[go: up one dir, main page]

Academia.eduAcademia.edu
NIH Public Access Author Manuscript J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. NIH-PA Author Manuscript Published in final edited form as: J Neurosci Psychol Econ. 2013 September 1; 6(3): 151–166. Can Personality Type Explain Heterogeneity in Probability Distortions? C. Monica Capra, Department of Economics and Center for Neuropolicy, Emory University Bing Jiang, Department of Economics and Business, Virginia Military Institute Jan B. Engelmann, and Laboratory for Social and Neural Systems Research, Department of Economics, University of Zurich, Switzerland NIH-PA Author Manuscript Gregory S. Berns Department of Economics and Center for Neuropolicy, Emory University Abstract There are two regularities we have learned from experimental studies of choice under risk. The first is that the majority of people weigh objective probabilities non-linearly. The second regularity, although less commonly acknowledged, is that there is a large amount of heterogeneity in how people distort probabilities. Despite of this, little effort has been made to identify the source of heterogeneity. In this paper, we explore the possibility that personality type is linked to probability distortions. Using validated psychological questionnaires, we clustered participants into distinct personality types: motivated, impulsive, and affective. We found that the motivated viewed gambling more attractive, whereas the impulsive were the most capable of discriminating non-extreme probabilities. Our results suggest that the observed heterogeneity in probability distortions may be explained by personality profiles, which can be elicited though standard psychological questionnaires. Keywords NIH-PA Author Manuscript choice under risk; personality; experiments; probability weighting function There are two regularities that we have learned from experimental studies of choice under risk. The first is that the majority of people weigh objective probabilities non-linearly, challenging the view from traditional economics that expected utility is linear in probability. In particular, several studies suggest that people overweigh small probabilities of a gain or loss and underweigh medium and large probabilities, and the “typical” probability weighting function has an inverse S-shape as depicted below (see Latimore, Baker & Witte 1992; Tversky & Kahneman, 1992; Camerer & Ho, 1994; Abdellaoui, 2000; Starmer, 2000). The Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed to C. Monica Capra, Department of Economics and Center for Neuropolicy, Emory University, 1602 Fishburne Dr., Atlanta, GA 30322. mcapra@emory.edu. Publisher's Disclaimer: The following manuscript is the final accepted manuscript. It has not been subjected to the final copyediting, fact-checking, and proofreading required for formal publication. It is not the definitive, publisher-authenticated version. The American Psychological Association and its Council of Editors disclaim any responsibility or liabilities for errors or omissions of this manuscript version, any version derived from this manuscript by NIH, or other third parties. The published version is available at www.apa.org/ pubs/journals/npe Capra et al. Page 2 NIH-PA Author Manuscript second regularity, although less commonly acknowledged, is that there is a large amount of heterogeneity in how people distort probabilities (Berns et al., 2007; Bleichrodt & Pinto, 2000; Bruhin, Fehr-Duda & Epper, 2010; Fehr-Duda & Epper, 2012; Gonzalez & Wu, 1999; Wu & Gonzalez, 1999; Wu & Gonzalez, 1996). Indeed, although in most of the abovementioned studies the authors report close median estimates of the probability weights (as shown in Figure 1), heterogeneity in the subject-specific estimates is seldom explained. NIH-PA Author Manuscript Interestingly, these regularities (i.e., inverse-shaped median probability weighting functions and large heterogeneity) seem to hold when choices are defined over gains or losses, and when outcomes are monetary or nonmonetary. For example, allowing for heterogeneity in preferences, Bleichrodt and Pinto (2000) proposed non-parametric elicitation of individuals’ utility and probability weighting functions for hypothetical gains and losses. They found significant evidence of inverse S-shaped probability weighting both at the aggregate and the individual level. In Berns et al. (2007), we used electric shocks to induce real and negative outcomes in choice under risk. We found median estimated probability distortion parameters similar to the above-mentioned. In addition, we found that, 46% of the subjects distorted probabilities in an inverse S-shape manner, as predicted by Prospect Theory or Rankdependent Utility Theory; 14% did not distort probabilities and could be classified as Expected Utility Theory (EUT) subjects, whereas 16% could not be classified at all with existing theories of choice under risk. Finally, using parametric and non-parametric estimation of the probability weighting function, Gonzalez and Wu (1999) – henceforth G&W – found that sub-certainty (the tendency of subjective probabilities to add to a number less than 1) failed to hold in 40% of the subjects. The implication of G&W’s result is that some people may overestimate a larger set of probabilities than it is customarily believed. Although little effort has been made to identify the determinants of such heterogeneity, existing research suggests there are two possible explanations. First, differences in estimated values of probability weighting may be due to differences in participants’ ability and experience in processing probability. For example, Piaget and Inhelder (1975) showed that 4-year old children had a step-like function. Young children seemed to understand when a sure thing would happen and when something would not happen, but they treated all other probabilities equally. This suggests that very young children have flat probability weighting functions. More recently, in a large-scale experiment, Dohmen et al. (2011) found that lower cognitive ability was associated with greater risk aversion. NIH-PA Author Manuscript A second possible explanation comes from the emotional response to the task. Rottenstreigh and Hsee’s (2001) experiments, for example, showed that the weighting function depended on affective reactions, which were influenced by the description of the outcome. They found that affect-rich prizes, such as a trip to the Caribbean, revealed weighting functions with jumps at the ends of the probability scale and low marginal sensitivity over a wide range of probabilities in the middle (i.e., child-like weighting functions). However, even in affectpoor environments, people distort probability in surprisingly different ways, as mentioned above. Given the important modulatory role of personality on behavior, motivation, emotion and cognition, we investigate the impact of personality on risky choices. Specifically, we explore the possibility that the personality “type” of the decision maker is linked to probability distortions. We choose to study personality type rather than personality traits, because an individual’s personality consists of many dimensions. An individual may possess a set of contradictory traits (i.e., score high in extraversion, inhibition, and neuroticism), but is best described by a dominant personality trait or type that he or she shares with other people. Thus, here, we identify how groups of subjects, who differ in their personality types, differ with respect to their probability and utility weights. J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 3 NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript There are several reasons for why we believe that personality influences probability weights. First, personality mediates emotion. Individuals who rank high in neuroticism, for example, tend to experience feelings such as anxiety, anger, and depressed mood. Previous studies on the effect of affect on choice under risk suggest that induced positive affect decreased the perceived frequency of negative outcomes (see Johnson & Tversky, 1983). Secondly, personality reflects generally stable patterns in behavior, motivation, and cognition (Borghans et al., 2009; Zillig, Hemenover & Dienstbier, 2002). Borghans, Golsteyn, Heckman and Meijers (2009) conducted an experiment on a sample of 347 Dutch high school students; they showed that the differences in cognitive and non-cognitive personality traits, such as IQ, the Big Five (openness, conscientiousness, extraversion, agreeableness, neuroticism), and self-control accounted for the differences in preference parameters. Zuckerman (2007) also found that differences in sensation-seeking personality traits (i.e. impulsivity, motivation, and extraversion) were strongly related to a broad range of risky behaviors, such as extreme sports, substance use and abuse (i.e. smoking, drinking, drugs), unprotected sex, violence, and criminal behavior. Finally, voxel-based morphometry (e.g., Blankstein, et al., 2009; DeYoung et al., 2010; Omura et al., 2005) and diffusion tensor imaging (Cohen et al., 2008) studies have identified neuroanatomical correlates of individual differences in personality traits. Furthermore, functional imaging studies have demonstrated significant modulation of neural correlates of emotional reactivity (e.g., Mobbs et al., 2005; Canli et al., 2002) and functional connectivity (Adelstein et al., 2011) by personality trait. Together, results from Personality Neuroscience underline the modulatory role of personality traits in brain-behavior relationships. In order to explore the link between personality and probability distortions, we designed an experiment that consisted of two parts. In the first, participants responded to several psychological questionnaires1 that included the Eysenck Personality Questionnaire Revised Version (EPQ-R; Eysenck et al., 1985), the Behavioral inhibition and behavioral activation systems scale BIS/BAS Scales (Carver & White,1994), the Barratt Impulsiveness Scale, Version 11 (BIS-11; Patton et al., 1995), and the Regulatory Focus Questionnaire (RFQ; Higgins et al., 2001). Unlike the Big Five questionnaire, which is more widely recognized, our chosen psychological questionnaires provide validated measures of sensation-seeking personality traits that are shown to strongly correlate with risk preference (Zuckerman, 2007; Harlow & Brown, 1990). We used the personality scores obtained from these four questionnaires to cluster people into heterogeneous personality types. We did this to identify how groups of individuals that exhibited differing categorizations of dominant traits distorted probabilities and outcomes. NIH-PA Author Manuscript In the second part, participants made a series of binary choices between a fixed amount of sure bet and a chance of winning a larger amount. To estimate probability weighting and the curvature of the utility function for each participant, we assumed a power utility function, and a two-parameter probability weighting function as in Lattimore, Baker and Witte (1992), Tversky and Wakker (1995), and Gonzalez and Wu (1999). Unlike one-parameter probability functions, the two-parameter weighting function allowed us to identify heterogeneity in distortions that were due to discriminability (i.e., a measure of curvature that captures the idea that people are more sensitive to changes in probabilities as they move away from certainty), or due to attractiveness (i.e., a measure of elevation that captures how appealing gambling is to the decision maker). To approximate an individual’s value of a lottery or certainty equivalent (CE), we used a modified version of the parameter estimation by sequential testing (PEST) procedure (Luce, 2000; Cho, Luce & von Winterfeld, 1994). 1In personality studies, it is customary to include a large set of questions to better capture the complete personality profile of the participants; not all questions capture the same attribute (see Cicchetti, 1994 for a discussion of guidelines and criteria for assessment instruments in Psychology). J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 4 NIH-PA Author Manuscript We found that heterogeneous types of personality traits are associated with different risk characteristics. In particular, the motivated viewed gambling more attractive, while the impulsive were most capable of discriminating non-extreme probabilities. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. We begin by describing the experiment. Then we analyze the experimental data, and finally, we discuss the implications of our experiment. Experimental Design and Procedures We recruited a total of 48 healthy participants (32 females) for this study. All participants were students or staff members at Emory University. The average age was 23.40 with a standard deviation of 5.36 years. All participants gave written informed consent to participate. The experiment took about 2 hours to complete, and included a one-hour brain scan, parts of which are reported elsewhere (Engelmann et al., 2009, 2012). Earnings ranged between $44.50 and $76 with an average of $60.51. NIH-PA Author Manuscript The sequence of experimental procedures was as follows. First, subjects were asked to respond to a pre-survey consisting of a set of psychological questionnaires including the EPQ-R and BIS/BAS2. After completing all psychological surveys, participants were asked to make a series of choices between a sure win and lotteries providing ex-ante probabilities of winning a comparatively higher payoff denominated in experimental currency (Yen), or not winning anything. For every decision, the higher payoff was always 1,000 Yen and the probability of winning the 1,000 Yen prize varied across conditions (0.01, 0.1, 0.2, 0.37, 0.8, 0.9, and 0.99). The sure win amount was adjusted according to participant’s choices on previous trials using an iterative staircase algorithm (PEST) that is outlined in detail inthe next section. Figure 2 depicts an example of the lottery choices in two different trials. A typical trial consisted of a decision-making period, followed by a feedback period that provided confirmatory information about which option was selected by the participant, but not about how much the subject made in that trial. In order to control for wealth effects, one of the trials was selected randomly to count towards payment at the end of the session. The decision made on the selected trial determined payment as follows: if the sure win was chosen on the selected trial, the respective amount was paid to the subject; if the lottery was chosen, a “computerized coin” was tossed, giving subjects a chance to win 1,000 laboratory Yen at the probability indicated in the lottery. Finally, an exchange rate of 1,000 laboratory Yen = 16 USD was established at the beginning of the experiment. At the beginning of the experiment subjects were fully informed of the payment plan and the exchange rate. Certainty Equivalents and Structural Estimation NIH-PA Author Manuscript We were interested in identifying each individual’s certainty equivalents (CE) for the lotteries. To do this, we used a modified version of the Parameter Estimation by Sequential Testing (PEST) introduced by Cho, Luce and von Winterfeld (1994), which is a procedure that relies on a staircase algorithm to identify the CE of a lottery. With PEST, the CE of a lottery is found by sequentially adjusting the value of the sure win according to decisions made by the subject. In our version of PEST, the algorithm started with a random offer that depended on the probability condition. When the probability of winning the prize was between 0.1 and 0.37 (i.e. low probability conditions), the sure win was between 0 and 500 Yen. In contrast, offers started between 500 and 1,000 Yen in the high probability conditions (i.e., 0.8–0.99). In order to create choice switches between sure wins and lotteries, amounts for sure wins were adjusted as follows: whenever the subject chose the sure win, the amount offered on the next trial was decreased by step-size, ε. Whenever the subject chose the 2We provide a more detailed explanation of the personality surveys in the “Psychological Questionnaires” section. J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 5 NIH-PA Author Manuscript lottery, the amount of the sure win offered on the next trial was increased by ε. The magnitude of ε was determined by the following 4 rules adapted from Luce (2000) and Cho, Luce and von Winterfeld (1994): (1) the initial step-size was set to 1/5 of the difference between the maximum and minimum possible payoffs (ε = 200 Yen); (2) at each choice switch ε was halved; (3) ε was doubled after three successive choices of the same item; (4) values were bounded at the maximum (1,000 Yen) and the minimum payoffs (0 Yen). This was done within each probability condition, which we presented in random order. The staircase algorithm terminated when the threshold step-size for a given probability condition was reached. This threshold was set to 25 Yen for all conditions, except for 0.01, 0.37 and 0.99, for which the threshold was set to 12.5 Yen. The PEST procedure allowed us to generate CEs relatively fast for many pairs of different lotteries3. This is important because we are interested in estimating individual-level probability weighting and utility function parameters. For this, many observations of decisions for each subject were needed. In addition, the PEST procedure is a choice task, not a valuation task, and previous literature has suggested that choice mode may be less “biased” than valuation mode (see Cox & Grether, 1996). Thus, for our purposes, the PEST procedure is preferred over alternative value elicitation mechanisms, such as auction mechanisms and the Becker-deGroot-Marschak (BDM) procedure. NIH-PA Author Manuscript After collecting all the data from subjects’ binary decisions (lottery or sure win), we estimated each participant’s probability weighting and utility functions using Gonzalez and Wu (1999)’s probability weighting form and power utility function. In each trial, the subject had a choice between a sure win (sw) and a lottery that paid a fixed amount π with probability p. The probability of choosing the lottery (Pl) was estimated using a logistic regression specification: where Φ represented the difference in utility between the lottery and the sure win in each trial; that is, The parameter σ captures the curvature of the utility function, and the subjective probability of winning the lottery was given by: NIH-PA Author Manuscript where parameters γ and δ control the curvature (discriminability) and the elevation (attractiveness) of the probability weighting function, respectively. Figure 3 shows shapes of the probability weighting for a few of our subjects. On the top panel, subject S8 and subject S13 share very similar estimated δ (elevation), but different estimated γ (discriminability). Subject S13 discriminates intermediate probabilities more 3The staircase algorithm terminated as soon as a threshold was reached - so there was no set number of trials; the longer the algorithm would take, the more trials there were. Most subjects participated in more than 50 trials. J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 6 NIH-PA Author Manuscript than S8, whose w(p) at the extremes is very steep. On the bottom panel, subjects S35 and S37 share similar γ parameters, but differ in their estimated δ, resulting in S35’s w(p) that lies above the 45° line and S37’s w(p) that lies below the 45° line. In our study, we estimated the three risk parameters jointly for each individual using Matlab. Psychological Questionnaires NIH-PA Author Manuscript According to psychologists, personality reflects the characteristic patterns of thoughts, feelings, and behaviors that make a person unique. It originates within the individual and remains fairly consistent throughout life (Borghans et al., 2009). To psychologists, personality is an area of study that deals with complex human behavior, including emotions, actions, and cognitive (thought) processes. As early as in the 90s, researchers like Harlow and Brown (1990) studied the role of certain biological and personality traits in the formation of economic preferences. To test the statistical relations between various measures, they separated male and female subjects into subgroups within each gender group, based on measures of subjects’ neurochemical activities, and their scores on sensationseeking scale and introversion scale. They found that individuals with a high level of “sensation-seeking” personality traits (i.e. extraversion and impulsivity) exhibited a willingness to accept economic risk. Recent studies have shown that sensation-seeking personality traits are linked to risk taking behaviors, such as extreme sports, substance use and abuse (i.e. smoking, drinking, drugs), unprotected sex, violence, and criminal behavior (see Zuckerman, 2007 for a review). NIH-PA Author Manuscript To measure sensation-seeking personality traits, we used well-established psychological questionnaires/scales including the EPQ-R, the BAS/BIS, the BIS-11, and the RFQ. The EPQ-R contains 100 Yes/No questions assessing biologically-based categories of temperament including Extraversion/Introversion, Neuroticism/Stability, Psychoticism/ Socialisation, and Lie. Extraversion is characterized by being outgoing, talkative, high on positive affect (feeling good), and in need of external stimulation. Neuroticism is characterized by having high levels of negative affect such as anger, depression, and anxiety. Psychoticism is associated not only with the liability to have a psychotic episode (or break with reality), but also with aggression. Last but not the least, Lie scale measures the tendency of lying when lying makes one socially better off. The second questionnaire (BAS/ BIS) contains behavioral questions. According to Gray (1981, 1982) two general motivational systems underlie behavior and affect: a behavioral inhibition system (BIS) and a behavioral activation system (BAS). A behavioral activation system (BAS) is believed to regulate appetitive motives, in which the goal is to move toward something desired. A behavioral inhibition system (BIS) is said to regulate aversive motives, in which the goal is to move away from something unpleasant. The BIS/BAS scales assess individual differences in the sensitivity of these systems. The Barratt Impulsiveness Scale, Version 11 (BIS-11; Patton et al., 1995) is a 30 item self-report questionnaire designed to assess general impulsiveness, which includes attentional impulsiveness, motor impulsiveness, self-control, and planning impulsiveness. Finally, the RFQ is an 11 item self-report questionnaire designed to assess individuals' subjective histories of success or failure in promoting and preventing self-regulation. According to focus theory (Higgins, 1998), all goal-directed behavior is regulated by two distinct motivational systems. These two systems, termed promotion and prevention, each serve as a distinct survival function. The promotion system is concerned with obtaining nurturance (e.g. nourishing food) and underlies higher-level concerns with accomplishment and advancement. The promotion system's hedonic concerns relate to the pleasurable presence of positive outcomes and the painful absence of positive outcomes. In contrast, the prevention system is concerned with obtaining security and underlies higher-level concerns with safety and fulfillment of responsibilities. The J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 7 prevention system's hedonic concerns relate to the pleasurable absence of negative outcomes and the painful presence of negative outcomes. NIH-PA Author Manuscript Results Table 1 displays a summary statistics of parameter estimates among the 48 subjects. The median estimates suggest an inverse-S probability weighting function similar to those reported in previous literature. At the individual level, we observed a large variability in individual’s estimated probability weighting parameters (see Chart A in the Appendix). To determine how personality profiles differed with respect to their probability and outcome distortions, we used clustering analysis4 to identify participants based on their responses to the four psychological questionnaires5. We used hierarchical clustering analysis (Complete Linkage method6) to classify 47 subjects7 into different clusters; we identified four distinct personality types. Personality Type 1 (henceforth PersType1) had a total of 9 subjects who, on average, were older and mostly women. PersType2 was comprised of 21 subjects, and had a higher proportion of males than the other groups. PersType3 had 16 subjects and the female/male ratio mirrored our participant population. Finally, PersType4 had 1 subject only. We excluded PersType4 from the rest of the analysis. NIH-PA Author Manuscript What kind of personality profiles do these clustered types have? To answer this question and label the types, we performed factor analysis (i.e. varimax rotation) and identified four factors with eigenvalues greater than one, which accounted for 68.3% of the variance. Table 2 shows the loadings and the uniqueness scores for each personality attribute. As the table suggests, Factor 1 is mainly defined by impulsivity traits (NP-BIS11; Mot-BIS-11; CogBIS-11; Psychoticism; BAS-funskg). Factor 2 is mainly defined by affective traits (Extraversion; Neuroticism; BIS). In contrast, Factor 3 is influenced by motivational traits (Reg-promote; BAS-drive; BAS-rewards). Finally, Factor 4 is defined by loss avoidance/ prevention traits (Lie-all; Reg-prevent). For each clustered type, we identified which factors had positive average scores. For PersType1, the average score of Factor 3 (motivation) was positive, the rest were negative. For PersType2, the average score for Factor 1 (impulsiveness) was positive, the rest were negative. For PerstType3, only Factor 1’s average score was negative, the rest positive. NIH-PA Author Manuscript We tested whether the factor scores among these three personality types were statistically different. PersType2 differed from the other two personality-types (PersTypes1 and 3) with respect to the Factor 1 (Median test p=0.012 and p<0.001, respectively), with PersType2 being relatively more impulsive. With respect to Factor 2, PersType3 was different from the two other personality types (Median test p=0.001 and p<0.001) with PersType3 being relatively more emotionally reactive, or more affective. In addition to these personality differences, we noticed that PersType1 were older and had relatively more females (see 4The criterion for classifying subjects into clustered personality types is the measure of traits similarity or distances (dissimilarity measures) between individual subjects. At each stage, it computes the distances between all the existing clusters to determine which clusters are the closest to each other. The closest clusters are combined to form a new, large cluster and the algorithm stops clustering whenever membership in clusters stabilizes. As a result, items within a cluster are similar, and/or the distance between them is small; and items in different clusters are dissimilar, and/or the distance between them is large. 5Although correlating personality to risk parameters without clustering the data may seem reasonable, this method hides the fact that the effect of a specific trait (e.g. extraversion) on preferences is conditional on the general personality profile of the individual. For example, more extraversion in an inhibited person has a contradictory effect compared to more extraversion in an impulsive one. 6We also tried out other clustering algorithms that apply different criteria to measure distances such as Single, Median, Centroid Linkage, and obtained the same results. 7One female subject didn’t complete all the personality questionnaires, so this observation was excluded. J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 8 NIH-PA Author Manuscript Table C in the Appendix for a summary of demographic variables by clustered type). The above results suggest that we could label three types in the following manner: PersType1 (9 subjects) were relatively more “Motivated”. PersType2 (21 subjects) were more “Impulsive”. Finally PersType3, which had 16 subjects, were more “Affective” (see Table B and C for further details). Behavioral differences among Types NIH-PA Author Manuscript Table 3 presents summary statistics of the estimated risk parameters gamma, delta, and sigma by personality type (additional data are found in the appendix). We compared and contrasted the three different personality types with respect to the estimated probability weighting and utility functions parameters. Acknowledging the fact that we had three groups of multivariate data, we performed group comparison tests using non-parametric MANOVA8. We found noticeable overall differences among the three characteristic types (test statistics based on distances to centroids, F=3.092, p=0.056). In particular, PersType1 (Motivated) differed significantly from PersType3 (Affective) with regard to the three estimated risk parameters (test statistics based on distances to centroids, t=2.521, permutation p-value=0.054). With respect to comparisons between types, we found differences in attractiveness (i.e., a measure of elevation that captures how appealing gambling is to the decision maker) and discriminability (i.e., a measure of curvature of the probability weighting function that captures the idea that people are more sensitive to changes in probabilities as they move away from certainty). PersType1 (Motivated) subjects had different estimated delta values, as compared to PersType2 (Impulsive) and PersType3 (Affective) (MWT, Z= 1.924, p=0.054; and Z=1.981, p=0.048, respectively). This suggests that the motivated viewed gambling significantly more attractive, PersType2 and PersType3 or the Impulsive vs. the Affective (but not impulsive) differed with respect to their estimated gamma values (MWT, Z=2.115, p=0.034) suggesting that the impulsive were the most capable of discriminating non-extreme probabilities. Finally with respect to sigma, PerstType1 (Motivated) and PersType2 (Impulsive) differed significantly (MWT, Z=−1.969, p=0.049). It’s also interesting to study the gender effect on individual’s risk preferences. Aggregating across all types (47 subjects), only with respect to the curvature of the utility function (sigma) did we observe significant differences between men and women (MWT, Z= 2.613, p= 0.009). This result is consistent with other works that have identified gender differences in risk attitudes (see Borghans et al., 2009). However, we did not observe statistically significant differences between men and women with respect to discriminability and elevation. NIH-PA Author Manuscript Discussion Several studies of choice under risk that report individual parameter estimates show that there is a high level of heterogeneity in how people distort probabilities. Despite of this, little effort has been made to identify the source of this heterogeneity. In this paper, we put forward the idea that personality type is a determinant of choice under risk, and that different personality types exhibit different risk preferences. Using four widely utilized psychological tests, we were able to classify participants into three distinct personality types. We then compared these types with respect to their estimated risk parameters. PersType 1, or “motivated” individuals, who were controlled and emotionally stable, tended to be more 8Non-parametric MANOVA (Multivariate Analysis of Variance) is to test significant difference between two or more groups of multivariate data, based on any distance measure of choice (Anderson, 2001). In our analysis, we used Euclidean distances and performed 9999 permutations. Manly (1997) pointed out that for tests at an α-level of 0.05, at least 999 permutations should be used; for tests at an α-level of 0.01, at least 4999 permutations should be used. J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 9 NIH-PA Author Manuscript risk averse as measured by the curvature of the utility function, but they were also more optimistic, as measured by the elevation of the probability weighting function. These results fit well with predictions from regulatory focus theory (RFT, Higgins, 1998) that people with a promotion focus have a heightened sensitivity for positive outcomes. It could be argued that motivated individuals by focusing on rewarding outcomes, they place a greater weight on payoff magnitude relative to payoff probability leading to more optimistic risk attitudes. PersType 2 or “impulsive” individuals were reward and fun seeking, and they tended to be less risk averse. Finally, PersType 3 or “affective” individuals were inhibited and neurotic, and they were shown to discriminate probabilities less around the middle and have curvier probability weighting functions around the reference points. Our results, thus, suggest that heterogeneity in probability weighting and more generally, in choice under risk may be explained by personality profiles, which can be elicited though standard psychological questionnaires. We also found that females were more risk averse than males, confirming previous findings. NIH-PA Author Manuscript Recent literature has shown that personality affects risk preferences (see Borghans et al., 2009). In addition, psychologists believe personality is a stable trait, but that personality also often interacts with the environment to produce a certain outcome (Weber et al., 2002). This can explain why risk preferences are stable when elicited through a single choice mode (Harrison & Rutström, 2000; Andersen, Harrison, Lau & Rutström, 2008), yet, may differ when elicited through valuation mechanisms (e.g., auction vs. lottery choice – see Eckel & Grossman, 2002; Berg, Dickhaut, & McCabe, 2005; Issac & James, 2000). Issac and James (2000), for example, showed that the estimated numerical values of individuals’ implied risk parameters were not stable within individuals across the BDM and first-price auction institutions. Furthermore, the rankings across subjects of the numerical values of risk were not preserved. In a more recent paper, Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe (2005) replicated these findings with an improved paradigm. They concluded by saying that “…there simply might not be such things as preferences (“they” ain’t nothing til we call em”). However, our study highlights the important role of personality type in explaining choices under risk, and it is the first step towards formulating the hypothesis that the observed instability of preferences may be due to an interaction between personality and the choice environment. Indeed, this could be an interesting path for future research. Acknowledgments We would like to thank participants at workshops and conferences where this work was presented. We acknowledge support from NIDA (R01 DA016434 and R01 DA025045 to Gregory S. Berns and T32 DA15040 to Jan B. Engelmann). Jan B. Engelmann is grateful for support from the NCCR Affective Sciences and the Mercator Foundation Switzerland. All errors are ours. NIH-PA Author Manuscript References Abdellaoui M. Parameter-free elicitation of the probability weighting function. Management Science. 2000; 46:1497–1512. Adelstein JS, Shehzad Z, Mennes M, Deyoung CG, Zuo X-N, Kelly C, Margulies DS, et al. Personality is reflected in the brain's intrinsic functional architecture. Public Library of Sciences – One. 2011; 6(11):e27633. Andersen S, Glenn WH, Morten IL, Rutström EE. Lost in state space: are preferences stable? International Economic Review. 2008; 49(3):1091–1112. Anderson MJ. Permutation tests for univariate or multivariate analysis of variance and regression. Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences. 2001; 58:629–636. Berg J, Dickhaut J, McCabe K. Risk preference instability across institutions: a dilemma. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 2005; 102(11):4209–4214. J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 10 NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript Berns GS, Capra CM, Moore S, Noussair C. A shocking experiment: New evidence on probability weighting and common ratio violations. Judgment and Decision Making. 2007; 2(4):234–242. Blankstein U, Chen JY, Mincic AM, McGrath PA, Davis KD. The complex minds of teenagers: neuroanatomy of personality differs between sexes. Neuropsychologia. 2009; 47(2):599–603. [PubMed: 19010338] Bleichrodt H, Pinto JL. A Parameter-free elicitation of the probability weighting function in medical decision analysis. Management Science. 2000; 46:1485–1496. Borghans L, Golsteyn BHH, Heckman JJ, Meijers H. Gender differences in risk aversion and ambiguity aversion. Journal of European Economic Association. 2009; 7(2–3):649–658. Bruhin A, Fehr-Duda H, Epper T. Risk and rationality: uncovering heterogeneity in probability distortion. Econometrica. 2010; 78:1375–1412. Canli T, Sivers H, Whitfield SL, Gotlib IH, Gabrieli JDE. Amygdala response to happy faces as a function of extraversion. Science (New York, N.Y.). 2002; 296(5576):2191. Camerer CF, Ho TH. Violations of the betweenness axiom and nonlinearity in probability. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 1994; 8:167–196. Carver CS, White TL. Behavioral inhibition, behavioral activation, and affective responses to impending reward and punishment: the BIS/BAS scales. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 1994; 67:319–333. Cho Y, Luce RD, von Winterfeld D. Tests of assumptions about the joint receipt of gambles in rankand sign-dependent utility theory. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance. 1994; 20:931–943. Cicchetti DV. Guidelines, criteria, and rules of thumb for evaluating normed and standardized assessment instruments in psychology. Psychological Assessment. 1994; 6(4):284–290. Cohen MX, Schoene-Bake J-C, Elger CE, Weber B. Connectivity-based segregation of the human striatum predicts personality characteristics. Nature neuroscience. 2008; 12(1):32–34. Cox J, Grether D. The preference reversal phenomenon: response mode, markets, and incentives. Economic Theory. 1996; 7:381–405. DeYoung CG, Hirsh JB, Shane MS, Papademetris X, Rajeevan N, Gray JR. Testing predictions from personality neuroscience: brain structure and the big five. Psychological Science. 2010; 21(6): 820–828. [PubMed: 20435951] Dohmen T, Falk A, Huffman D, Sunde U, Schupp J, Wagner GG. Individual risk attitudes: measurement, determinants and behavioral consequences. Journal of European Economic Association. 2011; 9(3):522–550. Eckel C, Grossman P. Sex differences and statistical stereotyping in attitudes toward financial risk. Evolution and Human Behavior. 2002; 23(4):281–295. Engelmann JB, Capra CM, Noussair C, Berns GS. Expert financial advice neurobiologically offloads financial decision-making under risk. Public Library of Sciences – One. 2009; 4(3):1–14. Engelmann JB, Moore S, Capra CM, Berns GS. Differential neurobiological effects of expert advice on risky choice in adolescents and adults. Social Cognitive and Affective Neuroscience. 2012; 7(5):557–567. [PubMed: 22563008] Eysenck SBG, Eysenck HJ, Barrett PB. A revised version of the psychoticism scale. Personality and Individual Difference. 1985; 6(1):21–29. Fehr-Duda H, Epper T. Probability and risk: foundations and economic implications of probabilitydependent risk preferences. Annual Review of Economics. 2012; 16(17):1905–1908. Gonzalez R, Wu G. On the shape of the probability weighting function. Cognitive Psychology. 1999; 38:129–166. [PubMed: 10090801] Gray, JA. A critique of Eysenck's theory of personality. In: Eysenck, HJ., editor. A model for Personality. Berlin: Springer-Verlag; 1981. p. 246-276. Gray, JA. The Neuropsychology of Anxiety: An Enquiry into the Functions of the Septo-hippocampal System. New York: Oxford University Press; 1982. Harlow WV, Brown KC. Understanding and Assessing Financial Risk Tolerance: A Biological Perspective. Financial Analysts Journal. 1990; 46(6):50–64. J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 11 NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript Harrison, GW.; Rutström, EE. Experimental evidence of hypothetical bias in value elicitation methods. In: Plott, CR.; Smith, VL., editors. Handbook of Experimental Economics Results. Amsterdam: North Holland; 2000. Higgins, ET. Promotion and prevention: regulatory focus as a motivational principle. In: Zanna, ME., editor. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology. Vol. Vol30. New York: Academic Press; 1998. Higgins ET, Friedman RS, Harlow RE, Idson LC, Ayduk O, Taylor A. Achievement orientations from subjective histories of success: promotion pride versus prevention pride. European Journal of Social Psychology. 2001; 31:3–23. Isaac RM, James D. Just who are you calling risk averse. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 2000; 20(2): 177–187. Johnson E, Tversky A. Affect, generalization and the perception of risk. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 1983; 45(1):20–31. Lattimore PM, Baker JR, Witte AD. The influence of probability on risky choice. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 1992; 17:377–400. Luce, RD. Utility of Gains and Losses: Measurement-theoretical and Experimental Approaches. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Association; 2000. Manly, BFJ. Randomization, bootstrap and Monte Carlo methods in biology. 2nd edition. London: Chapman and Hall; 1997. Mobbs D, Hagan CC, Azim E, Menon V, Reiss AL. Personality predicts activity in reward and emotional regions associated with humor. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America. 2005; 102(45):16502. [PubMed: 16275930] Omura K, Todd Constable R, Canli T. Amygdala gray matter concentration is associated with extraversion and neuroticism. NeuroReport. 2005; 16(17):1905–1908. [PubMed: 16272876] Patton JH, Stanford MS, Barratt ES. Factor structure of the Barratt impulsiveness scale. Journal of Clinical Psychology. 1995; 51:768–774. [PubMed: 8778124] Piaget, J.; Inhelder, B. The Origin of the Idea of Chance in Children. New York: Routledge and Kegan Paul; 1975. Rottenstreich Y, Hsee CK. Money, kisses, and electric shocks: an affective psychology of risk. Psychological Science. 2001; 12:185–190. [PubMed: 11437299] Starmer C. Developments in non-expected utility theory: the hunt for a descriptive theory of choice under risk. Journal of Economic Literature. 2000; 38(2):332–382. Tversky A, Kahneman D. Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 1992; 5:297–323. Tversky A, Wakker PP. Risk attitudes and decision weights. Econometrica. 1995; 63(6):1255–1280. Weber EU, Blais A, Betz NE. A domain-specific risk-attitude scale: measuring risk perceptions and risk behaviors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making. 2002; 15:263–290. Wu G, Gonzalez R. Nonlinear decision weights in choice under uncertainty. Management Science. 1999; 45:74–85. Wu G, Gonzalez R. Curvature of the probability weighting function. Management Science. 1996; 42:1676–1690. Zillig PLM, Hemenover SH, Dienstbier RA. What do we assess when we assess a Big 5 trait? A content analysis of the affective, behavioral and cognitive processes represented in the Big 5 personality inventories. Personality & Social Psychology Bulletin. 2002; 28:847–858. Zuckerman, M. Sensation Seeking and Risky Behavior. Washington. DC: American Psychological Association; 2007. J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 12 Appendix Chart A NIH-PA Author Manuscript Estimates of individual risk parameters and demographics Subject Probability weighting Utility Gender Age Payment (USD) γ δ σ 1 0.0853 1.2584 0.5319 F 25 63 2 0.3957 0.683 0.4908 F 25 65 3 0.4799 0.8599 0.4711 M 24 60 4 2.486 1 0.2042 F 22 63 5 0.5213 0.8688 0.5087 M 22 53.5 6 0.6797 0.549 0.4384 F 19 45 7 0.4468 0.7275 0.4583 F 22 54 8 0.3837 1.0797 1.1982 M 23 72.5 9 0.7624 0.5704 0.4435 M 20 60 10 0.8733 0.4662 0.5514 F 25 75 NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript 11 0.5 0.423 0.3203 M 20 70 12 0.9256 2.1918 2.1249 F 20 76 13 0.6497 1.0735 0.6437 M 22 72 14 2.5545 2.3059 0.5174 F 21 50 15 0.3752 0.8255 0.3904 F 21 45 16 0.4731 0.8646 0.3818 F 28 60.5 17 1.4804 1.7078 0.5141 F 21 63 18 1.5707 0.25 0.7073 F 22 65 19 2.0405 1 0.195 F 45 60.5 20 0.8703 1.8744 1.4863 M 18 44.5 21 3.9056 1 0.1971 F 21 62 22 0.7369 0.5405 0.4068 M 19 52 23 0.8854 1.5476 1.3497 M 20 49.5 24 0.2967 0.8436 0.4243 F 26 61 25 0.1007 1.4416 0.6182 F 19 60 26 0.322 0.4858 0.4132 F 28 69 27 0.5042 0.5529 0.4023 F 25 60 28 0.7625 0.5956 0.5099 F 20 47.4 29 0.3792 0.9213 0.4735 F 20 52.75 30 0.9842 1.5192 1.5306 M 28 60.48 31 1.9884 0.4115 1.3041 F 34 61 32 0.2693 0.7404 0.4328 F 21 76 33 0.9271 0.5443 0.5085 M 21 76 34 0.7157 0.5902 0.5337 F 21 60 35 0.9388 1.2865 1.2663 M 28 60 36 0.3772 0.5444 0.4234 F 25 51.84 37 1.0113 0.4968 0.4426 M 18 47 38 0.4277 1.0278 0.4483 F 21 60 J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 13 Subject Probability weighting Utility Gender Age Payment (USD) NIH-PA Author Manuscript γ δ σ 39 0.8149 0.4496 0.4087 F 18 60 40 0.9161 0.4595 0.5182 M 23 61 41 0.19 2.4983 0.2835 F 21 60 42 0.8443 0.7622 0.5592 M 20 62.25 43 1.0656 0.5107 0.5369 M 18 60 44 0.8914 1.0918 0.837 F 23 68 45 0.5135 0.6051 0.4884 M 28 76 46 0.4722 0.574 0.2462 F 36 59.93 47 1.63 2.8992 0.4218 F 36 66 48 1.1985 5 0.269 F 20 48 Table B Description of Variables (47 Subjects) NIH-PA Author Manuscript Category NIH-PA Author Manuscript Personality Traits Variable Name Description / Range of Values Mean (Std) Median Mode 95% C. I. NP-BIS-11 Non-planning impulsiveness (a lack of “futuring” or planning). Values range from 13 to 29 21.09 (3.79) 21.00 21.00 (19.97, 22.20) Cog-BIS-11 Cognitive impulsiveness (i.e. making quick cognitive decisions). Values range from 11 to 26 17.17 (3.46) 18.00 18.00 (16.15, 18.19) Mot-BIS-11 Motor impulsiveness (i.e. acting without thinking). Values range from 13 to 32 21.13 (3.78) 21.00 20.00 23.00 (20.02, 22.24) Reg-promote Promotion focused self-regulation to approach matches to desired endstates. Values range from 16 to 30 23.38 (3.22) 23.00 21.00 23.00 24.00 (22.44, 24.33) Reg-prevent Prevention focused self-regulation to approach matches to desired endstates. Values range from 6 to 25 18.09 (4.18) 17.00 17.00 (16.86, 19.31) Psychoticism Liability to have a psychotic episode (or break with reality), and aggression. Values range from 1 to 12 6.04 (2.65) 6.00 6.00 (5.27, 6.82) J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 14 Category NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript Four Factors Variable Name Description / Range of Values Mean (Std) Median Mode 95% C. I. Extraversion Being outgoing, talkative, high on positive affect (feeling good), and in need of external stimulation. Values range from 5 to 21 14.51 (4.88) 16.00 19.00 (13.08, 15.94) Neuroticism Emotionality, characterized by high levels of negative affect such as depression and anxiety. Values range from 0 to 23 9.89 (5.51) 10.00 4.00 5.00 (8.27, 11.51) Lie-all Tendency of lying when lying makes one socially better off. Values range from 2 to 14 8.15 (3.01) 8.00 7.00 (7.26, 9.03) BAS-drive Behavioral activation sensitivity to driving motives. Values range from 6 to 16 10.94 (2.50) 11.00 11.00 (10. 20, 11.67) BAS-funskg Behavioral activation sensitivity to funseeking motives. Values range from 5 to 16 11.30 (2.62) 11.00 14.00 (10. 53, 12. 07) BAS-reward Behavioral activation sensitivity towards rewards. Values range from 13 to 20 17.53 (1.85) 18.00 18.00 (16. 99, 18.08) BIS Behavioral inhibition sensitivity to unpleasantness. Values range from 13 to 28 19.96 (3.68) 20.00 20.00 (18. 88, 21.04) Factor1 Impulsivity traits, defined by Nonplanning Impulsiveness, Cognitive Impulsiveness, Motor Impulsiveness, Psychoticism and BAS Fun-seeking. Values range from −1.71 to 3.08. 3.80E-09 (1.00) −0.24 ___ (−0.29, 0.29) Factor2 Affective traits, defined by Extraversion, Neuroticism and BIS. Values range from −2.01 to 1.96. 4.29E-08 (1.00) 0.14 ___ (−0.29, 0.29) Factor3 Motivational traits, defined by Regulatory- −2.85E-08 (1.00) −0.11 ___ (−0.29, 0.29) J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 15 Category Description / Range of Values promotion, BASdrive and BASreward. Values range from −2.33 to 2.36. Mean (Std) Median Mode 95% C. I. Factor4 Loss avoidance/ prevention traits, defined by Regulatoryprevention and Lie-all. Values range from −2.37 to 1.83 1.80E-08 (1.00) −0.06 ___ (−0.29, 0.29) Male/Female Sex of the student subjects. Dummy: 0 Male, 1 Female 0.64 (0.49) 1.00 1.00 (0.50, 0.78) Age Age of the student subjects. Age ranges from 18 to 45. 23.47 (5.40) 22.00 21.00 (21.88, 25.05) Payment Subject’s earnings from the experiment. Maximum is 76, minimum is 44.5 60.18 (8.46) 60.00 60.00 (57.70, 62.67) Estimated Gamma-WG The curvature of the probability weighting function. It measures how one discriminates probabilities. Maximum is 3.91, minimum is 0.085 0.89 (0.82) 0.74 ___ (0.67, 1.10) Parameters Delta-WG The elevation of the probability weighting function. It measures how attractive one views gambling. Maximum is 5, minimum is 0.25 1.03 (0.33) 0.83 1.00 (0.79, 1.27) Sigma-CU The curvature of the CRRA utility function. Maximum is 1.53, minimum is 0.20 0.57 (0.33) 0.47 ___ (0.41, 0.74) NIH-PA Author Manuscript Variable Name Demographics NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript Table C (i) Summary Statistics by Personality Type (47 subjects) Factor1 Type Mean (Std) Median Maximum Minimum [95% Conf. Interval] 1 −0.93 (0.47) 2 0.56 (0.74) −1.00 −0.30 −1.59 (−1.29, −0.57) .59 1.60 −1.18 (0.22, 0.89) 3 4 −0.40 (0.68) −.49 0.79 −1.71 (−.76, −0.04) 3.08 (0.00) 3.08 ___ ___ ___ Total 3.80E-09 (1.00) −0. 24 3.08 −1.71 (−0.29, 0.29) J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 16 NIH-PA Author Manuscript Factor2 Factor3 Factor4 NIH-PA Author Manuscript Gamma_WG Delta_WG Type Mean (Std) Median Maximum Minimum [95% Conf. Interval] 1 −1.06 (0.69) 2 −0.30 (0.71) −1.35 0.21 −1.98 (−1.59, −0.53) −.31 0.81 −2.01 (−0.62, 0.03) 3 4 0.91 (0.58) .91 1.96 −0.03 (0.60, 1.21) 1.35 (0.00) 1.35 ___ ___ ___ Total 4.29E-08 (1.00) 0.14 1.96 −2.01 (−0.29, 0.29) 1 0.22 (0.83) .19 1.55 −1.13 (−0.42, 0.87) 2 −0.48 (0.79) −.45 0.55 −2.33 (−0.83, −0.12) 3 0.42 (1.11) .31 2.36 −1.50 (−0.17, 1.01) 4 1.27 (0.00) 1.27 ___ ___ ___ Total −2.85E-08 (1.00) −0.11 2.36 −2.33 (−0.29, 0.29) 1 −0.07 (0.45) −.15 0.60 −0.69 (−0.42, 0.28) 2 −0.14 (1.06) −.22 1.64 −2. 21 (−0.62, 0.34) 3 0.26 (1.16) .368 1.83 −2.37 (−0.36, 0.88) 4 −0.59 (0.00) −.59 ___ ___ ___ Total 1.80E-08 (1.00) −0.06 1.83 −2.37 (−0.29, 0.29) 1 0.91 (0.69) .48 2.04 0.09 (0.39, 1.44) 2 1.06 (0.87) .87 3.91 0.30 (0.67, 1.46) 3 0.67 (0.51) .50 1.99 0.10 (0.40, 0.94) 4 0.5 (0.00) .50 ___ ___ ___ Total 0.89 (0.82) 0.74 3.91 0.09 (0.67, 1.10) 1 1.67 (1.43) 1.03 5.00 0.57 (0.57, 2.77) 2 0.90 (0.50) .73 2.31 0.46 (0.67, 1.13) 3 0.87 (0.56) .78 2.50 0. 25 (0.57, 1.17) 4 0.42 (0.00) .42 ___ ___ ___ Total 1.03 (0.33) 0.83 5.00 0.25 (0.79, 1.27) Table C (ii) NIH-PA Author Manuscript Sigma_CU Gender Type Mean (Std) Median Maximum Minimum [95% Conf. Interval] 1 0.40 (0.13) .45 0.53 0. 20 (0.30, 0.50) 2 0.65 (0.39) .52 1.53 0. 20 (0.47, 0.82) 3 0.58 (0.31) .44 1.35 0. 28 (0.41, 0.74) 4 0.32 (0.00) .32 ___ ___ ___ Total 0.57 (0.33) 0.47 1.53 0. 20 (0.47, 0.67) 1 0.89 (0.33) 1.00 1.00 0.00 (0.63, 1.15) 2 0.52 (0.51) 1.00 1.00 0.00 (0.29, 0.76) 3 0.69 (0.48) 1.00 1.00 0.00 (0.43, 0.94) 4 0 (0.00) 0.00 0.00 ___ ___ Total 0.64 (0.49) 1.00 1.00 0.00 (0.50, 0.78) J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 17 Table C (ii) NIH-PA Author Manuscript Age Payment Type Mean (Std) Median Maximum Minimum [95% Conf. Interval] 1 28.11 (8.75) 25.00 45.00 20.00 (21.38, 34.84) 2 22.43 (3.19) 22.00 28.00 18.00 (20.98, 23.88) 3 22.44 (4.30) 21.00 34.00 18.00 (20.14, 24.73) 4 20 (0.00) 20.00 20.00 ___ ___ Total 23.47 (5. 40) 22.00 45.00 18.00 (21.88, 25.05) 1 60.60 (5.24) 60.50 66.00 48.00 (56.57, 64.63) 2 60.48 (9.48) 60.48 76.00 44.50 (56.17, 64.80) 3 58.94 (8.78) 60.00 76.00 45.00 (54.27, 63.62) 4 70 (0.00) 70.00 60.00 ___ ___ Total 60.18 (8.46) 60.00 76.00 44.50 (57.70, 62.67) NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 18 NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript Figure 1. Typical one-parameter probability weighting functions NIH-PA Author Manuscript Subjective probability weights [w(p)] representing how individuals perceive objective probabilities throughout the [0, 1] interval. Under the Expected Utility Theory (EUT), there is no probability distortion, as presented by the 45-degree straight line. However, several studies suggest that people overweigh small probabilities of a gain, and underweigh medium and large probabilities; the “typical” probability weighting function has an inverse S-shape (i.e. Latimore, Baker & Witte 1992; Tversky & Kahneman, 1992; Camerer & Ho, 1994; Abdellaoui, 2000; Starmer, 2000). In addition, many studies also report that there is a large amount of heterogeneity in how people distort probabilities (Berns et al., 2007; Bleichrodt & Pinto, 2000; Bruhin, Fehr-Duda & Epper, 2010; Fehr-Duda & Epper, 2012; Gonzalez & Wu, 1999; Wu & Gonzalez, 1996). J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 19 NIH-PA Author Manuscript Figure 2. Examples of Lottery Choices NIH-PA Author Manuscript In each trial, participants were asked to make a choice between a sure win and a lottery providing ex-ante probabilities of winning a comparatively higher payoff denominated in experimental currency (Yen), or not winning anything. For every decision, the higher payoff was always 1,000 Yen and the probability of winning the 1,000 Yen prize varied across conditions (0.01, 0.1, 0.2, 0.37, 0.8, 0.9, and 0.99). The sure win amount was adjusted according to participant’s choices on previous trials using an iterative staircase algorithm (PEST). The decision made on the selected trial determined payment as follows: if the sure win was chosen on the selected trial, the respective amount was paid to the subject; if the lottery was chosen, a “computerized coin” was tossed, giving subjects a chance to win 1,000 laboratory Yen at the probability indicated in the lottery. NIH-PA Author Manuscript J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 20 NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript Figure 3. Examples of subjects with different curvature (top) and elevation (bottom) Shapes of the probability weighting for a few of our subjects. On the top panel, subject S8 and subject S13 share very similar estimated δ (elevation=1.07~1.08), but different estimated γ (discriminability=0.38, and 0.65, respectively). On the bottom panel, subjects S35 and S37 share similar γ parameters (discriminability=0.93~1.02), but different estimated δ (elevation=1.29, and 0.50, respectively). J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Capra et al. Page 21 Table 1 Population Estimates NIH-PA Author Manuscript Statistics Probability weighting Utility Discriminability (γ) Attractiveness (δ) Curvature (σ) Mean 0.888 1.052 0.601 SE 0.104 0.120 0.057 Median 0.750 0.835 0.481 Note. Table 1 displays a summary statistics of parameter estimates among the 48 subjects. The median estimates suggest an inverse-S probability weighting function similar to those reported in previous literature. NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript Table 2 Variable J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01. Factor1 Impulsivity Factor2 Emotional Reactivity Factor3 Approach Motivation Factor4 Loss Avoidance /Prevention Uniqueness NP-BIS-11 0.7377 0.1058 −0.3183 −0.0734 0.3379 Cog-BIS-11 0.5483 0.4701 −0.0864 0.0798 0.4646 Mot-BIS-11 0.8017 −0.0941 0.0300 −0.1255 0.3317 Reg-promote −0.3350 −0.2232 0.6944 0.2662 0.2848 Reg-prevent −0.4416 0.0191 −0.1432 0.7109 0.2788 Psychoticism 0.6744 −0.1415 0.1212 −0.2413 0.4522 Extraversion 0.3885 −0.5098 0.4913 0.1610 0.3219 Neuroticism 0.0451 0.9149 0.0099 −0.0761 0.1550 Lie-all 0.0067 −0.1266 0.1321 0.8585 0.2294 BAS-drive 0.2735 −0.0178 0.6239 0.0186 0.5353 BAS-funskg 0.5972 −0.2760 0.4609 −0.1293 0.3380 BAS-rewards −0.0253 0.2050 0.8292 −0.0882 0.2619 BIS −0.0982 0.9248 0.0202 −0.0266 0.1340 Capra et al. Factor Loadings and Uniqueness Scores Note. NP-BIS-11, Cog-BIS-11 and Mot-BIS-11 are indicators of impulsiveness, obtained from the Barratt Impulsiveness Scale, Version 11. Reg-promote and Reg-prevent assess individuals’ levels of selfregulation, given by the RFQ questionnaire. Psychoticism, Extraversion, Neuroticism and Lie-all belong to categories of the EPQ-R questionnaire, measuring different aspects of temperament. BAS-drive, BAS-funskg, BAS-rewards and BIS are components of the BAS/BIS scales that assess two motivational systems underlie behavior and affect. For a more detailed description of trait variables, see Table B in the Appendix. Page 22 Capra et al. Page 23 Table 3 Summary Statistics of Estimated Mean and Median Risk Parameters by PersType NIH-PA Author Manuscript PersType Dominant Personality Traits Discriminability γ Mean (std) Median Attractiveness δ Mean (std) Median Curvature σ Mean (std) Median 1 Motivated .912 (.685) .480 1.668 (1.435) 1.028 .399 (.127) .448 2 Impulsive 1.062 (.867) .870 .900 (.495) .728 .646 (.387) .517 3 Affective .668 (.510) .497 .874 (.563) .783 .577 (.312) .443 All --- .896 (.732) .750 1.041 (.824) .835 .574 (.332) .481 Note. Table 3 presents summary statistics of the estimated risk parameters gamma, delta, and sigma by personality type (additional data are in the appendix). NIH-PA Author Manuscript NIH-PA Author Manuscript J Neurosci Psychol Econ. Author manuscript; available in PMC 2014 September 01.