[go: up one dir, main page]

Academia.eduAcademia.edu
Defence and Peace Economics ISSN: 1024-2694 (Print) 1476-8267 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/gdpe20 An analysis of the public–private wage differential in the Palestinian labour market Sami H. Miaari To cite this article: Sami H. Miaari (2018): An analysis of the public–private wage differential in the Palestinian labour market, Defence and Peace Economics, DOI: 10.1080/10242694.2018.1473137 To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2018.1473137 Published online: 09 May 2018. Submit your article to this journal View related articles View Crossmark data Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=gdpe20 Defence anD Peace economics, 2018 https://doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2018.1473137 An analysis of the public–private wage differential in the Palestinian labour market Sami H. Miaari Department of Labor studies, Tel-aviv University, Tel-aviv, israel ABSTRACT ARTICLE HISTORY This paper measures and analyzes the dynamics of the public–private wage differential in the West Bank and Gaza for the period before and during the ‘second Intifada’ using data from the Palestinian Labour Force Survey (PLFS) of the Palestinian Central Bureau of Statistics (PCBS). Because the distribution of workers’ individual characteristics, such as skills, and the ‘returns’ to these characteristics may differ across workers, the wage differential is decomposed into two components: an ‘endowment’ effect and a ‘returns’ effect. The results show that in the pre-Intifada period, the wage gap between the public and private sectors narrowed in both the West Bank and Gaza. However, a sharp increase is seen after the outbreak of the Intifada. Moreover, most of this increase comes from an increase in ‘returns’ to skills composition in the public sector, (unexplained effect), rather than a change in the skills composition of public sector workers, (explained effect). Using recent econometric quantile regression techniques, the analysis of the public–private sector wage gap from 1998 to 2006, at various points along the wage distribution, shows that the wage premium, (penalty), for the public sector varies across the distribution, being higher, (lower), at the lowest end of the wage distribution and decreasing (increasing) along the wage distribution; it becomes negative in the top percentiles. Received 28 December 2017 accepted 3 may 2018 KEYWORDS conflict; decomposition; intifada; Palestine; public sector; quantile; wage gap JEL CLASSIFICATION J21; J31; J61; J45; c14; c24 Introduction Public sector salaries have attracted much attention in the West Bank and Gaza in recent years. Salaries are by far the largest component of the Palestinian Authority’s (PA’s) budget, accounting for 62% of total expenditure in 2005. Labour market data from the last quarter of 2006 suggest that public sector employment accounts for nearly 25% of all full-time employment. As the largest employer in Palestine, the PA has both political and economic influence on Palestinian labour markets. Historically, in the West Bank and Gaza, as in other developing countries, the processes of recruitment, promotion and wage determination have differed substantially between the public and private sectors. Following the second Intifada, the Palestinian public sector was perceived as a ‘buffer’ to absorb the private sector job losses resulting from the impact, on product and labour markets, of increased closures and movement restrictions imposed by Israel. (Cali and Miaari, 2018; Miaari and Sauer 2011). Latterly, there were also increases in public sector salaries, such that in 2005 the wage bill averaged $US 85 m per month.1 Given that the net revenues of the PA were approximately $US 101 m per month in 2005 (Figure 1), CONTACT sami H. miaari samimiaari@post.tau.ac.il © 2018 informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & francis Group 2 S. H. MIAARI Figure 1. net Revenue and Wage Bill, 1998–2005. source: international monetary fund data files. the commitment to public sector salaries and employment crowded out other forms of expenditure, including spending on the maintenance and development of critically important infrastructure. This situation has created a serious dilemma for a Palestinian Government faced with the unenviable task of cutting expenditure at a time when the economy has been stagnating as a result of the closure regime; reducing its workforce and/or reducing public sector salaries carries the considerable risk of dangerously high levels of unpopularity, at a time when the PA needs to convince the populace of its ability to carry out its electoral mandate. On the one hand, high public sector salaries can represent unsustainably high costs for the PA, while on the other, excessively low salaries can be expected to have a negative impact on employee motivation and productivity, also making it difficult for the PA to attract skilled professionals. Theoretical and empirical research points to a number of reasons for the emergence of public–private wage differentials, the most obvious being the difference in the economic, political and institutional environment surrounding these sectors. The public sectors of most countries are not bound by the profit-maximizing concerns of private sector firms and the consequent cost-consciousness that prevails in a competitive market. In most cases, particularly in developing countries, the public sector must compete with the private sector to attract the top professionals. This situation suggests that while there is a ‘floor’ to public sector wages―often dictated by private sector wages―there might not be a ‘ceiling’. Finally, wage differentials can also emerge as part of the ‘electoral wage-cycle process’, or because of the collective bargaining strength of the health care and education sectors (Disney and Gosling 1998). International data on wage differentials are mixed, and it is not easy to draw generalizations based on country patterns.2 In some developing and developed countries, such as Australia (Cai and Liu 2011) Brazil (Emilio, Ponczek, and Botelho 2012), Greece (Papapetrou 2006), Haiti (Terrell 1993), India (Glinskaya and Lokshin 2005; Azam and Prakash 2015), Ireland (Foley and O’Callaghan 2011) Italy (Carlo, Lucifora, and Origo 2005; Depalo and Giordano 2011), Pakistan (Naser 2000; Hyder 2002; Hyder and Reilly 2005; Aslam and Kingdon 2009) and Romania (Voinea and Mihaescu 2012), there is evidence of a significant wage premium in favour of the public sector. On the other hand, in cases such as Estonia (Leping 2005, 2006), Germany (Dustmann and van Soest 1998) and Poland (Adamchik and Bedi 2000) the bias seems to be in the other direction, with a negative public wage premium (or a positive private wage premium). France has mixed results, with Giordano et al. (2011) and Lucifora and Meurs (2004) showing a negative public sector premium, and Bargain and Melly (2008) finding both penalties, (for male employees), and premiums, (for females), to be the consequence of selection, and the gap itself DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 3 negligible. Some recent studies find a gradual narrowing of the public sector premium in many OECD countries, as market forces have begun to influence public sector performance and decision-making. Christofides and Michael (2013) find the public–private wage premium to be generally positive for a 2008 cross-sectional sample of workers from 27 European states, but also some inter-country heterogeneity, with Luxembourg, Cyprus, Greece, Hungary and Estonia3 having the largest gaps and Belgium, Germany and Norway with small negative gaps. Giordano et al. (2011) also find the gap to be generally positive based on data from 10 European countries over the years 2004–2007, with Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain exhibiting a larger gap and France exhibiting a negative one. Panizza and Qiang (2005) find positive public sector wage premiums for most of 13 Latin American countries studied, and Mizala, Romaguera, and Gallegos (2011) further examine such gaps using 1992–2007 panel data on 11 Latin American countries, (not all of which are studied by Panizza and Qiang), finding a positive premium for all of them, that increased over the study period. Differences between these two studies can be attributed to the narrower nature of the data used by Panizza and Qiang (2005), which consists of a single-year set for each country. A review of empirical wage gap studies finds the premium to be negative in eastern European economies that transitioned from communism to capitalism during the 1990s, although it became less negative with time, and a zero to positive premium in developed countries (Lausev 2014). The public–private wage gap was found to decrease with wage distribution: high, positive gaps for lower payed workers and small positive, or even negative, gaps for higher paid workers (Azam and Prakash 2015; Cai and Liu 2011; Christofides and Michael 2013; Depalo and Giordano 2011; Foley and O’Callaghan 2011; Mizala, Romaguera, and Gallegos 2011; Papapetrou 2006; Poterba and Rueben 1994; Saha, Roy, and Kar 2014). However, two papers show a different result: Maczulskij (2008) finds that Finnish private sector males at the lower end of the income distribution enjoyed higher premiums, in relation to several factors, such as education, which decreased with income deciles. Voinea and Mihaescu (2012) find that in Romania, the public sector wage premium increases across wage percentiles, then decreases for the top few percentiles of workers. An accurate understanding of public sector salaries vis-à-vis the private sector and how they vary across the wage distribution can greatly assist in setting correct wage and employment policies. A sizeable public sector wage premium has been observed to lead to aberrant labour market behaviour, as individuals might prefer to ‘queue, or wait in unemployment’ for a stable public sector job with an appealing pension plan, and eschew low-paid and/or uncertain jobs in the private sector. This tendency has immediate relevance to Palestine, where a growing number of young people are entering the pool of the unemployed. The aim of this paper is to estimate the public–private wage differential in the West Bank and Gaza Strip, and to describe its dynamics between 1998 and 2006 using labour force surveys from the Palestinian Central Bureau of Statistics (PCBS). It is important to discover how much of the wage variation can be explained by differences in individual characteristics in the two sectors, and how much by differences in the returns to these characteristics across sectors. The econometric results are interesting for a variety of reasons: this is the first serious assessment of public–private wage differentials in Palestine, and the data are rich enough to allow a dynamic analysis of the evolution of differentials over time and by geographical area. The results show that in the pre-Intifada period the wage gap between the public and private sectors narrowed in both the West Bank and Gaza. However, a sharp increase was seen after the outbreak of the Intifada. Moreover, most of the increase in the wage gap comes from an increase in the ‘returns’ to skill composition in the public sector, (unexplained effect), rather than a change in the skills composition of public sector workers, (explained effect). These findings have implications for the incentives presented to a relatively youthful population and a rapidly growing work force, when deciding whether to aim for a job in the public or in the private sector. Because of the possibility that the distribution of salaries in the public sector may differ from that in the private sector due to compression, focusing exclusively on the mean salary levels in the two sectors can be misleading. Instead, using recently developed regression techniques, it has been possible 4 S. H. MIAARI to compare the wage differential at various points along the distribution of salaries. This comparison provides a much richer description of the wage differential along the salary scale, and allows testing for whether there is a decrease or an increase in the differential at upper or lower levels of income, respectively. The wage premium, (penalty), for the public sector varies across the distribution, being higher, (lower), at the lowest end of the wage distribution and decreasing, (increasing), along it; it becomes negative in the top percentiles. Over time, the lower quantiles of West Bank public sector wage earners have continued to earn a significant (log) wage premium, which increased over time, particularly after the outbreak of the Intifada. On the other hand, those in the very top income percentile, (95th), continue to face a wage penalty that has attenuated over time. In Gaza, the wage premium has increased over time, (especially after the outbreak of the Intifada), for both low and high wage earners in the public sector. Comparing 2000 to 2006, the estimates indicate that there was a steady increase in the wage premium for workers in the West Bank and Gaza in all percentiles. Given the inseparability, and thus complexity, of the political and economic challenges facing the PA, and the need for objective analysis to inform policy, this paper offers an interpretation of the wage gap phenomenon in terms of the changing demographic composition of the workforce over the period under study. During this period, the public sector was perceived as a ‘buffer’ to absorb private sector job losses, resulting from the impact, on product and labour markets, of increased closures and movement restrictions imposed by Israel following the second Intifada. However, these results have important policy implications, and could explain whether or not public sector workers are underpaid, why they are reluctant to leave their jobs, and why the PA finds it consistently difficult to fill, and retain the staff in, top-level administrative and managerial positions. The rest of this paper is organized as follows: the next section presents features of the data available on the Palestinian labour market. Methodology section describes the methodology, econometric specification and techniques used to measure wage gaps. The main results of the study are reported in Results section. Estimating the wage gap at various percentiles section provides further evidence on the wage gap using quantile regressions. The conclusion summarizes the findings and caveats. Data This paper’s data are drawn from the Palestinian Labour Force Survey (PLFS) of the West Bank and Gaza Strip, which is administered by the Palestinian Central Bureau of Statistics (PCBS). The PLFS was established in 1995, following the signing of the Oslo Accords and the creation of the Palestinian Authority (PA). In the PLFS, the same household is surveyed four times over six quarters. Two surveys are conducted during two consecutive quarters, and then two more are conducted after a break of two quarters, after which the household is dropped from the sample. From 1998 each yearly survey round contains approximately 7600 households, containing 22,000 individuals aged 15 years and above, residing in the West Bank or Gaza. Nomads and persons living in institutions such as prisons or shelters are not included in the survey. For the purpose of analyzing the public–private sector wage gap, the sample is restricted to male wage earning employees, working in the domestic, public and private sectors of the West Bank and Gaza, aged between 18 and 64, and reporting positive net hourly wages and positive days worked per month in the 1998 and 2006 surveys.4 This excludes Palestinian workers employed in the Israeli labour market.5 Palestinian women are excluded because their labour force participation rates have traditionally been low.6 Workers’ hourly wages are calculated by dividing daily income by hours worked per day.7 Because a ‘simple average’ can be strongly affected by large or extreme values, outliers in terms of hourly wage are dealt with by excluding observations below the 1st and above the 99th percentile of the log hourly wage distribution for each year.8 Rounds of the survey prior to 1998 are not considered because in 1995 the survey was conducted in one quarter only, and it was an experimental sample. In 1996, the survey was conducted over three DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 5 quarters. It was not until 1998, after the Palestinian census of 1997, that the survey was conducted in all four quarters of the year. The Local Palestinian Labor Market after the Intifada The share of West Bank male workers employed in the private sector, as a proportion of all employees in the West Bank labour market, decreased sharply between 1998 and 2006. This share fell by 10 percentage points, from a high of 67% in 1998 to 57% in 2006. Note the sharp drop in the share of people employed in the private sector, out of all employed individuals, in 2002 (Figure 2). This is a consequence of the second Intifada, which began in September 2000, and the onerous system of checkpoints imposed in the West Bank in 2002. In 1998, 45% of Gaza’s male employees worked in the private sector; by 2006, this proportion had dipped to 30% (Figure 3).9 As the share of workers in the private sector declined over the period 1998–2006, the role of the public sector, in absorbing a growing Palestinian labour force, grew, especially following the second Intifada. In 1998, 30% of West Bank male employees, and 48% of Gazan male employees were working in the public sector; by 2006 the proportions had reached 39% for West Bank males and 60% for Gazan males (Figures 2 and 3). It should be noted that the overall size of the Palestinian public sector workforce, (as opposed to the percentage of workers employed by the public sector), is not very large by international standards: based on 2013 World Bank estimates, Figure 2. share of West Bank male employees across various sectors, 1998–2006. source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs). Figure 3. share of Gaza male employees across various sectors, 1998–2006. source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs). 6 S. H. MIAARI (which include civil servants and the security services, but which exclude employees of state enterprises, autonomous public bodies not financed by the national government’s budget, and municipal government employees), public sector employment in the West Bank and Gaza comprised just 4.6% of the Palestinian population, while the average for the 75 developed and developing countries in the World Bank’s database was about 5.4%10 (World Bank 2016). Two factors contributed to the growth of the Palestinian public sector: first, the external and internal closure regimes, imposed by the Israeli authorities, restricted the mobility of Palestinians, leading to a decline in the number of Palestinians employed in the Israeli labour market, (thus increasing the supply of employees to the local private sector), and to a fall in local economic activity in the West Bank and Gaza, (and thus lower demand for employees in the local private sector).11 Consequently, the share of employees in the local (Palestinian) private sector decreased (Figures 2 and 3).12 As a result of the closure regime, the unemployment rate in the West Bank increased from 11% in 1998 to 28% in 2002, and in Gaza from 20% in 1998 to 38% in 2002. Given this increase the PA felt compelled to absorb a large number of the unemployed―despite the unfavourable economic circumstances ―in order to minimize the negative effect of unemployment. Second, faced with political instability, the PA sought to control both individuals and security in general, and this led it to employ a greater number of workers in its military and law enforcement services/agencies. One might expect that the monopsonistic power of the PA, derived from the decline of the private sector, coupled with possible reductions in revenue, would translate into lower wages in the public sector. As we see throughout this paper, the opposite is true; public sector wages have risen. It is possible that this increase was, in part, a response to political pressure on the PA to provide ‘pane e circus’, (‘bread and entertainment’), to keep the population satisfied during a period of upheaval. The fact that much of the growth, both in jobs and wages, was in the security sector (World Bank 2006b), required to maintain public order, strengthens the hypothesis that the increase was a response to political pressures on the PA to keep the population in order. Descriptive Statistics Table 1 summarizes the mean values of the labour force attributes observed in the period 1998–2006 for West Bank male workers in the public and private sectors, respectively. The labour force profile of workers in the samples changed over the study period. There was a small increase in the average age of private sector workers and their average years of schooling. However, for public sector workers, the average years of schooling remained unchanged over the same period, with only a slight increase in average age. Comparing 2006 to 2000, there was an increase in the proportion of married workers, and in average tenure in both the public and private sectors. Compared with private sector employees, the figures in Table 1 also show that public sector employees were on average better educated, older, more likely to be married and more likely to be tenured. However, the trend of real hourly wages differed considerably between the public and private sectors over the period in question. In the public sector, real hourly wages increased over the period 1998–2000, in 2001 they decreased, and from 2002 they again increased as a result of legislation and administrative decisions (World Bank 2006b). On the other hand, in the private sector there was a decrease in salaries over the period 2001–2006, as a result of a sharp decrease in the number of Palestinians employed in the Israeli labour market and low demand for employees in the local private sector.13 A comparison between real hourly wages in the public and private sectors reveals that the unadjusted wage gap between the two sectors decreased between the years prior to the second Intifada, from 3.4% in 1998 to −4% in 2000. However, it increased after the beginning of the second Intifada, from −1.7% in 2001 to 28% in 2006. Table 2 describes the mean characteristics of the sample of male workers in Gaza. The labour force profile of males in Gaza changes over the period with a slight increase in the average age of private sector workers and in their average years of schooling. For public sector workers, these averages remained Table 1. summary statistics of variables by sector: West Bank males, 1998–2006. Hourly Wage Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Total Private 6.336 (3.50) 6.809 (3.49) 7.205 (3.65) 6.604 (3.15) 6.608 (3.96) 6.028 (3.61) 5.753 (3.64) 5.520 (3.44) 5.588 (3.69) 6.315 (3.60) Public 12.399 (3.90) 12.499 (3.91) 12.466 (3.87) 12.420 (3.74) 12.605 (3.80) 12.755 (3.73) 12.627 (3.63) 12.442 (3.59) 12.331 (3.67) 12.492 (3.76) Private 9.581 (3.51) 9.598 (3.51) 9.719 (3.54) 9.858 (3.38) 10.144 (3.55) 10.058 (3.55) 10.157 (3.57) 10.069 (3.45) 10.133 (3.46) 9.877 (3.51) Age Public 35.052 (10.87) 35.289 (10.37) 34.297 (10.95) 35.424 (10.87) 37.764 (11.11) 37.625 (10.93) 37.155 (11.19) 35.828 (10.74) 35.782 (10.69) 35.878 (10.90) Private 29.996 (9.83) 30.279 (9.81) 30.473 (9.92) 30.809 (9.68) 31.103 (9.84) 31.698 (10.31) 31.546 (10.15) 31.902 (10.20) 32.067 (10.16) 30.994 (10.00) Married Public 0.695 (0.46) 0.734 (0.44) 0.664 (0.47) 0.695 (0.46) 0.753 (0.43) 0.749 (0.43) 0.745 (0.44) 0.733 (0.44) 0.708 (0.45) 0.716 (0.45) Private 0.585 (0.49) 0.597 (0.49) 0.585 (0.49) 0.595 (0.49) 0.588 (0.49) 0.589 (0.49) 0.592 (0.49) 0.619 (0.49) 0.611 (0.49) 0.596 (0.49) Tenure Public 80.677 (96.80) 139.394 (166.50) 81.462 (92.16) 85.572 (91.19) 99.474 (98.74) 98.574 (94.64) 98.048 (92.52) 92.021 (85.24) 95.003 (82.85) 96.050 (103.81) Private 58.937 (78.78) 116.169 (166.71) 69.454 (77.75) 67.891 (75.76) 69.916 (78.61) 70.825 (82.06) 70.301 (81.02) 69.595 (78.45) 70.668 (82.81) 74.664 (97.96) City Public 0.378 (0.48) 0.401 (0.49) 0.401 (0.49) 0.376 (0.48) 0.411 (0.49) 0.355 (0.48) 0.362 (0.48) 0.344 (0.48) 0.344 (0.48) 0.374 (0.48) Private 0.437 (0.50) 0.404 (0.49) 0.414 (0.49) 0.430 (0.50) 0.426 (0.49) 0.416 (0.49) 0.458 (0.50) 0.436 (0.50) 0.422 (0.49) 0.426 (0.49) Village Public 0.543 (0.50) 0.447 (0.50) 0.412 (0.49) 0.430 (0.50) 0.437 (0.50) 0.515 (0.50) 0.507 (0.50) 0.508 (0.50) 0.525 (0.50) 0.480 (0.50) Private 0.490 (0.50) 0.451 (0.50) 0.449 (0.50) 0.432 (0.50) 0.450 (0.50) 0.447 (0.50) 0.410 (0.49) 0.428 (0.49) 0.454 (0.50) 0.448 (0.50) Full-time employment Public 0.908 (0.29) 0.919 (0.27) 0.889 (0.31) 0.954 (0.21) 0.907 (0.29) 0.910 (0.29) 0.936 (0.24) 0.927 (0.26) 0.926 (0.26) 0.919 (0.27) Private 0.894 (0.31) 0.901 (0.30) 0.882 (0.32) 0.899 (0.30) 0.813 (0.39) 0.862 (0.35) 0.883 (0.32) 0.849 (0.36) 0.786 (0.41) 0.867 (0.34) N Public 2098 Private 4385 2208 4393 2527 4237 2112 2954 1495 1925 1791 2497 1873 2554 2357 3510 2338 3466 18,799 29,921 source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: The sample includes West Bank salaried, prime-aged (18–65) males. The income variable is the real hourly wage in constant 1996 new israeli shekels (₪). in 1996, 1₪.00 equalled approximately $Us 0.33. The married variable takes on the value 1 if the person is married, and 0 otherwise. The Tenure variable is in months. standard deviations in parentheses. DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 2006 Public 6.555 (3.41) 6.967 (3.40) 6.913 (3.33) 6.490 (2.77) 6.681 (3.38) 6.643 (3.42) 7.093 (3.54) 6.929 (3.33) 7.207 (3.60) 6.844 (3.37) Schooling 7 8 S. H. MIAARI Table 2. summary statistics of variables by sector: Gaza males, 1998–2006. Hourly Wage Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Total Public 6.474 (3.44) 6.586 (3.12) 6.780 (3.12) 6.742 (2.63) 6.771 (2.97) 6.520 (3.22) 6.733 (3.23) 7.592 (3.46) 8.370 (3.70) 6.990 (3.29) Private 3.737 (1.99) 4.009 (2.35) 4.353 (2.69) 4.600 (2.49) 4.294 (3.09) 4.006 (2.28) 3.973 (2.64) 3.659 (2.59) 3.566 (2.53) 3.982 (2.51) Schooling Public 12.564 (3.72) 12.197 (3.74) 12.416 (3.60) 12.486 (3.50) 12.587 (3.53) 12.414 (3.78) 12.554 (3.71) 12.464 (3.64) 12.474 (3.53) 12.456 (3.64) Private 8.894 (3.64) 9.435 (3.60) 9.439 (3.88) 10.046 (3.80) 9.946 (3.77) 9.513 (3.67) 9.948 (3.81) 9.725 (3.63) 9.996 (3.56) 9.597 (3.71) Age Public 34.517 (11.03) 35.219 (10.84) 35.135 (10.58) 34.917 (10.37) 36.178 (10.37) 36.291 (10.84) 36.214 (10.75) 35.936 (10.15) 35.390 (10.14) 35.537 (10.56) Private 29.364 (9.59) 28.997 (9.02) 30.046 (10.02) 31.145 (9.69) 31.068 (9.89) 31.854 (9.35) 32.362 (9.76) 32.367 (9.90) 33.185 (10.39) 31.001 (9.81) Married Public 0.755 (0.43) 0.830 (0.38) 0.808 (0.39) 0.784 (0.41) 0.825 (0.38) 0.800 (0.40) 0.781 (0.41) 0.820 (0.38) 0.807 (0.39) 0.802 (0.40) Private 0.683 (0.47) 0.636 (0.48) 0.640 (0.48) 0.698 (0.46) 0.684 (0.47) 0.722 (0.45) 0.708 (0.45) 0.702 (0.46) 0.724 (0.45) 0.685 (0.46) Tenure Public 62.604 (79.68) 148.098 (191.51) 62.169 (59.91) 64.196 (58.55) 71.197 (68.22) 75.157 (59.33) 80.825 (64.26) 84.698 (60.69) 87.886 (65.27) 82.506 (91.93) Private 38.635 (49.34) 94.277 (151.05) 44.866 (57.98) 49.934 (60.06) 42.714 (52.33) 44.426 (48.52) 47.424 (62.32) 39.389 (56.85) 37.895 (55.60) 50.481 (80.00) City Public 0.436 (0.50) 0.533 (0.50) 0.547 (0.50) 0.553 (0.50) 0.542 (0.50) 0.546 (0.50) 0.520 (0.50) 0.502 (0.50) 0.494 (0.50) 0.520 (0.50) Private 0.558 (0.50) 0.613 (0.49) 0.590 (0.49) 0.593 (0.49) 0.614 (0.49) 0.603 (0.49) 0.599 (0.49) 0.614 (0.49) 0.575 (0.49) 0.595 (0.49) Village Public 0.144 (0.35) 0.088 (0.28) 0.067 (0.25) 0.064 (0.25) 0.068 (0.25) 0.065 (0.25) 0.077 (0.27) 0.086 (0.28) 0.099 (0.30) 0.083 (0.28) Private 0.143 (0.35) 0.089 (0.28) 0.094 (0.29) 0.089 (0.28) 0.090 (0.29) 0.110 (0.31) 0.096 (0.29) 0.121 (0.33) 0.137 (0.34) 0.109 (0.31) Full-time employment Public 0.891 (0.31) 0.903 (0.30) 0.878 (0.33) 0.874 (0.33) 0.875 (0.33) 0.868 (0.34) 0.890 (0.31) 0.875 (0.33) 0.862 (0.35) 0.879 (0.33) Private 0.947 (0.22) 0.941 (0.24) 0.894 (0.31) 0.870 (0.34) 0.850 (0.36) 0.854 (0.35) 0.925 (0.26) 0.926 (0.26) 0.861 (0.35) 0.903 (0.30) N Public 1781 Private 1513 2296 1762 2354 1428 2241 745 1903 849 2089 1304 2186 1141 2454 1418 2450 1193 19,754 11,353 source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: The sample includes Gaza salaried, prime-aged (18–65) males. The income variable is the real hourly-wage in constant 1996 new israeli shekels (₪). in 1996, 1₪.00 equalled approximately $Us 0.33. The married variable takes on the value 1 if the person is married and 0 otherwise. The Tenure variable is in months. standard deviations in parentheses. DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 9 unchanged over the same period. The proportion of married workers increased in both sectors. A significant increase in the average tenure of public sector employees is observed, while there is no clear pattern among private sector employees. The figures in Table 2 also show that public sector employees are on average better educated, older, more likely to be married and more likely to be tenured. The unadjusted wage gap between the public and private sectors decreased between 1998 and 2000, from 73% in 1998 to 55% in 2000. However, it increased from 46% in 2001 to 134% in 2006. It is evident from Tables 1 and 2 that over the sample period real wages in the private sector remained below those in the public sector. The only exceptions to this are the years 2000 and 2001 in the West Bank male sample, where the wage gap was in favour of the private sector. Moreover, the decrease in the real hourly wage in the West Bank was faster than that in Gaza, because internal and external closures imposed in the West Bank, after the beginning of the second Intifada, were more widespread than those in Gaza.14 Methodology Basic Specification of Model A convenient starting point for estimating the magnitude of the public–private wage gap is to use ordinary least squares with a dummy variable for public sector participation on a pooled sample of workers. In this approach, an individual i has (log) real hourly wage ln Wi, conditional on observed characteristics Xi and a dummy variable Di that takes the value of 0 or 1 depending on whether the individual works in the private sector or public sector. Adding an error term εi distributed with a mean of zero leads to the least squares (OLS) specification: LnWi = X � i 𝛽 + Di 𝛿 + 𝜀i , (1) where β is a vector of unknown parameters whose estimates would provide the influence or ‘returns’ of the observed qualitative variables Xi on lnWi, and δ is the unknown parameter whose estimates provide the ceteris paribus impact of working in the public sector. While simple and intuitive, the foregoing approach is problematic for several reasons. The OLS estimate of δ captures only a pure ‘shift’ effect of working in the public sector, and ignores the fact that salaries could well differ because of differences in observed characteristics such as education and age across the two sectors. The foregoing OLS estimation assumes that error terms are homoskedastic and identically distributed across individuals. This may not be an appropriate assumption, especially when dealing with survey samples and two quite distinct population groups. Secondly, the pooled OLS dummy variable specification assumes that the earnings are distributed identically across both the private and public sectors. To the extent that the public sector compresses the distribution of earnings of those employees who work in that sector relative to the private sector, the least squares estimates are likely to be biased and produce an incomplete picture of the conditional distribution of lnWi (see Disney and Gosling 1998; Nielsen and Rosholm 2001). Finally, the least squares procedure, as specified above, does not control for endogenous selectivity bias; that is, the distribution of workers between the public and private sectors may not be completely random in the West Bank and Gaza. The approach employed to correct for these problems was to adopt the Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition method with modifications: (a) for decomposing the wage gap according to observed characteristics; and (b) implementing a correction for endogenous selectivity bias. Moreover, a quantile regression framework that examines the wage gap at various points along the wage distributions is appropriate to accommodate differing distributions of wages between the two sectors. It is important to correct for these in any econometric specification within the context of Palestine, where the public sector continues to attract workers in an environment where the private sector is buffeted by considerable uncertainty and exogenous shocks. 10 S. H. MIAARI Decomposing the Wage Gap within the OLS Framework While the preceding section calculates the wage premium/penalty for working in the public sector, it does not make it possible to control for the fact that individual attributes or their returns might vary across workers and sectors. Thus, the dummy variable estimates of the preceding section show the ‘shift’ or ceteris paribus effect of working in the public sector, and provide no information as to whether the observed differentials are due to differences in attributes or to differences in the returns to these attributes. The focus of this section is on decomposing the observed wage differential in order to better understand how much of it is caused by differences in the distribution of attributes, and how much is due to differences in the returns to these attributes. Within the OLS framework, a convenient way of decomposing observed pay gaps is to run separate regressions for each sector. Letting the subscript j (j = 1, 0) denote the public and private sectors, respectively, and i individuals, the following regression specification is estimated for each sector: LnWi = X � ij 𝛽j + 𝜀ij (2) where Wij is the hourly wage, Xij is a vector of worker characteristics, and εij a zero-mean constantvariance error term. Then, the wage equations, estimated by OLS at the mean point, will be: LnWj = X � j 𝛽̂j for (3) j = 1, 0 where 𝛽̂j is the OLS estimate of the marginal effects, or returns of observed characteristics Xj, on salaries, and Xj is the mean level of observed characteristics across sector j. The regressors vector x ′ ij includes age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, (total months in the same workplace), marital status, (dummy which takes value 1 if the worker is married and zero otherwise), full-time employment, (dummy which takes value 1 if the worker works at least 35 h a week and zero otherwise); set of location of residence dummies, (urban area and refugee camp), occupational dummies and district fixed effects.15 The average public–private gross wage gap ln(1 + G) is the difference between the average salaries in the two sectors.16: ln W 1 − ln W 0 = ln(1 + G) = (X̄ 1 − X̄ 0 )� 𝛽̂∗ + X̄ 1� (𝛽̂1 − 𝛽̂∗ ) + X̄ 0� (𝛽̂∗ − 𝛽̂0 ), ����������� ����������������������������������� E (4) R where 𝛽̂∗ is the estimate of the non-discriminatory wage coefficients. Equation (4) is the general Oaxaca decomposition, as per Oaxaca and Ransom (1994). It disentangles the average gross wage differential ln(1 + G) across the two sectors into two terms: the first term, E, is the explained component of the overall wage gap: the differential due to differences in the distribution of average characteristics, (the endowment effect). The second, R, is the unexplained component of the overall wage gap: the differences in the estimated coefficients or ‘returns’ between the two sectors (the ‘returns’ effect). If we assume that 𝛽̂∗ = 𝛽̂1, then the general Oaxaca decomposition reduces to the classical Oaxaca-Blinder (1973) decomposition. In this case, the first term will be evaluated at the returns in the public sector, and the second at the mean set of private sector characteristics. The study was conducted under two differing assumptions regarding the non-discriminatory wage coefficients𝛽̂∗. First, the estimated wage structure of the public sector was adopted as the non-discriminatory standard, i.e. 𝛽̂∗ = 𝛽̂1 as per Blinder (1973). These are the main results, reported in Tables 4–7. Second, 𝛽̂∗ is assumed to be equal to the estimated wage coefficients from a pooled regression that includes both public and private sectors, as per Neumark (1988), and Oaxaca and Ransom (1994).17 These results are reported in the Appendix 1. Moreover, since the decomposition results for categorical predictors depend on the choice of the omitted ‘base’ category (Jones 1983; Jones and Kelley 1984; Oaxaca and Ransom 1999; Nielsen 2000; Horrace and Oaxaca 2001; Gardeazabal and Ugidos 2004; Polavieja 2005; Yun ), we estimate the model with the conventional dummy arrangement, but transform the coefficient vectors so the usually omitted coefficient for the base category is included DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 11 and deviations from the grand mean are expressed. That keeps the result independent of the choice of base category (Suits 1984; Yun 2005). Selectivity-corrected Wage Gap Decomposition Estimates of wage gaps are potentially afflicted by sample selection bias arising from self-selection into sector (Heckman 1979). This section explores the possible impact of this source of bias on the estimate of the public–private wage differential. In order to obtain selectivity-corrected decompositions, the selectivity effect as a whole was calculated. The corrected gross wage gap was then decomposed into an endowment effect, a return effect, and a selectivity effect. In other words, the decomposition in Equation 4 is generalized as follows18: ln(1 + G) = (X̄ 1 − X̄ 0 )� 𝛽̂∗ + X̄ 1� (𝛽̂1 − 𝛽̂∗ ) + X̄ 0� (𝛽̂∗ − 𝛽̂0 ) + (𝜃̂1 𝜆̂ 1 − 𝜃̂0 𝜆̂ 0 ), ����������� ����������������������������������� ������������� E R (5) Selection where 𝜃̂ is the coefficient of the Inverse Mills Ratio (𝜆̂) in the modified wage equation. The selectivity-corrected wage equations are estimated by the Heckman two-step procedure. The probability of working in the public or private sector depends on the individual’s profile and a number of factors may constitute the costs and benefits of employment in a particular sector, such as job security and working environment. Thus, the explanatory variables in the selection equation are: age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, district fixed effects, number of jobholders in the same household, number of adults aged 70 or more in the household and share of public sector employees as a proportion of total labour force in locality. The number of jobholders (Lokshin and Javanovic 2003), number of adults aged 70 or more in a given household (Aslam and Kingdon 2009) and share of public sector employees (Voinea and Mihaescu 2012) are the additional variables included only in the selection equation. These variables affect a worker’s decision to seek a secure job, in either the public or private sector, yet do not affect his or her wage. That is, they account for the importance of a secure job and its associated benefits in sector choice.19 Results Table 3 summarizes the OLS results from estimating Equation (1) for each year of the PCBS labour force survey in two specifications both for the West Bank and Gaza. Specifications 1 and 3 include only the public dummy variable; the reported coefficient therefore measures the overall unadjusted (logarithmic) wage gap. In Specifications 2 and 4, in addition to the public dummy variable, all of the explanatory variables, as described in the previous section, are included, hence the reported coefficient measures the adjusted wage gap. For most years in the West Bank and Gaza Strip, the estimated coefficients of δ are highly significant at the 95% confidence level, and increase over time. It is apparent from Table 3 that introducing the productivity-related variables into the wage equations greatly reduces the measured wage gap. This fact highlights the magnitude of the explained components of the wage gap. The estimates for West Bank male workers suggest that in the earlier phases of the second Intifada, public sector male workers in the West Bank faced a wage penalty vis-à-vis their private sector counterparts, (controlling for differences in attributes or ceteris paribus), yet this effect disappears, then eventually reverses over time. From the beginning of the second Intifada, the PA systematically addressed the issue of a negative public sector wage gap through salary increases, such that by 2003 there is considerable evidence of an increase in the wage gap. In 1999, the public–private log wage differential was estimated at –0.10. However, by 2003 a positive public sector pay premium emerged. In 2005, the public sector pay premium rose significantly as another salary increase was implemented, (column 2). This increase may represent an effort to appeal to public sector workers in the run-up to 12 S. H. MIAARI Table 3. estimated unadjusted and adjusted wage differential. West Bank males Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 (1) 0.0648*** (0.0128) 0.0385*** (0.0123) −0.0156 (0.0117) 0.0137 (0.0123) 0.0760*** (0.0183) 0.1487*** (0.0159) 0.2764*** (0.0154) 0.2870*** (0.0133) 0.3310*** (0.0141) Gaza Males (2) −0.0544*** (0.0137) −0.1028*** (0.0139) −0.0965*** (0.0128) −0.0341** (0.0135) −0.0296 (0.0201) 0.0207 (0.0164) 0.0883*** (0.0148) 0.1252*** (0.0133) 0.1944*** (0.0154) (3) 0.5462*** (0.0156) 0.5292*** (0.0140) 0.4906*** (0.0156) 0.4332*** (0.0186) 0.5410*** (0.0205) 0.5049*** (0.0154) 0.5837*** (0.0182) 0.7904*** (0.0158) 0.9182*** (0.0174) (4) 0.2655*** (0.0187) 0.2269*** (0.0187) 0.2380*** (0.0173) 0.2367*** (0.0176) 0.2742*** (0.0233) 0.2604*** (0.0187) 0.3005*** (0.0196) 0.4266*** (0.0180) 0.5515*** (0.0210) source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: samples include salaried, prime-aged (18–65) males. The reported gap is measured by the coefficient of sector dummy variables (that take on the value 1 if the worker is employed in the public sector, and 0 if employed in the private sector) in a pooled wage regression that includes both public and private sector employees. The dependent variable in all specifications is the log of hourly wage. specifications 1 and 3 include only public dummy variable. specifications 2 and 4 include public dummy variable, age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, and district fixed effects. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels. the national elections, held in January 2006. Among male workers in the Gaza Strip, the public sector pay premium declined between the years 1998 and 1999, while the period 2000–2006 witnessed an increase (column 4). Alongside the fiscal burden of providing the public sector with wage premiums in relation to the private sector and the equity issues it raises, this trend is also worrying for other reasons. Within an environment of high unemployment, particularly among the young, the trend creates an incentive for job seekers to ‘wait’ for a secure job in the public sector, (or engage in civil strife to acquire it), rather than to strive to find employment in a highly fragmented and uncertain private sector. This may be described as rent seeking. Although the simple empirical exercise can be revealing, the objective is to decompose the observed wage differential into two components: one is due to differences in individual worker characteristics, and the other is due to differences in returns to those characteristics. The econometric results for the Oaxaca decomposition are shown in Table 4, under the assumption that 𝛽̂∗ = 𝛽̂1. The analyses of Tables 5–7 are also performed under that assumption. For comparison, Tables A1–A4 report analyses made under the assumption that 𝛽̂∗ = 𝛽̂pooled, i.e. 𝛽̂∗ is equal to the estimated wage coefficients from a pooled regression that includes both public and private sectors. The results under the two assumptions are reported for the sake of completeness, although the description of the data findings will be confined to the first assumption. The figures in Table 4, column (G), indicate the mean (log) wage differential between the public and private sectors. It is the sum or aggregate of the endowment effect (E) and the returns effect (R). An interesting pattern emerges among West Bank male workers: during the period before the Intifada, between 1998 and 2000, the gross wage gap decreased. This decrease is explained by the returns effect decreasing during this period. During that time, the endowment effect increased. After the outbreak of the Intifada, the period between 2001 and 2006, the gross wage gap increased. During that time, both the returns effect and the endowment effect increased, with the returns effect responsible for the DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 13 Table 4. Decomposing the wage differential over time: β* = βpublic. West Bank males Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 G 0.0664*** (0.0129) 0.0336*** (0.0129) 0.0277** (0.0120) 0.0318** (0.0125) 0.0868*** (0.0187) 0.1490*** (0.0160) 0.2776*** (0.0155) 0.2884*** (0.0134) 0.3296*** (0.0142) E 0.1405*** (0.0165) 0.1772*** (0.0174) 0.1878*** (0.0153) 0.1250*** (0.0153) 0.1502*** (0.0220) 0.1725*** (0.0204) 0.2118*** (0.0190) 0.1815*** (0.0158) 0.1575*** (0.0197) Gaza males R −0.0741*** (0.0178) −0.1436*** (0.0182) −0.1602*** (0.0161) −0.0932*** (0.0168) −0.0634*** (0.0241) −0.0235 (0.0220) 0.0658*** (0.0202) 0.1069*** (0.0171) 0.1721*** (0.0214) G 0.5483*** (0.0156) 0.5248*** (0.0142) 0.4911*** (0.0156) 0.4333*** (0.0188) 0.5410*** (0.0207) 0.5049*** (0.0155) 0.5832*** (0.0183) 0.7902*** (0.0158) 0.9182*** (0.0175) E 0.2587*** (0.0191) 0.2768*** (0.0186) 0.2493*** (0.0160) 0.1423*** (0.0146) 0.1881*** (0.0177) 0.2152*** (0.0180) 0.2244*** (0.0192) 0.3445*** (0.0154) 0.3638*** (0.0169) R 0.2896*** (0.0203) 0.2479*** (0.0202) 0.2418*** (0.0176) 0.2910*** (0.0183) 0.3529*** (0.0222) 0.2897*** (0.0200) 0.3587*** (0.0210) 0.4457*** (0.0164) 0.5545*** (0.0194) note: The dependent variable in the wage equations is the logarithm of hourly wage; the independent variables are age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, and district fixed effects. G refers to the gross wage gap (or ln(1+G)), e refers to the explained component of the wage gap (endowment effect), and R refers to the unexplained (return effect) component of the wage gap. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels. source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 19982006. majority of the wage gap increase. In other words, the positive endowment impact in the public sector is offset by the large negative return effect in the early years, resulting in a negative wage differential or an overall wage penalty for working in the public sector by the year 2000. However, a rapid rise in the returns effect over time generates a positive wage gap in favour of the public sector from 2001. In 2006, both the returns effect and the endowment effect are positive and work in the same direction to produce a substantial wage premium for the public sector, about 48% of which is due to the endowment effect, and 52% to the so-called return effect. Note that throughout 1998–2006, (with the exception of 2006), the endowment effect constituted the majority of the gross wage gap’s size. Among male workers in Gaza, the gross wage gap experienced the same general trend as the West Bank – decreasing in 1998–2000 and increasing in 2001–2006. However, unlike for the West Bank, both the endowment effect and the returns effect decreased, in the period before the Intifada. As in the West Bank, after the outbreak of the Intifada, both effects increased. The decline in the endowment and returns effects in the public sector in the early years of the study, in turn result in a significant decline in the public–private wage differential. A rapid rise in the returns and endowment effects over time generates a concurrent increase in the wage gap from 2001. In 2006, both the returns effect and the endowment effect are positive and work in the same direction to produce a wage premium for the public sector, about 40% of which is due to the endowment effect and 60% to the returns effect. Unlike for the West bank, it was the returns effect that constituted the majority of the wage gap over the entire period, with the exception of 1999–2000. The results reported so far do not take into account the possible selection bias caused when workers with different characteristics choose different sectors. Table 5 reports the selectivity-corrected decomposition results. We see that taking into account selectivity correction does not change the general trend of the gross wage gap, but does affect the trends of its components. The corrected gross wage gap, Ĝ, still declines in the period before the outbreak of the Intifada, (1998–2000), and increases thereafter, (2001–2006). There are however some differences. In the West Bank, the gross wage gap decreases in the period before the outbreak of the Intifada (1998–2000). This is explained by a decrease in the returns 14 S. H. MIAARI Table 5. selectivity-corrected wage gap decomposition: β* = βpublic. West Bank males Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 G 0.0656*** (0.0129) 0.0291** (0.0129) 0.0277** (0.0120) 0.0318** (0.0125) 0.0868*** (0.0187) 0.1490*** (0.0160) 0.2776*** (0.0155) 0.2884*** (0.0134) 0.3296*** (0.0142) E 0.1690*** (0.0409) 0.2310*** (0.0497) 0.1747*** (0.0357) 0.1009** (0.0430) 0.1778*** (0.0520) 0.1513*** (0.0461) 0.2406*** (0.0370) 0.2290*** (0.0385) 0.2066*** (0.0527) R −0.1284* (0.0742) −0.2703*** (0.0833) −0.1375** (0.0623) −0.0783 (0.0750) 0.0489 (0.0890) 0.0525 (0.0827) 0.0198 (0.0685) 0.0007 (0.0722) 0.0654 (0.0925) Gaza males Selection 0.025 Ĝ 0.041 0.068 −0.039 −0.009 0.037 0.009 0.023 −0.140 0.227 −0.055 0.204 0.017 0.260 0.059 0.230 0.058 0.272 G 0.5483*** (0.0156) 0.5248*** (0.0142) 0.4911*** (0.0156) 0.4333*** (0.0188) 0.5410*** (0.0207) 0.5049*** (0.0155) 0.5832*** (0.0183) 0.7902*** (0.0159) 0.9182*** (0.0175) E 0.4576*** (0.0845) 0.5803*** (0.0707) 0.4926*** (0.0630) 0.3792*** (0.0510) −0.0305 (0.0575) 0.1822*** (0.0539) 0.1386** (0.0585) 0.2055*** (0.0429) 0.2136*** (0.0457) R −0.0070 (0.1298) −0.1866* (0.1041) −0.1214 (0.1101) 0.3609** (0.1409) 0.7707*** (0.1351) 0.3956*** (0.0952) 0.5440*** (0.1038) 0.6968*** (0.0779) 0.8617*** (0.1084) Selection 0.098 Ĝ 0.451 0.131 0.394 0.120 0.371 −0.307 0.740 −0.199 0.740 −0.073 0.578 −0.099 0.683 −0.112 0.902 −0.157 1.075 source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: Regressions are estimated using the Heckman selection correction method where the first step is a probit regression. G refers to the gross wage gap (or ln(1 + G)), e refers to the explained component of the wage gap (endowment effect), R refers to the unexplained (return effect) component of the wage gap. selection is the component of the wage gap attributed to self-selection into sector, and Ĝ is the selectivity-corrected gross wage gap. The dependent variable in the wage equations is the logarithm of hourly wage; the independent variables are age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, and district fixed effects. The selection equation includes as explanatory variables, age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, district fixed effects, number of jobholders, number of adults aged 70 or more in a given household, and locality’s share of public sector employees. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 per cent levels. effect and in the selection effect. During the same period, the endowment effect increases, but this effect is much smaller. After the outbreak of the Intifada (2001–2006), the gross wage gap increases. The majority of this increase is explained by an increase in the returns effect. The endowment effect also increases during the same period, but this effect is smaller. Throughout this period, the endowment effect is dominant in explaining the gross wage gap itself, (though not the change). In Gaza, the gross wage gap also decreased in the years before the outbreak of the Intifada (1998– 2000). During this period, the endowment effect increases, the returns effect decreases and the returns effect is more dominant in determining the net change in the wage gap. The dominant component accounting for the gross wage gap itself remained the endowment effect. In the period after the outbreak of the Intifada (2001–2006), the gross wage gap increases. This increase is explained by an increase in the returns effect. The endowment effect decreased during this period. Except for 2001, the returns effect was dominant in explaining the gross wage gap itself. The results show that in the pre-Intifada period, the wage gap between the public and private sectors narrowed in both the West Bank and Gaza. However, a sharp increase was seen at the end of the time period, as a result of the increase in public sector wages brought on by implementation of new civil service laws and government-mandated public wage increases, and a rapid decrease in private sector wages brought on by a sharp decrease in the number of Palestinians working in the Israeli labour market and low demand for employees in the local private sector.20 This is not surprising given the disruptive influence the Intifada had on private sector jobs. Moreover, most of the increase in the wage gap, in both the West Bank and Gaza after the outbreak of the Intifada, stems from an increase in the ‘returns’ to skill composition in the public sector, (unexplained effect), rather than a change in the skills composition of public sector workers (explained effect). DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 15 Palestinians working in Israel were generally less skilled, (and lower paid), workers in the private sector, or workers with fewer years of schooling, relative to the average for the Palestinian workforce (Miaari and Sauer 2011). Unskilled workers, returning from Israel, compete with locals largely for private sector unskilled jobs in the Palestinian labour market, often winning them at the expense of unskilled local workers. Consequently, for wage earners who continued to be employed in the local market, or who had obtained jobs in the local market, the impact was exacerbated by the decline in average real private sector wages over much of the Intifada period, meaning a high gross public–private wage gap among unskilled workers during this period. Further, since the unskilled workers are homogenous, we would expect the endowment effect of the wage gap to be low. In turn, we would expect the unexplained component of the wage gap to follow the pattern of the overall gross pay gap. Table 6 and Table 7 document the selectivity-corrected decomposition of the public–private wage gap for skilled and unskilled workers in the West Bank and Gaza, respectively. For skilled workers in the West Bank, the gross wage gap decreased between 1998 and 2002, and increased from 2003 to 2006. The selectivity-corrected gap decreased between 1998 and 2000, and increased between 2001 and 2006. The endowment effect for these workers increased in 1998–2000, decreased in 2001 and increased in 2002–2006. The returns effect decreased in 1998–2000, increased in 2001, decreased again in 2002–2003 and increased in 2004–2006. The gross wage gap among unskilled workers in the West Bank decreased, (became more negative), from 1998 and 2000, and increased thereafter, reaching 0.24 in 2006. The selectivity-corrected gap’s trend was similar, although more volatile. The endowment effect increased between 1998 and 1999, decreased between 2000 and 2001, and increased again from 2002 to 2006, while the returns effect decreased from 1998 to 1999, and increased over the period 2000–2006. The continued increase during the years of the Intifada is related to the entry of a large number of unskilled workers previously employed in the Israeli labour market, coinciding with a decline in the local economic activity. An increase in unskilled labour supply, along with a general decrease in demand, resulted in a decrease in private sector wages unrelated to skills and other explained variables, thus increasing the returns effect. In Gaza, the gross wage gap among skilled workers decreased between 1998 and 2001 and increased over the period 2002–2006. The selectivity-corrected wage gap was more volatile, but generally decreased from 1998 to 2002, and increased between 2003 and 2006. The return effect followed exactly the same pattern as the selectivity-corrected wage gap. The endowment effect steadily decreased over the period 1998–2006. The gross wage gap among unskilled workers in Gaza decreased between 1998 and 2001 and increased between 2002 and 2006. The selectivity-corrected gap decreased between 1998 and 2000, and increased between 2001 and 2006. The endowment effect increased from 1998 to 2001, decreased in 2002 and increased again from 2003 to 2006. The returns effect decreased from 1998 to 1999, increased between 2000 and 2002, decreased in 2003 and increased again from 2004 to 2006. As shown in Tables 6 and 7, for most of the period studied, especially the years after the outbreak of the Intifada, the returns effect is the dominant component of the gross wage gap for unskilled workers in both the West Bank and Gaza. Furthermore, the returns effect follows almost exactly the same trends as the selectivity-corrected wage gap for unskilled workers, in both the West Bank and Gaza.21 Both of these results confirm our expectations regarding the effect on unskilled workers. Estimating the Wage Gap at Various Percentiles The simple OLS analysis has thus far focused exclusively on the average level of earnings differentials between the public and private sectors. It provides little information on the extent to which this differential varies across the wage distribution. Empirical evidence from many countries suggests that the pay gap, ln(1 + G), varies across the wage spectrum, and focusing on the mean could be misleading. Here, the dummy variable approach is used in a quantile regression model, where the estimates of β and δ are computed at various points along the wage distribution. A series of quantile regressions is estimated, taking the form22: Q𝜃 (ln wi |xi ) = xi 𝛽𝜃 + di 𝛿𝜃 , (6) 16 S. H. MIAARI Table 6. selectivity-corrected wage gap decomposition by skill group: West Bank, β* = βpublic. Skilled Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 G 0.0653*** (0.0246) 0.0288 (0.0233) 0.0294 (0.0229) 0.0065 (0.0241) −0.0732** (0.0342) −0.0267 (0.0307) 0.0770*** (0.0297) 0.1417*** (0.0280) 0.1946*** (0.0293) E 0.0763 (0.0620) 0.1283** (0.0593) 0.1586*** (0.0389) −0.0156 (0.0626) 0.0230 (0.0620) 0.0175 (0.0844) 0.0355 (0.0443) 0.0583 (0.0476) 0.1047 (0.0753) R 0.1668 (0.1169) −0.0340 (0.1260) −0.1622* (0.0970) 0.1777 (0.1446) 0.1514 (0.1425) −0.0003 (0.1717) 0.1840 (0.1275) 0.4427*** (0.1641) 0.2054 (0.1992) Unskilled Selection 0.011 Ĝ −0.085 0.092 −0.136 0.086 −0.067 −0.116 0.084 0.122 −0.247 −0.044 0.012 −0.027 0.032 0.000 0.161 0.135 0.070 G −0.1022*** (0.0151) −0.1728*** (0.0152) −0.1654*** (0.0141) −0.1116*** (0.0151) −0.0531** (0.0221) 0.0146 (0.0188) 0.1408*** (0.0171) 0.1537*** (0.0144) 0.2415*** (0.0162) E 0.0244 (0.0423) 0.0627 (0.0562) 0.0322 (0.0431) −0.0051 (0.0474) 0.0494 (0.0654) 0.0703 (0.0452) 0.1393*** (0.0416) 0.1147*** (0.0415) 0.1559*** (0.0597) R −0.2219** (0.0943) −0.3806*** (0.1076) −0.2308*** (0.0848) −0.2060** (0.0940) −0.0988 (0.1214) −0.1104 (0.0919) −0.1592* (0.0835) −0.1286 (0.0821) −0.0527 (0.1050) Selection −0.216 Ĝ 0.097 0.016 −0.210 0.022 −0.214 0.004 −0.116 −0.072 0.021 0.053 −0.018 0.094 0.060 0.069 0.092 0.186 0.051 source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: a skilled worker is defined as one with more than 12 years of schooling. Regressions are estimated using the Heckman selection correction method where the first step is a probit regression. G refers to the gross wage gap (or ln(1 + G)), e refers to the explained component of the wage gap (endowment effect), R refers to the unexplained (return effect) component of the wage gap. selection is the component of the wage gap attributed to self-selection into sector, and Ĝ is the selectivity-corrected gross wage gap. The dependent variable in the wage equations is the logarithm of hourly wage; the independent variables are age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, and district fixed effects. The selection equation includes as explanatory variables, age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, district fixed effects, number of jobholders, number of adults aged 70 or more in a given household, and locality’s share of public sector employees. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 per cent levels. DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 17 Table 7. selectivity-corrected Wage Gap Decomposition By skill Group: Gaza, β* = βpublic. Skilled Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 G 0.4620*** (0.0513) 0.4466*** (0.0433) 0.3236*** (0.0430) 0.2357*** (0.0427) 0.2492*** (0.0611) 0.3297*** (0.0486) 0.2091*** (0.0450) 0.4445*** (0.0435) 0.6790*** (0.0474) E 0.2317** (0.0954) 0.2588*** (0.0886) 0.2088*** (0.0521) 0.1411*** (0.0420) 0.0983** (0.0460) 0.1111* (0.0596) 0.0757** (0.0331) 0.0984** (0.0396) −0.0739 (0.0619) Unskilled R 0.6233 (0.4890) 0.3716 (0.3304) 0.8365** (0.3592) 0.0134 (0.3418) −0.8875* (0.5141) 0.3257 (0.3546) 0.5193 (0.3840) 0.6139*** (0.2236) 1.0955*** (0.2273) Selection 0.183 Ĝ 0.038 0.314 0.042 −0.053 0.377 0.509 −0.294 0.780 −0.567 −0.176 0.510 0.198 −0.013 0.012 0.401 −0.252 0.856 G 0.4094*** (0.0160) 0.4136*** (0.0143) 0.3883*** (0.0157) 0.3737*** (0.0188) 0.4722*** (0.0194) 0.4032*** (0.0153) 0.5188*** (0.0172) 0.7209*** (0.0150) 0.8574*** (0.0176) E 0.2115** (0.0988) 0.4284*** (0.0774) 0.3177*** (0.0721) 0.3595*** (0.0618) −0.2088*** (0.0645) 0.1448*** (0.0551) 0.1817*** (0.0659) 0.2293*** (0.0515) 0.3445*** (0.0580) R 0.0477 (0.1585) −0.1747 (0.1153) −0.1073 (0.1214) 0.1368 (0.1375) 0.7112*** (0.1211) 0.2179** (0.0954) 0.3304*** (0.1018) 0.4659*** (0.0870) 0.6376*** (0.1091) Selection −0.089 Ĝ 0.495 −0.020 0.436 0.087 0.310 −0.003 0.441 −0.069 0.571 0.043 0.404 0.038 0.483 0.052 0.671 0.136 0.729 source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: a skilled worker is defined as one with more than 12 years of schooling. Regressions are estimated using Heckman selection correction method where the first step is a probit regression. G refers to the gross wage gap (or ln(1 + G)), e refers to the explained component of the wage gap (endowment effect), R refers to the unexplained (return effect) component of the wage gap. selection is the component of the wage gap attributed to self-selection into sector, and Ĝ is the selectivity-corrected gross wage gap. The dependent variable in the wage equations is the logarithm of hourly wage; the independent variables are age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, and district fixed effects. The selection equation includes as explanatory variables, age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, district fixed effects, number of jobholders, number of adults aged 70 or more in a given household, and locality’s share of public sector employees. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 per cent levels. where 𝜃 is an arbitrary percentile between (0,1); Q𝜃 (ln wi |xi ) is the ‘𝜃th’ quantile function of wages conditional on observed characteristics or attributes specified by xi; 𝛽𝜃 is the vector specifying the ‘returns’ or ‘effects’ of individual characteristics; and 𝛿𝜃 captures the unexplained gap of log earnings, all at the 𝜃th quantile. Within the QR framework, for any given 𝜃 and a sample size of n, 𝛽𝜃 is derived as the argmin to n−1 n ∑ 𝜇𝜃 (ln wi − xi 𝛽𝜃 − di 𝛿𝜃 ), (7) i=1 where μθ is the ‘check’ function and is defined as μθ = θɛ if ɛ ≥ 0, or μθ = (θ - 1)ɛ if ɛ < 0. ɛ is the ‘error’ term analogous to the OLS specification. The QR estimates of β at any given quantile can be interpreted as the ‘returns’ to the attributes if Qθ(wi|xi) is assumed to be linear, (or a linear approximation). Moreover, to ensure the results are not driven by selection bias, we estimate the QR specifications using the Heckman selection correction method where the first step is a probit regression. The usefulness of this technique can be seen from Table 8, which compares the OLS and quantile regression, (QR), estimates of the dummy variable, or unexplained variation, (or impact), of working in the public sector. While the OLS estimates only give information near the median or 50th percentile of the wage distribution, the QR technique also provides estimates at various points along the wage distribution. Looking at the pay differential across the wage distribution, (Table 8), suggests a distinct trend over time: the wage premium (penalty) for the public sector varies across the distribution, being higher, (lower), at the lowest end of the wage distribution and decreasing, (increasing), along the wage distribution. It becomes negative at the top percentiles. By comparison, Azam and Prakash (2015) found 18 S. H. MIAARI Table 8. selectivity-corrected quantile regression results. Quantile Regression wage differentials at various percentiles West Bank males Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 OLS Wage Differential −0.0544*** (0.0137) −0.1028*** (0.0139) −0.0965*** (0.0128) −0.0341** (0.0135) −0.0296 (0.0201) 0.0207 (0.0164) 0.0883*** (0.0148) 0.1252*** (0.0133) 0.1944*** (0.0154) 5th 0.1358 (0.1355) 0.1602 (0.1653) 0.5629*** (0.1644) 0.1463 (0.1863) 0.4545* (0.2375) 0.2289 (0.1906) 0.0082 (0.2350) 0.2374 (0.1547) 0.3370* (0.1820) 20th 0.0838* (0.0503) −0.0106 (0.0612) 0.2565*** (0.0563) 0.2145*** (0.0722) 0.4999*** (0.1218) 0.2553** (0.1216) 0.0372 (0.0884) 0.2318** (0.1004) 0.3497*** (0.0937) 50th −0.0284 (0.0647) 0.0231 (0.0552) −0.0260 (0.0403) 0.0771 (0.0784) 0.4361*** (0.0874) 0.2409*** (0.0591) 0.0892* (0.0529) 0.1086 (0.0749) 0.2833*** (0.0831) Gaza males 75th −0.0825 (0.0865) −0.1090** (0.0468) −0.1392*** (0.0484) −0.1280 (0.1144) 0.0799 (0.0874) 0.0662 (0.0657) −0.0049 (0.0489) 0.0225 (0.0775) 0.1295 (0.0797) 95th −0.0621 (0.1712) −0.5158*** (0.1662) −0.4870*** (0.0865) −0.2939** (0.1200) −0.2831* (0.1518) −0.2039 (0.1438) 0.1334 (0.1788) −0.0349 (0.1174) −0.1802 (0.1132) OLS Wage Differential 0.2655*** (0.0187) 0.2269*** (0.0187) 0.2380*** (0.0173) 0.2367*** (0.0176) 0.2742*** (0.0233) 0.2604*** (0.0187) 0.3005*** (0.0196) 0.4266*** (0.0180) 0.5515*** (0.0210) 5th 0.0008 (0.4103) 0.0350 (0.2199) 0.0687 (0.2360) 0.6550*** (0.1987) 1.0119* (0.6138) 0.4979** (0.2262) 0.2681 (0.1978) 0.2904* (0.1705) 0.4365** (0.1893) 20th 0.3812** (0.1713) 0.1630 (0.1083) −0.0392 (0.1190) 0.4137*** (0.1509) 0.9175*** (0.2148) 0.3197** (0.1364) 0.3541** (0.1578) 0.5824*** (0.0836) 0.5400*** (0.1058) 50th 0.2617** (0.1101) −0.0521 (0.0976) −0.1375 (0.1233) 0.4636*** (0.1154) 0.7921*** (0.1155) 0.3769*** (0.0979) 0.5604*** (0.0900) 0.7133*** (0.0708) 0.7678*** (0.0872) 75th −0.1585 (0.1432) −0.2419*** (0.0851) −0.2434* (0.1324) 0.3330** (0.1638) 0.7881*** (0.0796) 0.4816*** (0.1063) 0.5677*** (0.1148) 0.6733*** (0.0812) 0.7785*** (0.1112) 95th −0.0759 (0.3757) −0.1279 (0.2068) −0.0971 (0.1965) 0.5337** (0.2654) 0.4774* (0.2525) 0.3170* (0.1741) 0.2195 (0.2266) 0.3793*** (0.1265) 0.4352** (0.1835) source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: Regressions are estimated using the Heckman selection correction method where the first step is a probit regression. The dependent variable in the wage equations is the logarithm of hourly wage; the independent variables are age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, district fixed effects and a sector dummy variable (that takes on the value 1 if the worker is employed in the public sector, and 0 if employed in the private sector). The selection equation includes as explanatory variables, age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, district fixed effects, number of jobholders, number of adults aged 70 or more in a given household, and locality’s share of public sector employees. standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 per cent levels. DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 19 this to be positive for the entire wage distribution in India, but still smaller at the top quantiles, while Saha, Roy, and Kar (2014) found the premium to be positive at the 25th quantile and negative at the 50th and 75th quantiles. Christofides and Michael (2013), found that the wage gap is negatively related to income quantiles. West Bank workers in the lowest 5th percentile earn significant wage premiums in the public sector compared to their private sector counterparts. West Bank public sector workers in the 20th percentile also had a positive premium throughout the entire observed period, as did public sector workers at the median, (50th percentile), for the period 2001–2006. For the 75th percentile the premium was negative until 2001, and for the 95th percentile it was negative throughout 1998–2006 (except for 2004). Between 1998 and 2000, the wage gap becomes more negative for the higher percentiles, and more positive for the lower percentiles. Both of these trends reverse between 2000 and 2001. The wage premium increased for all groups, except for the 95th percentile, between 2001 and 2002, becoming less negative for high wage earners and more positive for those on lower wages. There was a decrease in the gap between 2003 and 2004, and then another increase during the period 2005–2006. For workers of the 95th percentile, the gap increased between 2001 and 2004 and decreased in the period 2005–2006. In Gaza, public sector workers in the 5th, 20th and 50th percentiles have a positive premium in 1998, while the others have a negative one. Between 1998 and 2000, the wage gap decreases for all groups except the 5th percentile, for whom in increases. All groups’ wage gaps rapidly rise in 2001, and for all except the 95th percentile, this trend continues to 2002. For all groups, there is another decrease in 2003, and an increase in 2004–2006. In both the West Bank and Gaza, the wage gap sharply increased for lower wage workers during the years of the Intifada. This difference in the public sector premium, between high and low earning workers, mirrors the difference between high and low skilled workers reported in Results section. Conclusion Currently, Palestinian public sector salaries absorb at least 85% of net revenues, crowding out virtually all other expenditure. The past five years have seen a series of wage increases in the public sector with the stated intention of bringing public sector salaries up to par with the private sector. This paper has measured the public–private wage differential in the West Bank and Gaza, and described its dynamics before and during the second Intifada using data from the PLFS of the PCBS. The paper is the first systematic analysis of the public–private wage gap in the context of the economic costs of political instability. While the public sector has become increasingly attractive to workers, the private sector continues to be buffeted by exogenous shocks and beset by considerable uncertainty. Given that the public sector was seen as a ‘buffer’ to absorb private sector job losses, due to increased closures and movement restrictions following the second Intifada, employment in it expanded as the political and economic situation worsened. Given the inseparability, and thus complexity, of the political and economic challenges facing the PA, and the need for objective analysis to inform policy, this paper offers an interpretation of the wage gap phenomenon in terms of the changing demographic composition of the Palestinian workforce over the study period. The paper has used Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition to estimate the explained and unexplained components of the wage gap. The estimates for West Bank workers suggest that in the earlier years of the analysis, particularly in the pre-Intifada period, the public sector suffered a penalty in (log) hourly wages, but this penalty disappeared, and then reversed over time. In 1999, the public–private log wage differential was estimated at –0.10. However, from 2003 a clear public sector premium emerges, which rises significantly in 2005, just prior to the Palestine national elections. Among Gaza Strip workers, the public sector pay premium declined between 1998 and 1999, and then increased between 2000 and 2006. Moreover, most of the increase in the wage gap, in both the West Bank and Gaza, in the post-Intifada period stems from an increase in the ‘returns’ to skills composition in the public sector (unexplained effect), rather than a change in the skills composition of public sector workers, (explained effect). 20 S. H. MIAARI The massive influx of Palestinians, who had previously worked in the Israeli private sector before the second Intifada, into the PA local private sector, and a fall in local economic activity in the West Bank and Gaza, simultaneously reduced the demand for, and increased the supply of, Palestinian unskilled workers. Consequently, the wage for private sector employees decreased over the Intifada period. Moreover, public sector wages increased several times during the study period. The average PA wage increased at an annual rate of 3.5% during the years 2000–2003 (World Bank 2006b). Furthermore, public sector wages were further increased in the period 2004–2005, when the PA implemented its Civil Service Law (World Bank 2006b) and again in 2006. Consequently, although in the pre-Intifada period the wage gap between the public and private sectors narrowed, it has widened in the post-Intifada period. Looking at the pay differential in the West Bank and Gaza across the wage distribution suggests a distinct trend over time: the wage premium, (penalty), for the public sector varies across the distribution, being higher, (lower), at the lowest end of the wage distribution and decreasing, (increasing), along the wage distribution. It becomes negative at the top percentiles. Over time, the lower quantiles of West Bank wage earners have continued to earn a significant (log) wage premium, and this has increased after the outbreak of the Intifada. On the other hand, those in the very top income percentiles, (95th), continue to face a wage penalty, which has attenuated over time. In Gaza, especially after the outbreak of the Intifada, the wage premium increased for both low and high wage earners in the public sector. Comparing 2000 to 2006, estimates indicate that public sector workers in the West Bank and Gaza in all percentiles showed a steady increase in the wage premium. Besides the fiscal burden of providing the public sector with wage premiums vis-à-vis the private sector and the equity issues this raises, this trend is also worrying for other reasons. In an environment of high unemployment, particularly among the young, this trend creates an incentive for job seekers to ‘sit it out’ and wait for a secure job in the public sector rather than become absorbed in a highly fragmented and uncertain private sector. The results of this paper might suggest that the PA was using the expansion of the public sector and the wage increases to maintain its popular support. Further research is needed to test this hypothesis. Another interesting hypothesis is that security sector jobs are used to ‘buy out’ various armed groups or potential dissidents. Notes 1. Source: International Monetary Fund data files. 2. The Palestinian political and economic situation is unique in many ways, and international experience should be interpreted with care when applied to the Palestinian context. 3. This is contrary to Leping (2005, 2006). Some of this difference can be attributed to the different timeframe for the data of these papers, which is 2000 and 1989–2005, respectively, compared to 2008 for Christofides and Michael (2013). We also know from Leping (2006) that the negative public sector premium became less negative with time. 4. Wage employment represents approximately 55% of total employment in the West Bank, and two-thirds of total employment in Gaza, percentages that have remained fairly stable since the outbreak of the Intifada. The other three types of employment are ‘employer’, representing approximately 5% of total employment in the West Bank and 3% in Gaza; ‘self-employed,’ amounting to roughly 28% in the West Bank and 23 percent in Gaza; and ‘unpaid family member,’ which accounts for approximately 11% of employment in the West Bank and 9% in Gaza. These three groups were not asked about their wages in the PLFS. 5. Including Palestinians workers in Israel would give a confused picture of the public-private wage gap in the Palestinian local market, because Palestinian workers in Israel are generally paid more than those employed in the Palestinian local market. 6. The female labour force participation rate in 1998–2006 averaged 14.4% for females from the West Bank and 8.4% for females from Gaza. 7. The PLFS questionnaire on hours worked asks, ‘How many hours did the household member work in all jobs last week?’ This number was multiplied by 4.35 weeks per month, and then divided by the number of reported workdays in the month to calculate hours worked per day. 8. Thereby removing the most extreme responses, which in some cases are simply the results of incorrect data entry. 9. According to the World Bank report in 2006a ‘West Bank and Gaza Update’: ‘Between Q3 of 2000 and Q4 of 2000, the number of wage employees working in the private sector in the West Bank fell by 28,500; by Q2 of 2002, a further 27,900 West Bank private sector wage employees were no longer working, a decline of 48% from the last quarter DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 21 prior to the Intifada, when 117,600 workers enjoyed regular wage employment. In Gaza, the reduction was more sudden: Whereas 43,000 Gazans held regular wage employment in Q3 of 2000, that number fell to 22,600 in Q4 of 2000; a further 2900 were without regular private sector wage jobs by Q3 of 2002, a decline of 59%.’. According to the same report, public sector employment increased by 13% through 2007–2013, making it likely that for the period studied in this paper, the public sector was also not very large by international standards. For instance, the UNSCO database shows that the number of comprehensive closure days imposed in the West Bank increased from 53 in 1998 to 260 in 2006; and in Gaza from 28 days to 77 days during the same period. According to the World Bank report in May 2003, ‘The negative impact on domestic employment of job losses in Israel was aggravated by the difficulties in conducting business within the West Bank and Gaza: Internal closures and curfews are attended by significant transaction costs, disruption in production cycles, losses of perishable output, and lower economies of scale. Regional variations in unemployment and labor participation between the West Bank and Gaza are significant. By Q3/2002, 51,000 of the 327,000 eve-of-intifada private sector jobs had been lost in the West Bank (16%), and 54,000 of 164,000 in Gaza (33%).’. Miaari and Sauer (2011) document the large and statistically significant negative effects of the Israeli-Palestinian conflict on Palestinian employment rates in Israel and mean monthly earnings, regardless of work location, (Israel or the West Bank and Gaza), following the outbreak of the Intifada. External closures consist of restrictions on the movement of Palestinians and Palestinian goods between the West Bank, Gaza, and Israel (as well as third countries). Internal closures consist of restrictions on the movement of Palestinians within the territories. Controlling for occupational affiliation in the wage regressions would eliminate inter-occupational wage gaps. Adding and subtracting the term (X̄ 1 − X̄ 0 )� 𝛽̂jin Equation (3). We also use (a) pooled regression non-discriminatory wage coefficients because the source of the wage gap might stem from both positive discrimination of one sector and negative discrimination of the other, and the two often occur together (Jann 2008). In our case, the positive ‘discrimination’ is the extra funds allocated towards public sector employment, while the negative one is the effects of the second Intifada on the private sector. See Reimers (1983) and Neuman and Oaxaca (2004a) for more details on choosing the ‘correct’ selectivity decomposition. A greater number of jobholders in the same household increases the probability of joining the private sector, without affecting the worker’s wage. A higher share of public sector employees in a locality facilitates access to jobs in the public sector. The number of Palestinian labourers in Israel falls from a high of 146,000 just prior to the start of the uprising, (116,000 from the West Bank and 30,000 from Gaza), to around 50,000 in Q4 of 2004; since then, the number of Palestinian workers in Israel and in the settlements has been relatively stable, fluctuating with the extent of closure imposed by Israel. Note that there is also great similarity between the trends of the returns effect and those of the selectivity-corrected wage gap for skilled workers. See Bassett snd Koenker (1978; 1982) for details on quantile regressions. Acknowledgements I am deeply grateful to the Palestinian Central Bureau of Statistics for providing the Palestinian Labour Force Survey data; I owe special thanks to Michael Beenstock, Massimiliano Cali, Esteban Klor, Hani Mansour, Daniele Paserman, Robert Sauer, Eytan Sheshinski, Avichai Snir, Asaf Zussman, and Noam Zussman for their helpful suggestions and comments. Disclosure statement No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author. References Adamchik, V. A., and A. S. Bedi. 2000. “Wage Differentials between the Public and the Private Sectors: Evidence from an Economy in Transition.” Labour Economics 7 (2): 203–224. Aslam, M., and G. Kingdon. 2009. “Public–Private Sector Segmentation in the Pakistani Labour Market.” Journal of Asian Economics 20 (1): 34–49. Azam, M., and N. Prakash. 2015. “A Distributional Analysis of Public-Private Wage Differentials in India.” Labour 29 (4): 394–414. Bargain, O., & B. Melly (2008). Public Sector Pay Gap in France: New Evidence Using Panel Data. SSRN 1136232. Bassett, G., and R. Koenker. 1978. “Regression Quantile.” Econometrica 46: 33–50. 22 S. H. MIAARI Bassett, G., and R. Koenker. 1982. “An Empirical Quantile Function for Linear Models with I.I.D Errors.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 77: 407–415. Blinder, A. S. 1973. “Wage Differential: Reduced Form and Structural Variables.” The Journal of Human Resources 8: 436–455. Cai, L., and A. Y. Liu. 2011. “Public-Private Sector Wage Gap in Australia: Variation along the Distribution.” British Journal of Industrial Relations 49 (2): 362–390. Calì, M., and S. H. Miaari. 2018. “The Labor Market Impact of Mobility Restrictions: Evidence from the West Bank.” Labour Economics 51: 136–151. Carlo, D. A., C. Lucifora, & F. Origo. 2005. Public Sector Pay and Regional Competitiveness: A First Look at Regional PublicPrivate Wage Differentials in Italy (No. 1828). Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). Christofides, L. N., and M. Michael. 2013. “Exploring the Public-Private Sector Wage Gap in European Countries.” IZA Journal of European Labor Studies 2 (1): 1–53. Depalo, D., & R. Giordano. 2011. “The Public-Private Pay Gap: A Robust Quantile Approach.” Bank of Italy Temi di Discussione (Working Paper) No, 824. Disney, R., and A. Gosling. 1998. “Does It Pay to Work in the Public Sector?” Fiscal Studies 19 (4): 347–374. Dustmann, C and A. Van Soest. 1998. “Public and Private Sector Wages of Male Workers in Germany”. European Economic Review 42 (8): 1417–1441. Emilio, D., V. Ponczek, and F. Botelho. 2012. “Evaluating the Wage Differential between Public and Private Sectors in Brazil.” Revista De Economia Política 32 (1): 72–86. Foley, P., and F. O’Callaghan. 2011. “Investigating the Public-Private Wage Gap in Ireland Using Data from the National Employment Survey 2007.” Journal of the Statistical and Social Inquiry Society of Ireland 39: 23–52A. Gardeazabal, J., and A. Ugidos. 2004. “More on Identification in Detailed Wage Decompositions.” Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (4): 1034–1036. Giordano, R., D. Depalo, M. C. Pereira, B. Eugène, E. Papapetrou, J. J. Perez, A. Aaaa, and M. Roter. 2011. “The Public Sector Pay Gap in a Selection of Euro Area Countries.” Working Paper Series 1406, European Central Bank. Glinskaya, Elena, and Michael Lokshin. 2005. Wage Differential between the Public and Private Sectors in India. Mimeo. Washington, DC: World Bank. Heckman, James J. 1979. “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error.” Econometrica 47 (1): 153–162. Horrace, W. C., and R. L. Oaxaca. 2001. “Inter-Industry Wage Differentials and the Gender Wage Gap: An Identification Problem.” ILR Review 54 (3): 611–618. Hyder, A. 2002. “Public-Private Wage Differentials in Pakistan.” The Bangladesh Development Studies 28 (4): 79–93. Hyder, A., and B. Reilly. 2005. “The Public and Private Sector Pay Gap in Pakistan: A Quantile Regression Analysis.” The Pakistan Development Review 271–306. Jann, B. 2008. “The Blinder-Oaxaca Decomposition for Linear Regression Models.” The Stata Journal 8 (4): 453–479. Jones, F. L. 1983. “On Decomposing the Wage Gap: A Critical Comment on Blinder's Method.” The Journal of Human Resources 18 (1): 126–130. Jones, F. L., and J. Kelley. 1984. “Decomposing Differences between Groups: A Cautionary Note on Measuring Discrimination.” Sociological Methods & Research 12 (3): 323–343. Lausev, J. 2014. “What has 20 years of public–private pay gap literature told us? Eastern European transitioning vs. developed economies.” Journal of Economic Surveys 28 (3): 516–550. Leping, K. O. 2005. Public-Private Sector Wage Differential in Estonia: Evidence from Quantile Regression. University of Tartu Faculty of Economics and Business Administration Working Paper, (39). Leping, K. O. 2006. “Evolution of the Public–Private Sector Wage Differential during Transition in Estonia.” Post-Communist Economies 18 (4): 419–436. Lokshin, M., and B. Javanovic. 2003. “Public-Private Sector Employment Choice and Wage Differential in Yugoslavia.” Mimeo. Washington, DC: World Bank. Lucifora, C. and D. Meurs (2004), “The Public Sector Pay Gap in France, Great Britain, and Italy.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 1041. Maczulskij, T. 2008. “Public-Private Wage Differentials for Males: Evidence from Finland.” University of Jyväskylä, School of Business and Economics, Working Paper. Miaari, S. H., and R. M. Sauer. 2011. “The Labor Market Costs of Conflict: Closures, Foreign Workers, and Palestinian Employment and Earnings.” Review of Economics of the Household 9: 129–148. Mizala, A., P. Romaguera, and S. Gallegos. 2011. “Public–Private Wage Gap in Latin America (1992–2007): A Matching Approach.” Labour Economics 18: S115–S131. Naser, Z. M. 2000. “Earnings Differential between Public and Private Sectors in Pakistan.” Pakistan Development Review 39 (2): 111–130. Neuman, Shoshana, and Ronald L. Oaxaca. 2004a. “Wage Decompositions with Selectivity-Corrected Wage Equations: A Methodological Note.” The Journal of Economic Inequality 2 (1): 3–10. Neumark, D. 1988. “Employers’ Discriminatory Behavior and the Estimation of Wage Discrimination.” The Journal of Human Resources 23: 279–295. Nielsen, H. S. 2000. “Wage Discrimination in Zambia: An Extension of the Oaxaca-Blinder Decomposition.” Applied Economics Letters 7 (6): 405–408. DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 23 Oaxaca, Ronald L. 1973. “Male-Female Wage Differential in the Urban Labor Market.” International Economic Review 14 (3): 693–709. Oaxaca, Ronald L., and Michael R. Ransom. 1994. “On Discrimination and the Decomposition of Wage Differentials.” Journal of Econometrics 61 (1): 5–21. Oaxaca, R. L., and M. R. Ransom. 1999. “Identification in Detailed Wage Decompositions.” Review of Economics and Statistics 81 (1): 154–157. Panizza, U., and C. Z. W. Qiang. 2005. “Public–Private Wage Differential and Gender Gap in Latin America: Spoiled Bureaucrats and Exploited Women?” The Journal of Socio-Economics 34 (6): 810–833. Papapetrou, E. 2006. “The Public-Private Sector Pay Differential in Greece.” Public Finance Review 34 (4): 450–473. Polavieja, J. G. 2005. “Task Specificity and the Gender Wage Gap: Theoretical Considerations and Empirical Analysis of the Spanish Survey on Wage Structure.” European Sociological Review 21 (2): 165–181. Poterba, J.M., K.S. Rueben. 1994. “The Distribution of Public Sector Wage Premia: New Evidence Using Quantile Regression Methods”. NBER Working Paper No. 4734 (May). Reimers, Cordelia W. 1983. “Labor Market Discrimination against Hispanic and Black Men.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 65 (4): 570–579. Saha, S., P. Roy, and S. Kar. 2014. “Public and Private Sector Jobs, Unreported Income and Consumption Gap in India: Evidence from Micro-Data.” The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 29: 285–300. Nielsen, H. S., and M. Rosholm. 2001. “The Public-Private Sector Wage Gap in Zambia in the 1990s: A Quantile Regression Approach.” Empirical Economics 26: 169–182. Suits, D. B. 1984. “Dummy Variables: Mechanics V. Interpretation.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 66: 177–180. Terrell, K. 1993. “Public-Private Wage Differentials in Haiti Do Public Servants Earn a Rent?” Journal of Development Economics 42 (2): 293–314. Voinea, L., and F. Mihaescu. 2012. “A Contribution to the Public–Private Wage Inequality Debate.” Economics of Transition 20 (2): 315–337. World Bank. 2003. “Twenty-Seven Months: Intifada, Closures, and Palestinian Economic Crisis: An Assessment”, May. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 2016. “Public Expenditure Review of the Palestinian Authority. Towards Enhanced Public Finance Management and Improved Fiscal Sustainability.” Washington, D.C: World Bank. World Bank. 2006a. West Bank and Gaza Update, A Quarterly Publication of the West Bank and Gaza Office, April. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 2006b. West Bank and Gaza Public Expenditure Review: From Crisis to Fiscal Independence. Yun, M. S. 2005. “A Simple Solution to the Identification Problem in Detailed Wage Decompositions.” Economic Inquiry 43: 766–772. 24 S. H. MIAARI Appendix 1. Table A1. Decomposing the wage differential over time: β* = βpooled. West Bank males Year 1998 G 0.0664*** (0.0129) 0.0336*** (0.0128) 0.0277** (0.0120) 0.0318** (0.0125) 0.0868*** (0.0186) 0.1490*** (0.0160) 0.2776*** (0.0154) 0.2884*** (0.0133) 0.3296*** (0.0141) 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 E 0.1208*** (0.0121) 0.1364*** (0.0124) 0.1241*** (0.0116) 0.0659*** (0.0118) 0.1164*** (0.0179) 0.1283*** (0.0149) 0.1893*** (0.0142) 0.1632*** (0.0122) 0.1351*** (0.0133) Gaza males R –0.0544*** (0.0137) –0.1028*** (0.0139) –0.0965*** (0.0128) –0.0341** (0.0134) –0.0296 (0.0199) 0.0207 (0.0161) 0.0883*** (0.0146) 0.1252*** (0.0131) 0.1944*** (0.0152) G 0.5483*** (0.0156) 0.5248*** (0.0142) 0.4911*** (0.0156) 0.4333*** (0.0186) 0.5410*** (0.0205) 0.5049*** (0.0154) 0.5832*** (0.0182) 0.7902*** (0.0158) 0.9182*** (0.0174) E 0.2828*** (0.0170) 0.2979*** (0.0165) 0.2531*** (0.0153) 0.1966*** (0.0150) 0.2669*** (0.0187) 0.2445*** (0.0156) 0.2826*** (0.0171) 0.3636*** (0.0156) 0.3667*** (0.0166) R 0.2655*** (0.0186) 0.2269*** (0.0186) 0.2380*** (0.0171) 0.2367*** (0.0171) 0.2742*** (0.0225) 0.2604*** (0.0185) 0.3005*** (0.0188) 0.4266*** (0.0173) 0.5515*** (0.0204) source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: The dependent variable in the wage equations is the logarithm of hourly wage; the independent variables are: age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, and district fixed effects. G refers to the gross wage gap (or ln(1+G)), e refers to the explained component of the wage gap (endowment effect), and R refers to the unexplained (return effect) component of the wage gap. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels. Table A2. selectivity-corrected wage gap decomposition: β* = βpooled. West Bank males Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 G 0.0656*** (0.0129) 0.0291** (0.0128) 0.0277** (0.0120) 0.0318** (0.0125) 0.0868*** (0.0186) 0.1490*** (0.0160) 0.2776*** (0.0154) 0.2884*** (0.0133) 0.3296*** (0.0141) E 0.1100*** (0.0259) 0.1139*** (0.0279) 0.0895*** (0.0239) 0.0534* (0.0285) –0.0350 (0.0371) 0.0547* (0.0294) 0.1959*** (0.0267) 0.1625*** (0.0249) 0.1137*** (0.0307) R –0.0694 (0.0581) –0.1531** (0.0597) –0.0523 (0.0516) –0.0308 (0.0620) 0.2617*** (0.0800) 0.1491** (0.0667) 0.0645 (0.0624) 0.0671 (0.0594) 0.1583** (0.0728) Gaza males Selection 0.025 Ĝ 0.041 0.068 –0.039 –0.009 0.037 0.009 0.023 –0.140 0.227 –0.055 0.204 0.017 0.260 0.059 0.230 0.058 0.272 G 0.5483*** (0.0156) 0.5248*** (0.0142) 0.4911*** (0.0156) 0.4333*** (0.0186) 0.5410*** (0.0205) 0.5049*** (0.0154) 0.5832*** (0.0182) 0.7902*** (0.0158) 0.9182*** (0.0174) E 0.3304*** (0.0675) 0.4475*** (0.0613) 0.4020*** (0.0555) 0.0533 (0.0395) –0.0399 (0.0695) 0.1524*** (0.0422) 0.1889*** (0.0442) 0.3090*** (0.0406) 0.3188*** (0.0456) R 0.1202 (0.1299) –0.0538 (0.1092) –0.0308 (0.1244) 0.6868*** (0.1452) 0.7800*** (0.1846) 0.4254*** (0.0976) 0.4937*** (0.1072) 0.5933*** (0.0870) 0.7565*** (0.1279) Selection 0.098 Ĝ 0.451 0.131 0.394 0.120 0.371 –0.307 0.740 –0.199 0.740 –0.073 0.578 –0.099 0.683 –0.112 0.902 –0.157 1.075 source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: Regressions are estimated using the Heckman selection correction method where the first step is a probit regression. G refers to the gross wage gap (or ln(1+G)), e refers to the explained component of the wage gap (endowment effect), R refers to the unexplained (return effect) component of the wage gap. selection is the component of the wage gap attributed to self-selection into sector, and Ĝ is the selectivity-corrected gross wage gap. The dependent variable in the wage equations is the logarithm of hourly wage; the independent variables are age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, and district fixed effects. The selection equation includes as explanatory variables , age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, district fixed effects, number of jobholders, number of adults aged 70 or more in a given household, and locality's share of public sector employees. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels. DEFENCE AND PEACE ECONOMICS 25 Table A3. selectivity-corrected wage gap decomposition by skill group: West Bank, β* = βpooled. West Bank males Skilled Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 G 0.0653*** (0.0244) 0.0288 (0.0230) 0.0294 (0.0227) 0.0065 (0.0237) –0.0732** (0.0336) –0.0267 (0.0303) 0.0770*** (0.0293) 0.1417*** (0.0277) 0.1946*** (0.0290) E 0.0389 (0.0377) 0.0954** (0.0403) 0.1222*** (0.0307) 0.1081** (0.0440) 0.0690 (0.0469) 0.0786* (0.0439) 0.0790** (0.0379) 0.1582*** (0.0353) 0.0900* (0.0468) R 0.2041* (0.1143) –0.0012 (0.1212) –0.1257 (0.1079) 0.0540 (0.1544) 0.1053 (0.1417) –0.0613 (0.1520) 0.1405 (0.1533) 0.3429** (0.1528) 0.2201 (0.1988) Unskilled Selection 0.011 Ĝ –0.085 0.092 –0.136 0.086 –0.067 –0.116 0.084 0.122 –0.247 –0.044 0.012 –0.027 0.032 0.000 0.161 0.135 0.070 G –0.1022*** (0.0151) –0.1728*** (0.0151) –0.1654*** (0.0140) –0.1116*** (0.0150) –0.0531** (0.0219) 0.0146 (0.0187) 0.1408*** (0.0170) 0.1537*** (0.0143) 0.2415*** (0.0161) E –0.0071 (0.0250) 0.0096 (0.0310) –0.0949*** (0.0251) –0.0943*** (0.0282) –0.2381*** (0.0422) –0.1217*** (0.0299) 0.0286 (0.0282) –0.0382 (0.0257) –0.0559* (0.0330) SelecR tion –0.1905*** –0.216 (0.0680) –0.3275*** 0.016 (0.0773) –0.1036* 0.022 (0.0620) –0.1168 0.004 (0.0714) 0.1887* –0.072 (0.1040) 0.0815 0.053 (0.0728) –0.0485 0.094 (0.0736) 0.0243 0.069 (0.0638) 0.1592** 0.186 (0.0769) Ĝ 0.097 –0.210 –0.214 –0.116 0.021 –0.018 0.060 0.092 0.051 source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: a skilled worker is defined as one with more than 12 years of schooling. Regressions are estimated using the Heckman selection correction method where the first step is a probit regression. G refers to the gross wage gap (or ln(1+G)), e refers to the explained component of the wage gap (endowment effect), R refers to the unexplained (return effect) component of the wage gap. selection is the component of the wage gap attributed to self-selection into sector, and Ĝ is the selectivity-corrected gross wage gap. The dependent variable in the wage equations is the logarithm of hourly wage; the independent variables are age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, and district fixed effects. The selection equation includes as explanatory variables , age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, district fixed effects, number of jobholders, number of adults aged 70 or more in a given household, and locality's share of public sector employees. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels. 26 S. H. MIAARI Table A4. selectivity-corrected wage gap decomposition by skill group: Gaza, β* = βpooled. Gaza males Skilled Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 G 0.4620*** (0.0499) 0.4466*** (0.0423) 0.3236*** (0.0420) 0.2357*** (0.0415) 0.2492*** (0.0597) 0.3297*** (0.0470) 0.2091*** (0.0439) 0.4445*** (0.0428) 0.6790*** (0.0464) E 0.2710*** (0.0906) 0.2903*** (0.0679) 0.1817*** (0.0447) 0.1025** (0.0400) 0.1348*** (0.0508) 0.1590*** (0.0490) 0.0817*** (0.0286) 0.1497*** (0.0351) 0.1288*** (0.0453) R 0.5839 (0.5121) 0.3401 (0.3801) 0.8636** (0.3473) 0.0520 (0.3834) –0.9240* (0.4898) 0.2777 (0.3444) 0.5134 (0.3643) 0.5626*** (0.1852) 0.8928*** (0.2258) Unskilled Selection 0.183 Ĝ 0.038 0.314 0.042 –0.053 0.377 0.509 –0.294 0.780 –0.567 –0.176 0.510 0.198 –0.013 0.012 0.401 –0.252 0.856 G 0.4094*** (0.0159) 0.4136*** (0.0142) 0.3883*** (0.0156) 0.3737*** (0.0186) 0.4722*** (0.0192) 0.4032*** (0.0152) 0.5188*** (0.0171) 0.7209*** (0.0149) 0.8574*** (0.0175) E 0.1997*** (0.0759) 0.3391*** (0.0698) 0.2675*** (0.0639) 0.0036 (0.0481) –0.0461 (0.0866) 0.1273*** (0.0471) 0.1417*** (0.0464) 0.2960*** (0.0502) 0.3540*** (0.0542) R 0.0595 (0.1435) –0.0854 (0.1225) –0.0571 (0.1356) 0.4926*** (0.1370) 0.5485*** (0.1716) 0.2355** (0.1059) 0.3703*** (0.0969) 0.3993*** (0.1013) 0.6281*** (0.1243) Selection –0.089 Ĝ 0.495 –0.020 0.436 0.087 0.310 –0.003 0.441 –0.069 0.571 0.043 0.404 0.038 0.483 0.052 0.671 0.136 0.729 source: author calculations using Palestinian Labor force surveys (PLfs) of the Palestinian central Bureau of statistics (PcBs), 1998–2006. note: a skilled worker is defined as one with more than 12 years of schooling. Regressions are estimated using the Heckman selection correction method where the first step is a probit regression. G refers to the gross wage gap (or ln(1+G)), e refers to the explained component of the wage gap (endowment effect), R refers to the unexplained (return effect) component of the wage gap. selection is the component of the wage gap attributed to self-selection into sector, and Ĝ is the selectivity-corrected gross wage gap. The dependent variable in the wage equations is the logarithm of hourly wage; the independent variables are age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, and district fixed effects. The selection equation includes as explanatory variables , age, age squared, years of schooling, tenure, marital status, full-time employment; urban area/refugee camp residence, occupational dummies, district fixed effects, number of jobholders, number of adults aged 70 or more in a given household, and locality's share of public sector employees. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The symbols *, **, *** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels.