[go: up one dir, main page]

 
 
Sign in to use this feature.

Years

Between: -

Subjects

remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline

Journals

Article Types

Countries / Regions

remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline
remove_circle_outline

Search Results (365)

Search Parameters:
Keywords = carbon trade prices

Order results
Result details
Results per page
Select all
Export citation of selected articles as:
22 pages, 6819 KiB  
Article
Regional Operation of Electricity-Hythane Integrated Energy System Considering Coupled Energy and Carbon Trading
by Dong Yang, Shufan Wang, Wendi Wang, Weiya Zhang, Pengfei Yu and Wei Kong
Processes 2024, 12(10), 2245; https://doi.org/10.3390/pr12102245 - 14 Oct 2024
Viewed by 461
Abstract
The deepening implementation of the energy and carbon market imposes trading requirements on multiple regional integrated energy system participants, including power generation plants, industrial users, and carbon capture, utilization, and storage (CCUS) facilities. Their diverse roles in different markets strengthen the interconnections among [...] Read more.
The deepening implementation of the energy and carbon market imposes trading requirements on multiple regional integrated energy system participants, including power generation plants, industrial users, and carbon capture, utilization, and storage (CCUS) facilities. Their diverse roles in different markets strengthen the interconnections among these subsystems. On the other hand, the operation of CCUS, containing carbon capture (CS), power-to-hydrogen (P2H), and power-to-gas (P2G), results in the coupling of regional carbon reduction costs with the operation of electricity and hythane networks. In this paper, we propose a regional economic dispatching model of an integrated energy system. The markets are organized in a centralized form, and their clearing conditions are considered. CCUS is designed to inject hydrogen or natural gas into hythane networks, operating more flexibly. A generalized Nash game is applied to analyze the multiple trading equilibria of different entities. Simulations are carried out to derive a different market equilibrium regarding network scales, seasonal load shifts, and the ownership of CCUS. Simulation results in a 39-bus/20-node coupled network indicate that the regional average carbon prices fluctuate from ¥1078.82 to ¥1519.03, and the organization of independent CCUS is more preferred under the proposed market structure. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Process Design and Modeling of Low-Carbon Energy Systems)
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>The structure of the regional integrated market of electricity, gas, and carbon allowance.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>The three-bus electrical system and the three-node gas system.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>The price result of test case 1.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>The electricity balance of test case 1 (negative values for electricity consumption).</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>The carbon balance of test case 1 (negative values for carbon allowance).</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>The structure of test case 2.</p>
Full article ">Figure 7
<p>The total demand curves and carbon price results of test case 2.</p>
Full article ">
17 pages, 3128 KiB  
Article
Renewable Energy Credits Transforming Market Dynamics
by Bankole I. Oladapo, Mattew A. Olawumi and Francis T. Omigbodun
Sustainability 2024, 16(19), 8602; https://doi.org/10.3390/su16198602 - 3 Oct 2024
Viewed by 878
Abstract
This research uses advanced statistical methods to examine climate change mitigation policies’ economic and environmental impacts. The primary objective is to assess the effectiveness of carbon pricing, renewable energy subsidies, emission trading schemes, and regulatory standards in reducing CO2 emissions, fostering economic [...] Read more.
This research uses advanced statistical methods to examine climate change mitigation policies’ economic and environmental impacts. The primary objective is to assess the effectiveness of carbon pricing, renewable energy subsidies, emission trading schemes, and regulatory standards in reducing CO2 emissions, fostering economic growth, and promoting employment. A mixed-methods approach was employed, combining regression analysis, cost–benefit analysis (CBA), and computable general equilibrium (CGE) models. Data were collected from national and global databases, and sensitivity analyses were conducted to ensure the robustness of the findings. Key findings revealed a statistically significant reduction in CO2 emissions by 0.45% for each unit increase in carbon pricing (p < 0.01). Renewable energy subsidies were positively correlated with a 3.5% increase in employment in the green sector (p < 0.05). Emission trading schemes were projected to increase GDP by 1.2% over a decade (p < 0.05). However, chi-square tests indicated that carbon pricing disproportionately affects low-income households (p < 0.05), highlighting the need for compensatory policies. The study concluded that a balanced policy mix, tailored to national contexts, can optimise economic and environmental outcomes while addressing social equity concerns. Error margins in GDP projections remained below ±0.3%, confirming the models’ reliability. Full article
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>(<b>a</b>) Distribution of carbon tax revenue in British Columbia. (<b>b</b>) Geographical distribution of climate change mitigation costs and benefits.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>(<b>a</b>) Global greenhouse gas emissions trends. (<b>b</b>) Impact of carbon pricing on carbon emissions in the EU.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>(<b>a</b>) Sectoral GDP impacts of renewable energy subsidies. (<b>b</b>) Cost–benefit analysis of emission trading schemes in various countries.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>(<b>a</b>) Employment changes due to regulatory standards in the energy sector. (<b>b</b>) Comparison of pre- and post-implementation emission levels in the EU.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>(<b>a</b>) Economic growth rates before and after renewable energy subsidies in Germany; (<b>b</b>) projected long-term financial impacts of climate policies using CGE models; (<b>c</b>) effects of carbon pricing on low-income with high-income households; and (<b>d</b>) investment in renewable technologies post-subsidy implementation.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5 Cont.
<p>(<b>a</b>) Economic growth rates before and after renewable energy subsidies in Germany; (<b>b</b>) projected long-term financial impacts of climate policies using CGE models; (<b>c</b>) effects of carbon pricing on low-income with high-income households; and (<b>d</b>) investment in renewable technologies post-subsidy implementation.</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>(<b>a</b>) Trends in energy prices following renewable energy subsidy increases. (<b>b</b>) Comparative analysis of carbon emission reductions across policies. (<b>c</b>) Efficiency of emission trading schemes: cap achievements vs. market predictions. (<b>d</b>) Technological innovation induced by regulatory standards over time.</p>
Full article ">
16 pages, 7324 KiB  
Article
A Sustainable Model for Forecasting Carbon Emission Trading Prices
by Jiaqing Chen, Dongpeng Peng, Zhiwei Liu, Lingzhi Wu and Ming Jiang
Sustainability 2024, 16(19), 8324; https://doi.org/10.3390/su16198324 - 25 Sep 2024
Cited by 1 | Viewed by 831
Abstract
Carbon trading has garnered considerable attention as a pivotal policy instrument for advancing carbon peaking and carbon neutrality, which are essential components of sustainable development. The capacity to precisely anticipate the cost of carbon trading has significant implications for the optimal deployment of [...] Read more.
Carbon trading has garnered considerable attention as a pivotal policy instrument for advancing carbon peaking and carbon neutrality, which are essential components of sustainable development. The capacity to precisely anticipate the cost of carbon trading has significant implications for the optimal deployment of market mechanisms, the economic advancement of technological innovations in corporate emissions reduction, and the facilitation of international energy policy adjustments. To this end, this paper proposes a novel and sustainable trading price prediction tool that employs a four-step process: decomposition, reconstruction, prediction, and integration. This innovative approach first utilizes the Improved Complete Ensemble Empirical Mode Decomposition with Adaptive Noise (ICEEMDAN), then reconstructs the decomposition set using multi-scale entropy (MSE), and finally uses the Long Short-Term Memory neural network model (LSTM) enhanced by the Grey Wolf Optimizer (GWO) to predict the carbon emission trading price. The experimental results demonstrate that the tool achieves high accuracy for both the EU carbon price series and the carbon price series of China’s seven major carbon trading markets, with accuracy rates of 99.10% and 99.60% in Hubei and the EU carbon trading markets, respectively. This represents an improvement of approximately 3.1% over the ICEEMDAN-LSTM model and 0.91% over the ICEEMDAN-MSE-LSTM model, thereby contributing to more sustainable and efficient carbon trading practices. Full article
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>Model framework chart.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>GWO-LSTM model flow chart.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>Status of China’s eight carbon trading markets.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>Decomposition of carbon price series data in China’s carbon market. (note: The red line typically indicates the high-frequency components, while the green line represents the low-frequency components. This differentiation helps in analyzing the signal’s various frequency bands more effectively.)</p>
Full article ">Figure 4 Cont.
<p>Decomposition of carbon price series data in China’s carbon market. (note: The red line typically indicates the high-frequency components, while the green line represents the low-frequency components. This differentiation helps in analyzing the signal’s various frequency bands more effectively.)</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>Comparison of model prediction data with real data.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5 Cont.
<p>Comparison of model prediction data with real data.</p>
Full article ">
21 pages, 1970 KiB  
Article
Integrated Energy System Dispatch Considering Carbon Trading Mechanisms and Refined Demand Response for Electricity, Heat, and Gas
by Lihui Gao, Shuanghao Yang, Nan Chen and Junheng Gao
Energies 2024, 17(18), 4705; https://doi.org/10.3390/en17184705 - 21 Sep 2024
Viewed by 470
Abstract
To realize a carbon-efficient and economically optimized dispatch of the integrated energy system (IES), this paper introduces a highly efficient dispatch strategy that integrates demand response within a tiered carbon trading mechanism. Firstly, an efficient dispatch model making use of CHP and P2G [...] Read more.
To realize a carbon-efficient and economically optimized dispatch of the integrated energy system (IES), this paper introduces a highly efficient dispatch strategy that integrates demand response within a tiered carbon trading mechanism. Firstly, an efficient dispatch model making use of CHP and P2G technologies is developed to strengthen the flexibility of the IES. Secondly, an improved demand response model based on the price elasticity matrix and the capacity for the substitution of energy supply modes is constructed, taking into account three different kinds of loads: heat, gas, and electricity. Subsequently, the implementation of a reward and penalty-based tiered carbon trading mechanism regulates the system’s carbon trading costs and emissions. Ultimately, the goal of the objective function is to minimize the overall costs, encompassing energy purchase, operation and maintenance, carbon trading, and compensation. The original problem is reformulated into a mixed-integer linear programming problem, which is solved using CPLEX. The simulation results from four example scenarios demonstrate that, compared with the conventional carbon trading approach, the aggregate system costs are reduced by 2.44% and carbon emissions are reduced by 3.93% when incorporating the tiered carbon trading mechanism. Subsequent to the adoption of demand response, there is a 2.47% decrease in the total system cost. The proposed scheduling strategy is validated as valuable to ensure the low-carbon and economically efficient functioning of the integrated energy system. Full article
(This article belongs to the Section C: Energy Economics and Policy)
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>Structure of the IES.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>Comprehensive structure of the constraints.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>IES program flow chart.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>The power generated by different load in the IES.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>Prices for energy purchased from the upper grid and gas grid: (<b>a</b>) electricity prices, (<b>b</b>) gas prices.</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>Initial and time-of-use tariffs for three loads: (<b>a</b>) gas prices, (<b>b</b>) heat prices, and (<b>c</b>) electricity prices.</p>
Full article ">Figure 7
<p>Change in load before and after DR in Scenario 4: (<b>a</b>) change in gas load, (<b>b</b>) change in heat load, and (<b>c</b>) change in electric load.</p>
Full article ">Figure 8
<p>Balance of each power under Scenario 4: (<b>a</b>) gas power balance, (<b>b</b>) heat power balance, and (<b>c</b>) electric power balance.</p>
Full article ">Figure 9
<p>Balance of each power under Scenario 3: (<b>a</b>) gas power balance, (<b>b</b>) heat power balance, and (<b>c</b>) electric power balance.</p>
Full article ">
20 pages, 3781 KiB  
Article
Techno-Economic Analysis of Green Hydrogen Production as Maritime Fuel from Wave Energy
by Zimasa Macingwane and Alessandro Schönborn
Energies 2024, 17(18), 4683; https://doi.org/10.3390/en17184683 - 20 Sep 2024
Viewed by 963
Abstract
The study examined the potential changing roles of ports in terms of diversifying their revenue through the expansion of new markets in the Port of Ngqura. This is by means of the production and sales of renewable hydrogen as marine fuel produced from [...] Read more.
The study examined the potential changing roles of ports in terms of diversifying their revenue through the expansion of new markets in the Port of Ngqura. This is by means of the production and sales of renewable hydrogen as marine fuel produced from a wavefarm in Nelson Mandela Bay. A key objective of the study was to conduct a comprehensive techno-economic analysis of the feasible hydrogen production technologies based on the analysis performed, including alkaline electrolysis of seawater and renewable-powered electrolysis of seawater. The produced hydrogen aligns with global decarbonisation of ships and ports and will be used to supply the port with electricity, serve to refuel tugboats, and provide green hydrogen bunkering fuel for commercial shipping vessels. The Port of Ngqura is geographically well positioned to lead the production of zero carbon shipping fuel. This work considers the CAPEX and OPEX of a hydrogen plant using electrolysers and evaluates the current cost of production and selling price of hydrogen. The primary aim of this study was to examine the feasibility of hydrogen production through electrolysis of seawater at the Port of Ngqura. Through assessing resource and technological options, determining advantageous economic assumptions, and identifying existing limitations and potential opportunities, a feasibility study was conducted with special consideration of the site characteristics of Ngqura. The output of this study is a model that simulates the production, storage, and transportation of hydrogen gas from the Port of Ngqura, which was further used to analyse different case study scenarios. This approach directly addresses the main goal of the study. The results found showed that with wave energy convertors in a row of three next to each other, the energy produced by the wave farm was 2.973 TJ per month, which is equivalent to 18.58 tons of produced hydrogen when considering the lower heating value of hydrogen and assuming that hydrogen production efficiency is 75%. The anticipated hydrogen fuel will be able to refuel a tugboat with green hydrogen from the energy produced by the wave farm each month. It is predicted that the price of hydrogen is expected to drop, and the price of fossil fuel will gradually increase in the coming years. The fact that coal electricity can be produced on demand and wind and solar energy are weather dependent as a result lacks the ability to achieve a constant supply. There is currently an urgent need for energy storage and the efforts to study the production of hydrogen and ammonia. Hydrogen is still predicted to be more expensive than coal electricity; however, from this, maybe a critical cost for a kg of CO2 could be calculated, which could make hydrogen competitive. The cost of green hydrogen production from wave energy in the Port of Ngqura was calculated as R96.07/kg (4.88 EUR/kg) of produced hydrogen, which is equivalent to 2.1 times the cost of the same energy supplied as Marine Diesel Oil (MDO) at current prices. Hydrogen from wave energy would thus become competitive with MDO; if a price is set for the emission of CO2, this may also offset the difference in cost between MDO and hydrogen from wave energy. The carbon price necessary to make green hydrogen competitive would be approximately R6257/tonne CO2, or 318 EUR/tonne CO2, which is around 4.5 times the current trading price of carbon in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme. Full article
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>Definitions in the computational domain of the wave energy converter.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>Predicted price of hydrogen between 2010 and 2050 (R19.70 = 1 EUR, 22 May 2024) [<a href="#B29-energies-17-04683" class="html-bibr">29</a>,<a href="#B31-energies-17-04683" class="html-bibr">31</a>,<a href="#B32-energies-17-04683" class="html-bibr">32</a>,<a href="#B33-energies-17-04683" class="html-bibr">33</a>,<a href="#B34-energies-17-04683" class="html-bibr">34</a>].</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>Location of the Wave Farm in Nelson Mandela Bay Municipality with the average wave height in (m).</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>The percentage change in wave weight for Stratigaki et al., 2014 [<a href="#B24-energies-17-04683" class="html-bibr">24</a>], and this study.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>Location of the wave farm and wave height in Nelson Mandela Bay in August 2020 at the Port of Ngqurha (indicated as red dot).</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>Average wave height sample over one month (August 2020).</p>
Full article ">Figure 7
<p>The monthly power produced from Jan 2019–August 2021 using one energy wave convertor.</p>
Full article ">Figure 8
<p>The electric power produced by individual WECs in a row of 3 WECs.</p>
Full article ">Figure 9
<p>The power produced by individual WECs in a row of 9 WECs.</p>
Full article ">Figure 10
<p>The average power of the 3 types of WECs rows.</p>
Full article ">Figure 11
<p>The average power produced by the wave energy convertors, depending on their position in the wave-farm array.</p>
Full article ">
24 pages, 6932 KiB  
Article
Evolutionary Game Analysis of Collaborative Prefabricated Buildings Development Behavior in China under Carbon Emissions Trading Schemes
by Wenbin Cao and Yiming Sun
Sustainability 2024, 16(18), 8084; https://doi.org/10.3390/su16188084 - 16 Sep 2024
Viewed by 748
Abstract
Prefabricated buildings (PBs) are considered a green way to reduce energy consumption and carbon emissions in the construction industry due to their environmental and social benefits. However, PBs have obstacles such as high construction costs, immature technology, and insufficient policy incentives, and developers’ [...] Read more.
Prefabricated buildings (PBs) are considered a green way to reduce energy consumption and carbon emissions in the construction industry due to their environmental and social benefits. However, PBs have obstacles such as high construction costs, immature technology, and insufficient policy incentives, and developers’ willingness to develop them needs to be higher. Therefore, it is necessary to explore how to motivate more developers to develop PBs. In this paper, we first discuss the impact of the carbon emissions trading scheme (ETS) on the construction industry and then consider the heterogeneity of construction developers, introduce a collaborative mechanism to establish a three-party evolutionary game model between the government and the heterogeneous developers, and explore the evolution of the three-party dynamic strategies through numerical simulation. The results show that developers’ initial development probability affects the system’s evolutionary trend, and the developer who obtains more low-carbon benefits plays a dominant role. Further analyses show that critical factors such as market profitability, synergistic benefits, and carbon tax price positively influence the development of PBs, and the influence of synergistic cooperation mechanisms should be especially emphasized. This study provides practical insights into the sustainable development of the construction industry and the government’s development of a suitable carbon portfolio policy for it. Including the construction industry in the ETS is recommended when carbon prices reach 110 RMB/t. At this point, the government can remove the subsidy for PBs, but the behaviors of the developers who participate in the ETS still need to be supervised. Full article
(This article belongs to the Section Green Building)
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>The interactions between heterogeneous developers under an ETS.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>The evolution process of the system in the initial stage.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>The evolution process of the system in the transition stage.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>The evolution process of the system in the growth stage.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>The evolution process of the system in the stabilization stage.</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>Evolutionary convergence before and after the introduction of the ETS.</p>
Full article ">Figure 7
<p>Effect of B on tripartite evolutionary processes.</p>
Full article ">Figure 8
<p>Effect of V on tripartite evolutionary processes.</p>
Full article ">Figure 9
<p>Effect of P on tripartite evolutionary processes.</p>
Full article ">Figure 10
<p>Effect of S on tripartite evolutionary processes.</p>
Full article ">Figure 11
<p>Effect of g on tripartite evolutionary processes.</p>
Full article ">Figure 12
<p>Effect of D<sub>i</sub> on tripartite evolutionary processes.</p>
Full article ">
19 pages, 1367 KiB  
Article
Blockchain-Assisted Secure Energy Trading in Electricity Markets: A Tiny Deep Reinforcement Learning-Based Stackelberg Game Approach
by Yong Xiao, Xiaoming Lin, Yiyong Lei, Yanzhang Gu, Jianlin Tang, Fan Zhang and Bin Qian
Electronics 2024, 13(18), 3647; https://doi.org/10.3390/electronics13183647 - 13 Sep 2024
Viewed by 810
Abstract
Electricity markets are intricate systems that facilitate efficient energy exchange within interconnected grids. With the rise of low-carbon transportation driven by environmental policies and tech advancements, energy trading has become crucial. This trend towards Electric Vehicles (EVs) is bolstered by the pivotal role [...] Read more.
Electricity markets are intricate systems that facilitate efficient energy exchange within interconnected grids. With the rise of low-carbon transportation driven by environmental policies and tech advancements, energy trading has become crucial. This trend towards Electric Vehicles (EVs) is bolstered by the pivotal role played by EV charging operators in providing essential charging infrastructure and services for widespread EV adoption. This paper introduces a blockchain-assisted secure electricity trading framework between EV charging operators and the electricity market with renewable energy sources. We propose a single-leader, multi-follower Stackelberg game between the electricity market and EV charging operators. In the two-stage Stackelberg game, the electricity market acts as the leader, deciding the price of electric energy. The EV charging aggregator leverages blockchain technology to record and verify energy trading transactions securely. The EV charging operators, acting as followers, then decide their demand for electric energy based on the set price. To find the Stackelberg equilibrium, we employ a Deep Reinforcement Learning (DRL) algorithm that tackles non-stationary challenges through policy, action space, and reward function formulation. To optimize efficiency, we propose the integration of pruning techniques into DRL, referred to as Tiny DRL. Numerical results demonstrate that our proposed schemes outperform traditional approaches. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Network Security Management in Heterogeneous Networks)
Show Figures

Graphical abstract

Graphical abstract
Full article ">Figure 1
<p>A blockchain-assisted secure electricity trading framework between EV charging operators and the electricity market.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>Performance comparison between the proposed Tiny PPO algorithm and the PPO algorithm.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>Utilities and strategies of the electricity market and EVs under different costs, with <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <mi>M</mi> <mo>=</mo> <mn>5</mn> </mrow> </semantics></math> corresponding to the number of EV charging operators and a unit profit of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <mi>α</mi> <mo>=</mo> <mn>50</mn> </mrow> </semantics></math>.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>Utilities and strategies of the electricity market and EV charging operators under different numbers of EV charging operators with cost of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <mi>C</mi> <mo>=</mo> <mn>5</mn> </mrow> </semantics></math> and unit profit of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <mi>α</mi> <mo>=</mo> <mn>50</mn> </mrow> </semantics></math>.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>Utilities and strategies of the electricity market and EV charging operators under different unit profits (<math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>α</mi> </semantics></math>), with <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <mi>M</mi> <mo>=</mo> <mn>5</mn> </mrow> </semantics></math> corresponding to the number of EV charging operators and cost of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <mi>C</mi> <mo>=</mo> <mn>5</mn> </mrow> </semantics></math>.</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>Security probability under different numbers of miners.</p>
Full article ">
24 pages, 2567 KiB  
Article
Research on Carbon Cap Regulation, Retailer Altruistic Preferences, and Green Decision-Making of Manufacturing Enterprises
by Xiaoxuan Sun and Guangcheng Ma
Sustainability 2024, 16(17), 7575; https://doi.org/10.3390/su16177575 - 1 Sep 2024
Viewed by 571
Abstract
As manufacturing advances swiftly and public consciousness about low-carbon practices rises, eco-friendly supply chains have seen significant expansion. This study investigates a government-driven green supply chain in two phases, involving a producer and a seller. Four scenario game models are established to determine [...] Read more.
As manufacturing advances swiftly and public consciousness about low-carbon practices rises, eco-friendly supply chains have seen significant expansion. This study investigates a government-driven green supply chain in two phases, involving a producer and a seller. Four scenario game models are established to determine whether the manufacturer engages in green technology innovation or whether the retailer has altruistic preferences. The Stackelberg game was used to analyze changes in government carbon quota regulations, retail prices of retailers, and manufacturers’ carbon reduction efforts in the context of carbon market trading. Research shows that the government will set looser carbon emission limits for manufacturers when retailers have no altruistic preferences. When carbon prices in the market are low, encouraging manufacturers to invest in green technology innovation enhances social welfare. This study offers essential theoretical backing for the government in crafting carbon quota regulations and aids businesses in making prompt technological innovation choices. Full article
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>Model Structure.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>Impact of Carbon Prices on Social Welfare.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>Impact of Product Carbon Emissions on Carbon Cap.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>The impact of carbon prices on carbon emission limits.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>The impact of product carbon emissions and carbon prices on carbon emission limits.</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>The Impact of Altruistic Preference on Carbon Emission Cap.</p>
Full article ">Figure 7
<p>The Impact of Carbon Price on Production.</p>
Full article ">Figure 8
<p>The Impact of Carbon Prices on Product Prices.</p>
Full article ">Figure 9
<p>The Impact of Carbon Prices on Retailer Profits.</p>
Full article ">Figure 10
<p>The Impact of Carbon Prices on Manufacturers’ Profits.</p>
Full article ">
21 pages, 1807 KiB  
Article
Research on the Inhibitory Effect of the EU’s Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism on Carbon Leakage
by Tian Lan and Ran Tao
Sustainability 2024, 16(17), 7429; https://doi.org/10.3390/su16177429 - 28 Aug 2024
Viewed by 789
Abstract
Associated with more ambitious targets for reducing emissions, the European Union (EU) plans to implement the Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM) fully in 2026, aiming to reduce carbon leakage and competitiveness concerns by imposing tariffs on carbon-intensive imports, which is expected to significantly [...] Read more.
Associated with more ambitious targets for reducing emissions, the European Union (EU) plans to implement the Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM) fully in 2026, aiming to reduce carbon leakage and competitiveness concerns by imposing tariffs on carbon-intensive imports, which is expected to significantly impact its trade partners. Existing research has focused on CBAM’s impact on macroeconomic indicators but has insufficiently addressed its effects on global and regional carbon leakage, especially in non-EU countries like China. This research offers a detailed analysis of industry-specific leakage rates and integrates both global and regional impacts by employing the dynamic recursive GTAP-E general equilibrium model to numerically simulate CBAM’s inhibitory effect on carbon leakage under different carbon tariff scenarios, while also exploring the synergistic effects of anti-leakage policies in non-EU countries. Our simulations indicate the following: (1) CBAM effectively inhibits carbon leakage, with greater inhibition observed at higher tax rates and with the expansion of covered industries. (2) Establishing China’s domestic carbon market pricing can further reduce regional carbon leakage rates. Implementing global export carbon tax policies will significantly diminish the risk of global carbon leakage. (3) The implementation of CBAM is projected to reduce China’s total exports to the EU, though this loss will be partly offset by trade diversion effects. Carbon-intensive industries are more adversely affected in the short term, while all industries except fossil fuels face inevitable long-term negative impacts. Full article
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>China’s foreign exports 2014–2023 (USD Trillion).</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>Carbon leakage rate results of different NDC aggregations under different scenarios.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>Carbon leakage rate results of China and trading partners under different scenarios.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>Industry leakage rate results when USD 35 Mt/CO<sub>2</sub> tax rate is imposed under different scenarios.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>Results of GDP change by region under CBAM Phase I with USD 55 Mt/CO<sub>2</sub> tax rate.</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>Range of carbon leakage rates with different Armington elasticities.</p>
Full article ">Figure A1
<p>Production structure of the GTAP-E model with embedded capital-energy composite factors. Source: Burniaux and Truong [<a href="#B47-sustainability-16-07429" class="html-bibr">47</a>].</p>
Full article ">Figure A2
<p>Consumption structure of the GTAP-E model. Source: Burniaux and Truong [<a href="#B47-sustainability-16-07429" class="html-bibr">47</a>].</p>
Full article ">
20 pages, 11667 KiB  
Article
Economic Scheduling Strategy for Multi-Energy-Integrated Highway Service Centers Considering Carbon Trading and Critical Peak Pricing Mechanism
by Xiaoxue Ge, Zhijie Liu, Kejun Li, Chenxian Guo, Gang Shen and Zichen Wang
Symmetry 2024, 16(9), 1110; https://doi.org/10.3390/sym16091110 - 26 Aug 2024
Viewed by 499
Abstract
This study proposes an optimized economic scheduling strategy for multi-energy-integrated highway service centers (MEIHSCs) within a 24 h operational timeframe. With the imperative of carbon peaking and carbon neutrality, highway areas are increasingly incorporating renewable energy systems, such as photovoltaic arrays, to capitalize [...] Read more.
This study proposes an optimized economic scheduling strategy for multi-energy-integrated highway service centers (MEIHSCs) within a 24 h operational timeframe. With the imperative of carbon peaking and carbon neutrality, highway areas are increasingly incorporating renewable energy systems, such as photovoltaic arrays, to capitalize on abundant resources along highways. Considering the diverse load demands of new energy vehicles and the mismatch between energy supply and demand on the highway, MEIHSCs must adapt to these trends by establishing integrated networks for electricity, natural gas, and hydrogen refueling. However, there is a lack of coordination between equipment switching and the phases of low electricity prices and peak renewable energy periods. To address this challenge and improve economic efficiency, this study proposes an economic dispatch strategy that combines economic incentives based on carbon trading and critical peak pricing mechanisms. This strategy aims to maximize economic benefits while fully meeting the load demands of new energy vehicles. Case studies indicate that operating costs are reduced by 28.04% compared to strategies without new energy installations, and by 47.85% compared to strategies without optimization. The results demonstrate that this integrated and optimized strategy significantly reduces energy costs and enhances economic benefits in highway service centers. Full article
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>Aerial view of an MEIHSC.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>The framework of an MEIHSC.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>The carbon emission accounting boundary of Chinese highway service areas.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>Stepped carbon trading mechanism.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>Switching sequence of no optimal scheduling scheme.</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>Output distribution chart of Case II.</p>
Full article ">Figure 7
<p>Switching sequence diagram of optimal scheduling scheme considering critical peak pricing mechanism.</p>
Full article ">Figure 8
<p>Energy storage change chart of optimal scheduling scheme considering critical peak pricing mechanism.</p>
Full article ">Figure 9
<p>Output distribution chart of Case III.</p>
Full article ">Figure 10
<p>Switching sequence diagram of optimal scheduling scheme considering carbon trading and critical peak pricing mechanism.</p>
Full article ">Figure 11
<p>Energy storage change chart of optimal scheduling scheme considering carbon trading and critical peak pricing mechanism.</p>
Full article ">Figure 12
<p>Output distribution chart of Case IV.</p>
Full article ">
23 pages, 6239 KiB  
Article
Complexity Analysis of the Interaction between Government Carbon Quota Mechanism and Manufacturers’ Emission Reduction Strategies under Carbon Cap-and-Trade Mechanism
by Abudureheman Kadeer, Jinghan Yang and Shiyi Zhao
Sustainability 2024, 16(16), 7115; https://doi.org/10.3390/su16167115 - 19 Aug 2024
Viewed by 584
Abstract
Based on different carbon quota trading mechanisms, the price and emission reduction strategies of oligopoly manufacturers in the low-carbon market and the government carbon quota mechanism are considered. A dynamic game evolution model of the two oligopoly manufacturers with competitive relations is established. [...] Read more.
Based on different carbon quota trading mechanisms, the price and emission reduction strategies of oligopoly manufacturers in the low-carbon market and the government carbon quota mechanism are considered. A dynamic game evolution model of the two oligopoly manufacturers with competitive relations is established. The stability of the equilibrium point of the game model, the price adjustment speed of the decision variable, the impact of carbon emission reduction investment, and the government carbon quota on the system are discussed. Through nonlinear dynamics research, it is found that the advantage of the grandfathering method is that it is conducive to maintaining market stability when the government’s carbon quota decision changes; the advantage of the benchmarking method is that when manufacturers formulate price adjustment strategies, the benchmarking method carbon quota mechanism has a stronger stability range for the market, the manufacturer’s profit price adjustment speed is positively correlated, and the government carbon quota decision and emission reduction investment are also positively correlated. Decision makers need to choose appropriate carbon quota mechanisms and manufacturers’ emission reduction strategies according to actual market changes to maintain supply chain stability. Full article
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>Consider government carbon quotas and supply chain systems for producing homogeneous products.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>Three-dimensional stability domain: (<b>a</b>) The stability domain of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>1</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math>, <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>2</mn> </msub> <mo> </mo> </mrow> </semantics></math> and <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>3</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> in the grandfathering method. (<b>b</b>) The stability domain of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>1</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math>, <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>2</mn> </msub> <mo> </mo> </mrow> </semantics></math> and <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>3</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> in the benchmarking method.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>(<b>a</b>) The impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>1</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> dynamic adjustment parameters on system stability changes in grandfathering on the system. (<b>b</b>) The impact of g1 changes in benchmarking on the system.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>The dynamic evolution phenomenon of chaotic attractors in dynamic equations: (<b>a</b>) Front view of the grandfathering attractor. (<b>b</b>) Top view of the grandfathering attractor. (<b>c</b>) Benchmarking attractor front view. (<b>d</b>) Top view of the attractor of the benchmarking method.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>(<b>a</b>) The impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>5</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> (carbon limit decision variable adjustment parameters) changes in grandfathering on the system. (<b>b</b>) Impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>5</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> (carbon limit decision variable adjustment parameters) changes in the benchmarking method on the system.</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>(<b>a</b>) Effect of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>5</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> (carbon limit decision variable adjustment parameters) changes on the stability domain in the grandfathering method. (<b>b</b>) Effect of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>5</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> (carbon limit decision variable adjustment parameters) changes on the stability domain in the benchmarking method.</p>
Full article ">Figure 7
<p>(<b>a</b>) The impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>1</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> changes in grandfathering on demand; (<b>b</b>) the impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>g</mi> <mn>1</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> changes in benchmarking on demand.</p>
Full article ">Figure 8
<p>The impact of price adjustment speed on profits: (<b>a</b>) Manufacturers’ separate profits under the grandfathering method. (<b>b</b>) Profits of manufacturers in the benchmarking method. (<b>c</b>) Total profits of the oligopoly manufacturers under the grandfathering method. (<b>d</b>) Total profits of oligopolistic manufacturers in the benchmarking method.</p>
Full article ">Figure 9
<p>(<b>a</b>) The impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>β</mi> </semantics></math> (oligopoly competition coefficient) changes in the grandfathering method on the system; (<b>b</b>) the impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>β</mi> </semantics></math> (oligopoly competition coefficient) changes in the benchmarking method on the system.</p>
Full article ">Figure 10
<p>(<b>a</b>) The impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>β</mi> </semantics></math> (oligopoly competition coefficient) changes in the grandfathering method on profits. (<b>b</b>) The impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>β</mi> </semantics></math> (oligopoly competition coefficient) changes in the benchmarking method on profits.</p>
Full article ">Figure 11
<p>(<b>a</b>) Impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>μ</mi> <mn>1</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> in the grandfathering method changes on the system. (<b>b</b>) Impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>μ</mi> <mn>1</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> in the benchmarking method changes on the system.</p>
Full article ">Figure 12
<p>(<b>a</b>) Impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>μ</mi> <mn>2</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> in the grandfathering method changes on the system. (<b>b</b>) Impact of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mrow> <msub> <mi>μ</mi> <mn>2</mn> </msub> </mrow> </semantics></math> in the benchmarking method changes on the system.</p>
Full article ">Figure 13
<p>Conclusions and recommendations and their connections.</p>
Full article ">
32 pages, 1896 KiB  
Article
Considering Blockchain Technology and Fairness Concerns for Supply Chain Pricing Decisions under Carbon Cap-and-Trade Mechanism
by Yande Gong, Xinze Jiang, Zhe Wang and Jizhou Zhan
Mathematics 2024, 12(16), 2550; https://doi.org/10.3390/math12162550 - 18 Aug 2024
Viewed by 487
Abstract
To address the growing demand for green development, governments worldwide have introduced policies to promote a green economy. Among these policies, the carbon cap-and-trade mechanism is adopted as an effective approach to control carbon emissions. Additionally, blockchain may increase transparency in the industrial [...] Read more.
To address the growing demand for green development, governments worldwide have introduced policies to promote a green economy. Among these policies, the carbon cap-and-trade mechanism is adopted as an effective approach to control carbon emissions. Additionally, blockchain may increase transparency in the industrial process. Despite focusing on improving its own green standards, the supply chain needs to establish stable cooperative relationship. Thus, we focus on a supply chain consisting of a dominant manufacturer and a retailer, where the manufacturer opts for implementing blockchain and the retailer selects their stance on fairness. We construct a Stackelberg game model and use backward induction to obtain the equilibrium solutions. In the supply chain, the highest profits can be achieved when the manufacturer adopts blockchain technology, provided that the cost of application is relatively low. For manufacturer and retailer, when the cost of applying blockchain is relatively low, they can both obtain maximized profits without applying blockchain and the retailer does not have fairness concerns. However, as the cost of inducing blockchain and the product’s reduction in carbon emission increase, the optimal strategies for manufacturer and retailer begin to diverge, which may affect the stability of the supply chain. Full article
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>Changes in optimal decisions with b. (<b>a</b>) Changes in product’s carbon emission reduction with b (<math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>k</mi> </semantics></math> = 2.5). (<b>b</b>) Changes in the demand quantity of low-carbon products with b (<math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>k</mi> </semantics></math> = 2.5).</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>Effects of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>λ</mi> </semantics></math> and <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>k</mi> </semantics></math> on the supply chain’s profit (<math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>k</mi> </semantics></math> = 2.5).</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>Effects of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>λ</mi> </semantics></math> and <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>k</mi> </semantics></math> on the decision profit (<math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>k</mi> </semantics></math> = 2.5): (<b>a</b>) Effects of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>λ</mi> </semantics></math> and <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>k</mi> </semantics></math> on the manufacturer’s profit. (<b>b</b>) Effects of <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>λ</mi> </semantics></math> and <math display="inline"><semantics> <mi>k</mi> </semantics></math> on the retailer’s profit.</p>
Full article ">
29 pages, 2065 KiB  
Article
Battery Mode Selection and Carbon Emission Decisions of Competitive Electric Vehicle Manufacturers
by Zhihua Han, Yinyuan Si, Xingye Wang and Shuai Yang
Mathematics 2024, 12(16), 2472; https://doi.org/10.3390/math12162472 - 10 Aug 2024
Viewed by 570
Abstract
Competition in China’s electric vehicle industry has intensified significantly in recent years. The production mode of power batteries, serving as the pivotal component in these vehicles, has emerged as a critical challenge for electric vehicle manufacturers. We considered a system comprising an electric [...] Read more.
Competition in China’s electric vehicle industry has intensified significantly in recent years. The production mode of power batteries, serving as the pivotal component in these vehicles, has emerged as a critical challenge for electric vehicle manufacturers. We considered a system comprising an electric vehicle (EV) manufacturer with power battery production technology and another EV manufacturer lacking power battery production technology. In the context of carbon trading policy, we constructed and solved Cournot competitive game models and asymmetric Nash negotiation game models in the CC, PC, and WC modes. We examined the decision-making process of electric vehicle manufacturers regarding power battery production modes and carbon emission reduction strategies. Our research indicates the following: (1) The reasonable patent fee for power batteries and the wholesale price of power batteries can not only compensate power battery production technology manufacturers for the losses caused by market competition but can also strengthen the cooperative relationship between manufacturers. (2) EV manufacturers equipped with power battery production technology exhibit higher profitability within the framework of a perfectly competitive power battery production mode. Conversely, manufacturers lacking power cell production technology demonstrate greater profitability when operating under a more collaborative power cell production mode. (3) Refraining from blindly persisting with and advocating for carbon emission reduction measures is advisable for manufacturers amidst rising carbon trading prices. Full article
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>Structure diagram of the supply chain modes.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>The influence of carbon trading prices on the pricing of vehicles manufactured. (<b>a</b>) Manufacturer 1. (<b>b</b>) Manufacturer 2.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>The impact of the extent of vehicle substitution on the manufacturer’s profitability. (<b>a</b>) Mode CC. (<b>b</b>) Mode PC. (<b>c</b>) Mode WC.</p>
Full article ">
41 pages, 448 KiB  
Article
Sustainable Inventory Managements for Non-Instantaneous Deteriorating Items: Preservation Technology and Green Technology Approaches with Advanced Purchase Discounts and Joint Emission Regulations
by Shun-Po Chiu, Jui-Jung Liao, Sung-Lien Kang, Hari Mohan Srivastava and Shy-Der Lin
Sustainability 2024, 16(16), 6805; https://doi.org/10.3390/su16166805 - 8 Aug 2024
Viewed by 661
Abstract
The present article aims to determine the green economic policies of an inventory model for non-instantaneous deteriorating items under practical scenarios. These scenarios involve specific maximum lifetimes for items with deteriorations controllable through investments in preservation technologies, which can affect the period without [...] Read more.
The present article aims to determine the green economic policies of an inventory model for non-instantaneous deteriorating items under practical scenarios. These scenarios involve specific maximum lifetimes for items with deteriorations controllable through investments in preservation technologies, which can affect the period without deterioration. Additionally, carbon is emitted due to energy-related costs, prompting retailers to invest in green technology investments to reduce carbon emissions concurrently under the carbon tax policy and the carbon cap-and-trade policy simultaneously. Meanwhile, when a retailer is required to make a prepayment, the purchase discount policy is contingent on the number of installments offered. This means that the retailer prepays off the entire purchasing cost with a single installment, thereby receiving a maximum percentage of price discount. Otherwise, the retailer prepays a certain fraction of the purchasing cost with multiple installments, and the percentage of the price discount will be contingent on the number of n identical installments. In this context, we present theoretical results for optimal solutions, and a salient algorithm is presented, which is derived from these theoretical findings within a sustainable inventory system. To better illustrate the proposed mathematical problems, several numerical examples are presented, followed by sensitivity analysis for different scenarios. Full article
14 pages, 1862 KiB  
Article
A Low-Carbon Collaborative Optimization Operation Method for a Two-Layer Dynamic Community Integrated Energy System
by Qiancheng Wang, Haibo Pen, Xiaolong Chen, Bin Li and Peng Zhang
Appl. Sci. 2024, 14(15), 6811; https://doi.org/10.3390/app14156811 - 4 Aug 2024
Viewed by 897
Abstract
The traditional centralized optimization method encounters challenges in representing the interaction among multi-agents and cannot consider the interests of each agent. In traditional low-carbon scheduling, the fixed carbon quota trading price can easily cause arbitrage behavior of the trading subject, and the carbon [...] Read more.
The traditional centralized optimization method encounters challenges in representing the interaction among multi-agents and cannot consider the interests of each agent. In traditional low-carbon scheduling, the fixed carbon quota trading price can easily cause arbitrage behavior of the trading subject, and the carbon reduction effect is poor. This paper proposes a two-layer dynamic community integrated energy system (CIES) low-carbon collaborative optimization operation method. Firstly, a multi-agent stage feedback carbon trading model is proposed, which calculates carbon trading costs in stages and introduces feedback factors to reduce carbon emissions indirectly. Secondly, a two-layer CIES low-carbon optimal scheduling model is constructed. The upper energy seller (ES) sets energy prices. The lower layer is the combined cooling, heating, and power (CCHP) system and load aggregator (LA), which is responsible for energy output and consumption. The energy supply and consumption are determined according to the ES energy price strategy, which reversely affects the energy quotation. Then, the non-dominated sorting genetic algorithm embedded with quadratic programming is utilized to solve the established scheduling model, which reduces the difficulty and improves the solving efficiency. Finally, the simulation results under the actual CIES example show that compared with the traditional centralized scheduling method, the total carbon emission of the proposed method is reduced by 16.34%, which can improve the income of each subject and make the energy supply lower carbon economy. Full article
(This article belongs to the Section Electrical, Electronics and Communications Engineering)
Show Figures

Figure 1

Figure 1
<p>Bi-level optimal scheduling architecture of the community integrated energy system.</p>
Full article ">Figure 2
<p>Multi-energy flow equipment coupling system.</p>
Full article ">Figure 3
<p>The proposed low-carbon optimal scheduling process of the two-layer dynamic CIES.</p>
Full article ">Figure 4
<p>ES optimal scheduling results. (<b>a</b>) Electricity price curve at each moment. (<b>b</b>) Heat price curve at each moment.</p>
Full article ">Figure 5
<p>Load aggregator optimization scheduling results. (<b>a</b>) Power load curve before and after the demand response. (<b>b</b>) Heat load curve before and after the demand response.</p>
Full article ">Figure 6
<p>Optimization scheduling results of new energy CCHP system. (<b>a</b>) Power equipment optimization scheduling results. (<b>b</b>) Heat equipment optimization scheduling results.</p>
Full article ">
Back to TopTop