/09E
ISBN: 978-92-1-132113-5
ISBN(Series): 978-1-132027-5